-
PDF
- Split View
-
Views
-
Cite
Cite
Christian Bayer, Benjamin Born, Ralph Luetticke, Gernot J Müller, The Coronavirus Stimulus Package: How Large is the Transfer Multiplier, The Economic Journal, Volume 133, Issue 652, May 2023, Pages 1318–1347, https://doi.org/10.1093/ej/uead003
- Share Icon Share
Abstract
In response to the COVID-19 pandemic, large parts of the economy were locked down and, as a result, households’ income risk rose sharply. At the same time, policy makers put forward the largest stimulus package in history. In the United States it amounted to $2 trillion, a quarter of which represented transfer payments to households. To the extent that such transfers were (i) announced in advance and (ii) conditional on recipients being unemployed, they mitigated income risk associated with the lockdown—in contrast to unconditional transfers. We develop a baseline scenario for a COVID-19 recession in a medium-scale heterogeneous agent new Keynesian model and use counterfactuals to quantify the impact of transfers. For the short run, we find large differences in the transfer multiplier: it is negligible for unconditional transfers and about unity for conditional transfers. Overall, we find that the transfers reduced the output loss due to the pandemic by some two percentage points at its trough.
The economic fallout of the COVID-19 pandemic was unprecedented. As many businesses and industries were locked down in an effort to limit infections—either voluntarily or by government mandate—unemployment rose sharply. In the ten weeks from mid-March to the end of May 2020 some 40 million initial claims to unemployment benefits were filed in the United States. Panel (a) of Figure 1 shows time-series data, testifying to the exceptional nature of the labour-market developments during the pandemic. A similar picture emerges for the unemployment rate, shown in panel (b). As a result, the COVID-19 pandemic raised income risk for US households strongly—much more so than in a usual recession.1

Unemployment. Panel (a) monthly initial claims to unemployment benefits. Panel (b) monthly unemployment rate, both from 2007 to 2021. Source: FRED Economic Data, St Louis. Fed.
The pandemic also triggered an exceptional fiscal response.2 On 27 March 2020 former President Trump signed the Coronavirus Aid, Relief and Economic Security (CARES) Act into law. As a result, $2 trillion of federal funds were disbursed to households and firms through various channels. The largest items on the household side included, first, a one-time payment of $1,200 to any adult in the US population with a gross income of up to $75,000 and, second, a top up to state unemployment benefits of $600 per week. Under the Federal Pandemic Unemployment Compensation (FPUC) scheme, the unemployed received this sum irrespective of their earlier earnings up until the end of July 2020. Each of these measures triggered additional federal expenditures of some $270 billion. To put this into perspective, recall that the entire American Recovery and Reinvestment Act (ARRA), legislated in 2009 in response to the financial crisis, mobilised some $800 billion of federal spending.
In this paper, we analyse the quantitative impact of the transfer components of the CARES Act and assess to what extent they limited the economic fallout from the COVID-19 pandemic. We proceed in two steps. First, we develop a baseline scenario for the COVID-19 recession. For this purpose, we specify a ‘quarantine shock’, or ‘Q-shock’ for short. Importantly, we abstract entirely from the epidemiological causes that underlie this shock in order to focus on the efficacy of transfers during the COVID-19 recession. Moreover, we are completely agnostic as to whether the Q-shock is imposed by governments or the result of voluntary social restraint: What matters is that as a result of the shock a sizeable fraction of the labour force is locked out of/prefers not to/cannot work for health reasons. In addition, a fraction of the aggregate capital stock and the goods of some sectors also become temporarily unavailable for production and consumption. As a result, the shock not only lowers the production potential of the aggregate economy, it also triggers an unprecedented increase in income risk at the household level, which, in turn, induces the private sector to increase savings. In the baseline, we assume that the Q-shock is fully anticipated. This is a conservative assumption because unemployment recovers more quickly in May 2020 than in previous recessions. While income risk rises sharply, our baseline thus assumes households to know the increase to be of very limited duration.3
Second, we study model-based counterfactuals and investigate how the Coronavirus stimulus shaped the COVID-19 recession. We focus on the transfer payments which households receive in the baseline, both unconditional transfers and transfers that are conditional on the recipient being unemployed.4 Unconditional transfers are part of the recession-fighting toolkit and have been deployed before. The Economic Stimulus Act passed in February 2008 under the Bush administration, for instance, was a $100 billion programme under which taxpayers received a $900 payment (Broda and Parker, 2014). The economic rationale is straightforward: to the extent that households are liquidity or credit constrained, they will spend the largest part of the transfer, even if taxes may go up at some point in the future. This, in turn, may limit the reduction of private expenditure triggered by the recession. By targeting the unemployed, conditional transfers provide more funds per recipient for a fiscal package of a given size. On top of this, they lower income risk associated with becoming unemployed, and thus the need for precautionary savings in response to the Q-shock.
We conduct our analysis within a heterogeneous agent New Keynesian (HANK) model, put forward and estimated by Bayer et al. (2022a,b). It is particularly well suited for the purpose at hand because it features income risk: households face different labour market outcomes and, because financial markets are incomplete, the resulting income risk is not shared across households. The model also features various additional frictions and is able to account for key features of the business cycle. We find that the calibrated version of the model that we use in this paper also captures key aspects of the COVID-19 recession—both along the time-series dimension and in terms of the heterogeneity of labour market outcomes in the cross-section of households. The model predicts the evolution of key macroeconomic indicators during the period 2020/1 quite accurately, even though—with the exception of the unemployment rate—they are not targeted in the calibration of the model. It also accounts well for the incidence and dynamics of unemployment across the income distribution.
We compute the quantitative effect of the CARES transfers through model-based counterfactuals. Absent the transfers, the collapse of economic activity which amounts to about 10% in the baseline would have been larger by almost two percentage points at its through. Also, because the recovery would have been slower without transfers, the cumulative output loss would have been larger by about 13% of monthly GDP. This effect is largely due to conditional transfers. To illustrate this, we compute the cumulative transfer multiplier. In the short run it is about 0.25 for the overall transfer component of the CARES Act, but about 1 for conditional transfers and basically 0 for unconditional transfers. Conditional transfers are effective in stabilising the economy because they are targeted to households with the highest marginal propensity to consume and because they lower income risk.
We also study the distributional consequences and the welfare effects of the Q-shock and the transfer payments. The results are clear cut. The COVID-19 recession led to an increase in inequality across a range of indicators, but the transfers dampened this effect to a considerable extent. A similar picture emerges for welfare. While the pandemic had adverse welfare effects across all wealth groups, they were particularly strong for the poor. The transfers under the CARES Act, in turn, were very effective in offsetting these effects. And while we do not offer a full-fledged analysis of the optimal fiscal response to the pandemic, our simulations show that there are decreasing returns to the transfer payments in terms of macroeconomic stabilisation because of the way they interact with income risk.
The paper is organised as follows. In the remainder of the introduction we clarify the paper’s main message and its connection to the existing literature. Section 1 outlines the model structure. Section 2 explains in detail our parameter choices. We present our results in Section 3, zooming in on the transmission mechanism of both, the Q-shock and the alternative transfer instruments. A final section offers some conclusions.
Our model extends the framework of Bayer et al. (2022a,b), first, by introducing two new labour market states. In this way we account for the fact that workers face the risk of not being able to work, be it because of sickness, actual quarantine or more general lockdowns. Second, we assume that product varieties, as well as the capital stock used in production, are ‘quarantined’ in the same way and temporarily unavailable for consumption and production. Third, we model the actual fiscal transfers that were legislated in response to the pandemic. Additionally, we calibrate monetary policy to match the observed path of interest rates instead of using estimated monetary policy rules from pre-pandemic times. In addition, rather than allowing for an array of shocks to hit the economy, we focus on the unique circumstances of the COVID-19 pandemic. These modifications are important, because we want the model to account for short-term unemployment risk and fluctuations in product varieties as drivers of the recession and to study targeted transfers which have been absent from previous work.
Related work by, among others, Kaplan et al. (2020) and Guerrieri et al. (2022), share with our work some of these features. Specifically, the notion that the limited availability of product varieties are important to understand inflation and business cycle dynamics during the COVID-19 recession is due to Guerrieri et al. (2022). Moving beyond their work, we embed this aspect in a quantitative dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) model that also features household heterogeneity. Similar to Kaplan et al. (2020), we show that it is important to consider heterogeneity at the household level to understand the full consequences of the COVID-19 pandemic. The focus on the role of different types of transfers distinguishes our work from theirs. Our findings suggest that both the demand shortages due to temporarily unavailable products and services and the sharp increase in income risk are important to understand the COVID-19 recession. In particular, the sharp rise in income risk is what makes additional insurance provided by the CARES package individually valuable for affected households, and gives rise to additional aggregate stabilisation.
A more conventional model would not allow us to capture the workings of CARES transfers correctly. This holds true, in particular, for two-agent new Keynesian (TANK) models. Coenen et al. (2012), for instance, offer a systematic analysis of transfer multipliers in seven large-scale TANK models. They find that transfers targeted to liquidity constrained households can give rise to sizeable multipliers provided the zero lower bound binds, a result further refined in later work (Bilbiie et al., 2013; Giambattista and Pennings, 2017; Mehrotra, 2018; Bilbiie, 2020; Faria-e-Castro, 2022). TANK models have also been used to study the transfers during the COVID-19 recession. Faria-e-Castro (2021) finds that the unemployment benefits multiplier is larger during the COVID-19 recession than in normal times. Bhattarai et al. (2021) show that the transfer multiplier depends on the monetary-fiscal mix.5 Importantly, TANK models do not account for household income risk which is at the core of our analysis.
Yet there is work which considers incomplete markets and income risk while studying the transfer multiplier. Oh and Reis (2012) perform a quantitative analysis of the transfers of the ARRA package in a model with household heterogeneity and sticky information. They find very small transfer multipliers on output, even though they assume that transfers are targeted to households with a high marginal propensity to consume. Likewise, McKay and Reis (2016) and Hagedorn et al. (2019) obtain moderate tax and transfer multipliers in calibrated versions of one-asset HANK models. Moving beyond these papers, we model wealthy hand-to-mouth households as introduced by Kaplan and Violante (2014). They show in partial equilibrium that illiquid wealth can rationalise sizeable consumption responses to transfers and low levels of consumption insurance. By using a similar setup in a new Keynesian model, the distinct contribution of our analysis is to show that conditional transfers in deep recessions lower income risk and thereby generate sizeable multiplier effects, in line with earlier work on unemployment benefits as automatic stabilisers (Den Haan et al., 2017; Ravn and Sterk, 2017; McKay and Reis, 2021; Kekre, 2022).
We believe that some of our results, such as the effectiveness of counter-cyclical unemployment benefits, are fairly general and may inform the government response to other recessions. However, some of our results, including those related to products and services becoming temporarily unavailable, are specific to the COVID-19 recession, because they are due to measures that are meant to protect individual or public health. In order to explore potential trade-offs between health protection and economic welfare, a number of studies develop explicit microfoundations of the interaction between economic activity and infection dynamics (Boppart et al., 2020; Eichenbaum et al., 2021; Glover et al., 2021). Instead, because we consider our model as a laboratory to study the properties of alternative fiscal transfers, we account for the feedback from economic activity to the state of the pandemic via a straightforward reduced-form relationship.
1. Model
The model and our exposition here closely follow Bayer et al. (2022a,b), extended to capture the economic fallout from the COVID-19 pandemic. We use the same general setup for the economy: it is composed of a firm sector, a household sector and a government sector. In the firm sector, we define several layers in order to maintain tractability. There is a continuum of isomorphic final-goods sectors, each characterised by monopolistic competition. Final goods producers rely on homogeneous intermediate inputs provided by perfectly competitive intermediate goods producers. Capital goods, in turn, are produced on the basis of final goods, subject to adjustment costs. Labour services are assembled on the basis of differentiated labour types provided by unions that, in turn, differentiate the raw labour input of households. Price setting for the final goods, as well as wage setting by unions is subject to nominal rigidities. Households earn income from supplying (raw) labour and capital and from owning the firm sector, absorbing all of its rents that stem from the market power of unions and final goods producers, and decreasing returns to scale in capital goods production. The government sector runs both a fiscal authority and a monetary authority. The fiscal authority levies taxes on labour income and distributed pure profits (monopoly rents), issues government bonds and adjusts expenditures to stabilise debt in the long run. The monetary authority sets the nominal interest rate on government bonds according to a Taylor rule targeting inflation and output growth.
To study the pandemic, we add short-term unemployment risk, unemployment insurance and transfers to the model of Bayer et al. (2022b), but, most importantly, we introduce the idea of ‘quarantines’, the Q-shock. Quarantines imply that a fraction of the workforce, a fraction of the capital stock and a fraction of sectors can no longer supply their services, be it because of a government mandated lockdown, be it because of actual infections or be it because consumers shy away from demanding the services to avoid infections themselves. This creates a recession environment that is characterised by a shortage of factor supplies, an increase in individual income risks and, as explained in detail by Guerrieri et al. (2022), by Keynesian supply shocks. These demand spillovers across sectors depend crucially on the elasticity of substitution across the goods produced in different sectors. Hence, we allow it to differ from the elasticity of substitution within sectors.
1.1. Households
The household sector is subdivided into two types of agents: workers and entrepreneurs. The transition between both types is stochastic. Both rent out physical capital, but only workers supply labour. The efficiency of a worker’s labour evolves randomly, exposing worker households to labour-income risk. Entrepreneurs do not work, but earn all pure rents in our economy except for the rents of unions, which are equally distributed across workers. All households self-insure against the income risks they face by saving in a liquid nominal asset (bonds) and a less liquid asset (capital). Trading illiquid assets is subject to random participation in the capital market.
To be specific, there is a continuum of ex ante identical households of measure one, indexed by i. Households are infinitely lived, have time-separable preferences with discount factor |$\beta$| and derive felicity from consumption |$c_{\textit {it}}$| and leisure. They obtain income from supplying labour, |$n_{\textit {it}}$|, from renting out capital, |$k_{\textit {it}}$|, from earning interest on bonds, |$b_{\textit {it}}$|, and, potentially, from unemployment benefits, firm profits or union transfers. Households pay taxes on labour and profit income.
A key economic aspect of the pandemic is that, beyond usual levels of unemployment, a substantially larger fraction of workers is locked out of work. We capture this in our model by having, next to a regular unemployment state, a COVID unemployment state; a ‘quarantine’. To model the aggregate shock to the economy, we let the probability of entering this state vary over time and calibrate it to be a very rare state in the steady state.
1.1.1. Productivity, labour supply and labour income
The entry into unemployment |$p_\mathcal{U}^{in}$| and the exit probabilities, |$p_\mathcal{Q}^{out, \mathcal {E/U}}$| and |$p_\mathcal{U}^{out}$|, are time-constant. From quarantine, the |$\mathcal {Q}$|-state, workers can go back to employment, |$\mathcal {E}$|, with probability |$p_\mathcal{Q}^{out, \mathcal {E}}$| or become regularly unemployed, |$\mathcal {U}$|, with probability |$p_\mathcal{Q}^{out, \mathcal {U}}$|.
The regular unemployed obtain unemployment benefits according to the US unemployment system which has a constant replacement rate that is, however, capped at 50% of the median income. The ‘quarantined’ workers obtain an additional unemployment benefit on top of the payments received in the |$\mathcal {U}$|-state, as described in Section 3.1. Employed households earn gross labour income |$w_{t} n_{\textit {it}} h_{\textit {it}}$|. Some employed households become entrepreneurs with fixed probability |$\zeta$| and return to the median employed state with probability |$\iota$|. An entrepreneur obtains a fixed share of the pure rents (aside from union rents), |$\Pi _t^F$|, in the economy (from monopolistic competition in the goods sector and the creation of capital).7 We assume that the claim to the pure rents cannot be traded as an asset. Union rents, |$\Pi _t^U$|, are distributed lump sum across workers, leading to labour-income compression.
Without further loss of generality, we can normalise the disutility of labour: |$G(h_{\textit {it}},n_{\textit {it}})=h_{\textit {it}} \frac{n_{\textit {it}}^{1+\gamma }}{1+\gamma }$|. This simplifies the household problem as |$h_{\textit {it}}$| drops out from the first-order condition. All employed households supply the same number of hours |$n_{\textit {it}}=N(w_t)$|, and income and productivity risk are the same. We denote by |$\bar{H}_t$| the total number of active workers |$\int \mathbb {I}_{e_{\textit {it}}=\mathcal {E}}di$|. We assume that the same fraction, |$\bar{H}_t$|, of final-goods sectors and capital is active, too. For the total effective labour supply, we need to take heterogeneity into account and obtain this as |$N(w_t) H_t$|, where |$H_t:=\int \mathbb {I}_{e_{\textit {it}}=\mathcal {E}} h_{\textit {it}} di$| is the productivity weighted share of active workers.
1.1.2. Consumption, savings and portfolio choice
Households make their savings choices and their portfolio choice between liquid bonds and illiquid capital in light of a capital market friction that renders capital illiquid, because participation in the capital market is random and independent and identically distributed (i.i.d.), in the sense that only a fraction, |$\lambda$|, of households is selected to be able to adjust their capital holdings in a given period.
1.2. Firm Sector
The firm sector consists of four sub-sectors: (a) a labour sector composed of ‘unions’ that differentiate raw labour and labour packers who buy differentiated labour, and then sell labour services to intermediate goods producers, (b) intermediate goods producers who hire labour services and rent out capital to produce goods, (c) final goods producers who differentiate intermediate goods and then sell them to goods bundlers, who finally sell them as consumption goods to households and (d) capital goods producers, who turn bundled final goods into capital goods.
When profit maximisation decisions in the firm sector require intertemporal decisions (i.e., in price and wage setting and in producing capital goods), we assume for tractability that they are delegated to a mass-zero group of households (managers) that are risk neutral and compensated by a share in profits.9 They do not participate in any asset market and have the same discount factor as all other households. Given that managers are a mass-zero group in the economy, their consumption does not show up in any resource constraint, and all but the unions’ profits go to the entrepreneur households (whose |$h=0$|). Union profits go lump sum to worker households.
1.2.1. Labour packers and unions
1.2.2. Final goods producers
Given that all sectors are symmetric and sectors are shut down randomly after price setting, all firms choose the same price when resetting it. Therefore, all sectoral price levels |$P_{kt}=( \int _{j\in S(k)} p_{jt}^{1-\eta _F }dj) ^{\frac{1}{1-\eta _F }}$| are the same and we denote this price level by |$P_{kt}=P^F_t$|. Yet, it implies a loss in final consumption to the households that only the fraction of sectors can actually offer their varieties (|$\psi _{kt}=1$|). This fraction is the same as the fraction of workers in |$\mathcal {E}$|, |$\bar{H}_t$|. Consumers lose out on varieties and this introduces a wedge, |$\bar{H}_t ^\frac{1}{1-\eta _S}$|, between the average price set by all firms, |$P^F_{t}$|, and the effective |$P_t$| of the consumption aggregate (the ideal price index): |$P_t = P^F_t \bar{H}_t^\frac{1}{1-\eta _S}$|. Vice versa, it implies that the real value of total output |$Y_t$| is by factor |$\bar{H}_t^\frac{1}{\eta _S -1}$| smaller than the quantity of intermediate goods produced.
Importantly, the ‘love of variety’ term |$\bar{H}_{t} ^\frac{1}{\eta _S -1}$| adds an element of ‘as if perfectly flexible’ prices to the model. In the first period in which the quarantine shock hits, some varieties are lost and |$\bar{H}_{t}$| falls. As a consequence, the effective price level jumps up even if all individual prices remain constant because households cannot perfectly substitute the lost varieties. As households expect the quarantine to be reduced in the future, they expect varieties to return and, hence, a falling effective price level from the love-of-variety component. This deflationary effect of the return of varieties to the consumption basket increases the real interest rate that households face and leads them to save more. This is the key mechanism behind the ‘Keynesian supply shocks’ in Guerrieri et al. (2022, sect. 3.1).
1.2.3. Intermediate goods producers
Total production |$Y_t = \bar{H}_t^\frac{1}{\eta _S -1} Y^F_t$| is scaled by an additional term |$\bar{H}_t^\frac{1}{\eta _S -1}$|, which reflects the fact that the loss in varieties through the quarantine decreases the effective productivity of the economy even further.
1.2.4. Capital goods producers
1.3. Government
The government operates a monetary and a fiscal authority. The monetary authority controls the nominal interest rate on liquid assets, while the fiscal authority issues government bonds to finance deficits and adjusts expenditures to stabilise debt in the long run.
1.4. Goods, Bonds, Capital and Labour Market Clearing
2. Parameterisation
We solve the model by perturbation methods (Bayer and Luetticke, 2020; Bayer et al., 2022b) and parameterise the model at monthly frequency in the following way. First, we calibrate or fix all parameters that determine the steady state of the model. Second, we specify the values of those parameters that govern the dynamics of the model in line with estimates from the literature.
Table 1 summarises all parameter values. On the household side, we model the |$\mathcal {U}$|-state as regular unemployment. We target an unemployment rate of 6% and an average duration of 5 months in line with US data for the period 1980–2019, which yields |$p_{\mathcal{U}}^{in}=1.2\%$| and |$p_{\mathcal{U}}^{out}=20\%$|. The |$\mathcal {Q}$|-state, by contrast, is a rare state with probability mass in the steady state of almost zero (|$p_{\mathcal{Q},ss}^{in}=0.03\%$|). In both states, households receive government transfers that replace 25% of their after-tax labour income capped at 50% of median income.12 Households in the |$\mathcal {Q}$|-state receive an additional $2,400 per month. The exit probability from the |$\mathcal {Q}$|-state is 33.33% per month (|$p_\mathcal{Q}^{out,\mathcal {E}} + p_\mathcal{Q}^{out,\mathcal {U}} = 1/3$|) so that the expected lockdown duration is 3 months. When exiting the |$\mathcal {Q}$|-state, there is a 75%-chance of directly being employed. In our experiments in the next section, the aggregate Q-shock increases |$p_{\mathcal{Q},t}^{in}$|, the probability of entering the |$\mathcal {Q}$|-state. As explained, we allow the probability of entering the |$\mathcal {Q}$|-state to depend on labour productivity. In particular, we match the incidence of job losses across the income distribution during March/April 2020 as documented in Mongey et al. (2021).13 For that purpose, we assume that the likelihood of entering the |$\mathcal {Q}$|-state is described by a logistic function in labour income, where the probability for the 25th percentile of the income distribution is three times higher than for the 75th percentile. The parameters of process (1) are set to |$\rho _Q = 0.86$| and |$\Sigma _{Q,Y}=0.04$| in order to match aggregate unemployment dynamics, as discussed in more detail in Subsection 3.1.
Parameter . | Value . | Description . | Parameter . | Value . | Description . |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Households | Nominal frictions | ||||
|$\beta$| | 0.99 | Discount factor | |$\kappa _Y$| | 0.009 | Price rigidity |
|$\xi$| | 4.00 | Relative risk aversion | |$\kappa _w$| | 0.011 | Wage rigidity |
|$\gamma$| | 2.00 | Inverse Frisch elasticity | Firms | ||
|$\lambda$| | 5.00% | Portfolio adj. prob. | |$\alpha$| | 0.68 | Share of labour |
Idiosyncratic productivity | |$\delta _0$| | 0.58% | Depreciation rate | ||
|$\rho _h$| | 0.99 | Persistence | |$\eta _F$| | 11.00 | Elasticity within sectors |
|$\sigma _h$| | 6.93% | Standard deviation | |$\eta _S$| | 3.50 | Elasticity between sectors |
|$\zeta$| | 0.02% | Trans. prob. W. |$\rightarrow$| E. | |$\eta _W$| | 11.00 | Elasticity of substitution |
|$\iota$| | 2.37% | Trans. prob. E. |$\rightarrow$| W. | Monetary Policy | ||
Labour market transitions | |$\rho _R$| | 0.93 | Inertia | ||
|$p_{\mathcal{Q},ss}^{in}$| | 0.03% | Trans. prob. |$\mathcal {E} \rightarrow \mathcal {Q}$| | |$\theta _\pi$| | 1.50 | Inflation reaction |
|$p_\mathcal{Q}^{out,\mathcal {E}}$| | 25.00% | Trans. prob. |$\mathcal {Q} \rightarrow \mathcal {E}$| | |$\theta _Y$| | 0.20 | Output reaction |
|$p_\mathcal{Q}^{out,\mathcal {U}}$| | 8.33% | Trans. prob. |$\mathcal {Q} \rightarrow \mathcal {U}$| | Fiscal Policy | ||
|$p_{\mathcal{U}}^{in}$| | 1.20% | Trans. prob. |$\mathcal {E} \rightarrow \mathcal {U}$| | |$\rho _G$| | 0.98 | Inertia spending |
|$p_\mathcal{U}^{out}$| | 20.00% | Trans. prob. |$\mathcal {U} \rightarrow \mathcal {E}$| | |$\gamma _{B}^G$| | −0.75 | Reaction debt |
Q-process | |$\tau$| | 0.20 | Tax rate level | ||
|$\rho _Q$| | 0.86 | Autocorrelation | Real frictions | ||
|$\Sigma _{Q,Y}$| | 0.04 | Feedback activity |$\rightarrow Q$| | |$\delta _s$| | 1.289 | Capital utilisation |
|$\phi$| | 1.000 | Investment adjustment |
Parameter . | Value . | Description . | Parameter . | Value . | Description . |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Households | Nominal frictions | ||||
|$\beta$| | 0.99 | Discount factor | |$\kappa _Y$| | 0.009 | Price rigidity |
|$\xi$| | 4.00 | Relative risk aversion | |$\kappa _w$| | 0.011 | Wage rigidity |
|$\gamma$| | 2.00 | Inverse Frisch elasticity | Firms | ||
|$\lambda$| | 5.00% | Portfolio adj. prob. | |$\alpha$| | 0.68 | Share of labour |
Idiosyncratic productivity | |$\delta _0$| | 0.58% | Depreciation rate | ||
|$\rho _h$| | 0.99 | Persistence | |$\eta _F$| | 11.00 | Elasticity within sectors |
|$\sigma _h$| | 6.93% | Standard deviation | |$\eta _S$| | 3.50 | Elasticity between sectors |
|$\zeta$| | 0.02% | Trans. prob. W. |$\rightarrow$| E. | |$\eta _W$| | 11.00 | Elasticity of substitution |
|$\iota$| | 2.37% | Trans. prob. E. |$\rightarrow$| W. | Monetary Policy | ||
Labour market transitions | |$\rho _R$| | 0.93 | Inertia | ||
|$p_{\mathcal{Q},ss}^{in}$| | 0.03% | Trans. prob. |$\mathcal {E} \rightarrow \mathcal {Q}$| | |$\theta _\pi$| | 1.50 | Inflation reaction |
|$p_\mathcal{Q}^{out,\mathcal {E}}$| | 25.00% | Trans. prob. |$\mathcal {Q} \rightarrow \mathcal {E}$| | |$\theta _Y$| | 0.20 | Output reaction |
|$p_\mathcal{Q}^{out,\mathcal {U}}$| | 8.33% | Trans. prob. |$\mathcal {Q} \rightarrow \mathcal {U}$| | Fiscal Policy | ||
|$p_{\mathcal{U}}^{in}$| | 1.20% | Trans. prob. |$\mathcal {E} \rightarrow \mathcal {U}$| | |$\rho _G$| | 0.98 | Inertia spending |
|$p_\mathcal{U}^{out}$| | 20.00% | Trans. prob. |$\mathcal {U} \rightarrow \mathcal {E}$| | |$\gamma _{B}^G$| | −0.75 | Reaction debt |
Q-process | |$\tau$| | 0.20 | Tax rate level | ||
|$\rho _Q$| | 0.86 | Autocorrelation | Real frictions | ||
|$\Sigma _{Q,Y}$| | 0.04 | Feedback activity |$\rightarrow Q$| | |$\delta _s$| | 1.289 | Capital utilisation |
|$\phi$| | 1.000 | Investment adjustment |
Parameter . | Value . | Description . | Parameter . | Value . | Description . |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Households | Nominal frictions | ||||
|$\beta$| | 0.99 | Discount factor | |$\kappa _Y$| | 0.009 | Price rigidity |
|$\xi$| | 4.00 | Relative risk aversion | |$\kappa _w$| | 0.011 | Wage rigidity |
|$\gamma$| | 2.00 | Inverse Frisch elasticity | Firms | ||
|$\lambda$| | 5.00% | Portfolio adj. prob. | |$\alpha$| | 0.68 | Share of labour |
Idiosyncratic productivity | |$\delta _0$| | 0.58% | Depreciation rate | ||
|$\rho _h$| | 0.99 | Persistence | |$\eta _F$| | 11.00 | Elasticity within sectors |
|$\sigma _h$| | 6.93% | Standard deviation | |$\eta _S$| | 3.50 | Elasticity between sectors |
|$\zeta$| | 0.02% | Trans. prob. W. |$\rightarrow$| E. | |$\eta _W$| | 11.00 | Elasticity of substitution |
|$\iota$| | 2.37% | Trans. prob. E. |$\rightarrow$| W. | Monetary Policy | ||
Labour market transitions | |$\rho _R$| | 0.93 | Inertia | ||
|$p_{\mathcal{Q},ss}^{in}$| | 0.03% | Trans. prob. |$\mathcal {E} \rightarrow \mathcal {Q}$| | |$\theta _\pi$| | 1.50 | Inflation reaction |
|$p_\mathcal{Q}^{out,\mathcal {E}}$| | 25.00% | Trans. prob. |$\mathcal {Q} \rightarrow \mathcal {E}$| | |$\theta _Y$| | 0.20 | Output reaction |
|$p_\mathcal{Q}^{out,\mathcal {U}}$| | 8.33% | Trans. prob. |$\mathcal {Q} \rightarrow \mathcal {U}$| | Fiscal Policy | ||
|$p_{\mathcal{U}}^{in}$| | 1.20% | Trans. prob. |$\mathcal {E} \rightarrow \mathcal {U}$| | |$\rho _G$| | 0.98 | Inertia spending |
|$p_\mathcal{U}^{out}$| | 20.00% | Trans. prob. |$\mathcal {U} \rightarrow \mathcal {E}$| | |$\gamma _{B}^G$| | −0.75 | Reaction debt |
Q-process | |$\tau$| | 0.20 | Tax rate level | ||
|$\rho _Q$| | 0.86 | Autocorrelation | Real frictions | ||
|$\Sigma _{Q,Y}$| | 0.04 | Feedback activity |$\rightarrow Q$| | |$\delta _s$| | 1.289 | Capital utilisation |
|$\phi$| | 1.000 | Investment adjustment |
Parameter . | Value . | Description . | Parameter . | Value . | Description . |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Households | Nominal frictions | ||||
|$\beta$| | 0.99 | Discount factor | |$\kappa _Y$| | 0.009 | Price rigidity |
|$\xi$| | 4.00 | Relative risk aversion | |$\kappa _w$| | 0.011 | Wage rigidity |
|$\gamma$| | 2.00 | Inverse Frisch elasticity | Firms | ||
|$\lambda$| | 5.00% | Portfolio adj. prob. | |$\alpha$| | 0.68 | Share of labour |
Idiosyncratic productivity | |$\delta _0$| | 0.58% | Depreciation rate | ||
|$\rho _h$| | 0.99 | Persistence | |$\eta _F$| | 11.00 | Elasticity within sectors |
|$\sigma _h$| | 6.93% | Standard deviation | |$\eta _S$| | 3.50 | Elasticity between sectors |
|$\zeta$| | 0.02% | Trans. prob. W. |$\rightarrow$| E. | |$\eta _W$| | 11.00 | Elasticity of substitution |
|$\iota$| | 2.37% | Trans. prob. E. |$\rightarrow$| W. | Monetary Policy | ||
Labour market transitions | |$\rho _R$| | 0.93 | Inertia | ||
|$p_{\mathcal{Q},ss}^{in}$| | 0.03% | Trans. prob. |$\mathcal {E} \rightarrow \mathcal {Q}$| | |$\theta _\pi$| | 1.50 | Inflation reaction |
|$p_\mathcal{Q}^{out,\mathcal {E}}$| | 25.00% | Trans. prob. |$\mathcal {Q} \rightarrow \mathcal {E}$| | |$\theta _Y$| | 0.20 | Output reaction |
|$p_\mathcal{Q}^{out,\mathcal {U}}$| | 8.33% | Trans. prob. |$\mathcal {Q} \rightarrow \mathcal {U}$| | Fiscal Policy | ||
|$p_{\mathcal{U}}^{in}$| | 1.20% | Trans. prob. |$\mathcal {E} \rightarrow \mathcal {U}$| | |$\rho _G$| | 0.98 | Inertia spending |
|$p_\mathcal{U}^{out}$| | 20.00% | Trans. prob. |$\mathcal {U} \rightarrow \mathcal {E}$| | |$\gamma _{B}^G$| | −0.75 | Reaction debt |
Q-process | |$\tau$| | 0.20 | Tax rate level | ||
|$\rho _Q$| | 0.86 | Autocorrelation | Real frictions | ||
|$\Sigma _{Q,Y}$| | 0.04 | Feedback activity |$\rightarrow Q$| | |$\delta _s$| | 1.289 | Capital utilisation |
|$\phi$| | 1.000 | Investment adjustment |
We take estimates for idiosyncratic income risk (after tax and transfers) from Storesletten et al. (2004), assuming |$\rho _h=0.993$| and |$\bar{\sigma }_h=0.069$|. Guvenen et al. (2014) provide the probability that a household will fall out of the top 1% of the income distribution in a given year, which we take as the transition probability from entrepreneur to worker, |$\iota =2.37\%$|.
We set the relative risk aversion to 4, which is common in the incomplete markets literature; see Kaplan and Violante (2014). We set the Frisch elasticity to 0.5; see Chetty et al. (2011). For the calibration of the remaining household parameters, we match four targets: (1) average illiquid assets (K/Y = 286% annual); (2) average liquidity (B/Y = 47% annual); (3) the fraction of borrowers, 16%; and (4) the average top 10% share of wealth, which is 67%. This yields a monthly discount factor of 0.991, a monthly portfolio adjustment probability of |$5.0\%$|, a borrowing limit of two average monthly incomes and a transition probability from worker to entrepreneur of |$0.02\%$|.14
For the firm side, we set the elasticity of substitution between differentiated goods within a sector to 11, which yields a markup of 10%. The labour share in production, |$\alpha$|, is |$68\%$|, implying a labour income share of |$62\%$|, given the 10% markup. The elasticity of substitution between labour varieties is also set to 11, yielding a wage markup of 10%, which is, however, redistributed to workers, leaving the labour income share unchanged. The depreciation rate is |$0.58\%$| per month. All these are standard values in the literature. We set the elasticity of substitution across sectors to 3.5, somewhat below the intertemporal elasticity of substitution. This ensures that the Q-shock shares the features of a ‘Keynesian supply shock’ as put forward by Guerrieri et al. (2022), in addition to raising the income risk of households.
The government taxes labour and profit income. The level of taxes in the steady state, |$\tau$|, is set to clear the government budget constraint at a level of government spending that amounts to 15% of output. As we have assumed indexation to the steady-state inflation rate in the Phillips curves, we set the steady-state inflation rate without loss of generality to zero. The steady-state net interest rate is set to 0.0%, too, in order to capture the average federal funds rate in real terms minus output growth.
The Taylor rule coefficients on inflation, 1.5, output growth, 0.2, and interest rate inertia, 0.93 at a monthly level, are in line with the literature. The fiscal rule that governs spending is parameterised to ensure that public debt is slowly brought back to the steady state after a debt build-up. The parameters that govern the real and nominal frictions are set to the values estimated via Bayesian methods by Bayer et al. (2022b). The parameter values for nominal frictions are in line with the representative-agent literature, with price and wage stickiness being less than 12 months on average.
3. Results
Having set up and calibrated the model, we use it to quantify the effects of the CARES transfers. In a first step, we develop our baseline scenario for which we expose the model economy to the quarantine shock, or ‘Q-shock’ for short. We specify the shock in such a way that the model predictions match the actual developments of the unemployment rate during 2020/1, because the exceptionally strong rise of US unemployment is one of the defining features of the COVID-19 recession. Next, we benchmark the predictions of the model for other variables against actual developments and find the model performs rather well.
To assess the effect of the Coronavirus stimulus—which is put in place under the baseline scenario—we study a counterfactual where the stimulus is switched off. For the entire package, we find a transfer multiplier of about 0.5. As we explore systematically the determinants of the multiplier, we identify a number of important aspects. In particular, the multiplier of the conditional transfer, that is, the Federal Pandemic Unemployment Compensation (FPUC), exceeds 1 when it comes online because it limits the idiosyncratic income risk triggered by the Q-shock. Finally, we also look at the distributional and welfare consequences of the Q-shock and the CARES package. Here, we find that the shock itself has significant welfare costs, especially for those households that lack financial resources to self-insure, and the CARES package is well able to eliminate these negative welfare consequences.
3.1. The Q-shock
In our model, the COVID-19 recession is caused by the Q-shock: it causes a reduction of the level of economic activity—either voluntary to avoid infection risk or mandated via lockdowns—and applies to workers, capital and final-goods sectors alike. While the Q-shock causes exogenously a reduction of activity, the model allows for feedback from economic activity to the state of the pandemic. In the model, we capture such feedback via a stylised rule and omit microfoundations developed elsewhere (see, e.g., Eichenbaum et al., 2021).
While under quarantine, final goods are temporarily unavailable for consumption; capital and workers, in turn, do not receive market income. Workers that lose their income and job because of the Q-shock qualify for FPUC which provides, on top of regular unemployment benefits to which an individual is entitled to under state laws, a $600 benefit for each week of unemployment between 5 April 2020 and 31 July 2020. After July 2020 a number of additional assistance measures were put in place, but they were only available for a limited time, and we abstract from those payments in order to measure the effect of the transfers under the CARES Act as initially specified.
To determine the size and the persistence of the Q-shock, as well as the endogenous feedback from the economy to the state of the pandemic determined by (1), we target the actual time path of the unemployment rate. As a result, the total amount of FPUC payments in the model sums to $274 billion during 2020, which is very close to the actual amount of $265 billion.15 Specifically, we assume innovations to the Q-shock process in March, April and May 2020, such that the average quarantine risk amounts to 1, 11 and 3%, respectively. Thereafter, there are no further innovations to the Q-process.16 The sequence of innovations to the Q-shock process becomes fully known in February (‘period 1’), that is, innovations are modelled as ‘news shocks’. As a result, the future path of the probability to enter the |$\mathcal {Q}$|-state is fully known and there is no aggregate risk. However, income risk at the individual level is very high because it is unclear which worker will end up in the |$\mathcal {Q}$|-state. That said, we stress that our baseline is still conservative because the 3% quarantine risk for May is considerably below what would be observed without the anticipated innovation for May. In a series of robustness checks on the information structure, we first consider a variant with incomplete anticipation, such that households expect in March a much higher income risk in May and are positively surprised in April. Second, we consider an alternative that features an anticipated second wave of quarantines in late 2020.
Given the parameterisation detailed in Section 2, we pick the parameter values which govern the endogenous feedback from aggregate activity to the |$Q_t$| process, |$\Sigma _{Q,Y}$|, and its autocorrelation, |$\rho _Q$|, to target the sharp decline in unemployment rates between May and September 2020, and the relatively flat tail between September 2020 and September 2021. Note that our parameterisation also implies that workers in the |$\mathcal {Q}$|-state have a seven times higher likelihood to become regularly unemployed than employed workers have (in the |$\mathcal {E}$|-state).
Besides the FPUC payments that are linked in our model to the |$\mathcal {Q}$|-state, the CARES Act also established another transfer: a one-time payment of $1,200 to everybody, except for households in the top 10% of the income distribution. This is a minor form of conditionality and we capture this in the model by linking it to productivity h. Still, in what follows, we refer to it, to highlight the difference to the FPUC payments, as ‘unconditional transfers’. In the simulations, we assume that, as of March 2020, these payments are known to arrive in April. The total transfer to an entitled person amounts to $1,200 and $283 billion in total. In the aggregate, the two transfer components are thus of approximately the same size.
By construction, the model captures the actual development of the unemployment rate during the COVID-19 recession, as panel (a) of Figure 2 illustrates. Here, and in what follows, the horizontal axis measures time at monthly frequency from February 2020 to December 2021. The predictions of the model are shown by the solid line and compared to the data shown by the dotted line. The vertical axis measures the deviation (in percentage points) from the pre-shock level observed in February 2020. Total unemployment peaks in April at 11 percentage points (above its February level) and declines afterwards. In the other panels of the same figure, we zoom in on the evolution of income tercile-specific unemployment rates as predicted by the model, and contrast it with the actual developments of the unemployment rate for three distinct education groups: no high school or high school graduates without college or less (panel b), some college (panel c), and bachelor degree (panel d), as reported in the FRED database maintained at the St. Louis Fed. Each of the three groups represents roughly one-third of the labour force. It turns out that the model predictions for the incidence of unemployment across the three terciles captures the actual developments for the three education groups rather well. A key aspect of these developments is that the incidence of the unemployment rate is considerably higher in the low-income group (panel b). Here the unemployment rate peaks some 15 percentage points above its pre-shock level. For the high-income group (panel d), the peak is at about six percentage points only. This is consistent with evidence reported by Mongey et al. (2021) and Cortes and Forsythe (2022), which shows that low-education and low-income occupations were indeed disproportionately exposed to the pandemic shock.

Unemployment Rate. Unemployment rate is measured in percentage-point detrended deviation from February 2020 level; solid line is model prediction, dotted line represents data.
In Figure 3, panel (a), we decompose the increase of the total unemployment rate into the underlying states. Initially, all additional unemployed are in the |$\mathcal {Q}$|-state (dotted line) and, hence, receive FPUC in addition to regular unemployment benefits. Over time, as more and more workers exit the |$\mathcal {Q}$|-state, the number of workers in regular unemployment increases, but the increase remains moderate compared to the initial jump of the unemployment rate. As a result, about two-thirds of the FPUC is paid out in the period up to July 2020.17 Because the FPUC payments are relatively large and do not vary with income, they imply replacement rates that are falling in income. This is shown in panel (b) of Figure 3. The replacement rate for regular unemployment benefits is shown in a dark shade and the one implied by the FPUC in a light shade, for each of the nine equally large income groups which we track in the state-space of the model (roughly deciles of the income distribution). For regular unemployment benefits our model calibration implies a replacement rate of 25%, and homogeneously across the income distribution. Accounting for FPUC, raises the replacement rate to more than 150% at the bottom of the income distribution. It also raises it at the top, but much less so. That replacement rates for the unemployed exceeded 100% because of the FPUC has been widely discussed (Ganong et al., 2020). In fact, as we show below, this feature of the CARES package adds to its effectiveness in terms of stabilising economic activity.

Unemployment States and Replacement Rates. Panel (a) shows composition of total unemployed (solid line) into those with FPUC (dotted line) and those with only regular unemployment benefits (dashed line). Panel (b) shows replacement rates across income states, both in the regular |$\mathcal {U}$|-state (bottom darker part) and the top-up in |$\mathcal {Q}$|-state (top lighter part).
3.2. The COVID-19 Recession
We have specified the Q-shock, such that model prediction for the unemployment rate aligns well with actual developments. We now turn to the model predictions for the broader macroeconomic impact of the Q-shock, comparing predictions for the behaviour of selected variables to their empirical counterparts. For this purpose, we remove (when necessary) an HP-trend from the actual time-series data and consider the developments from February 2020 to December 2021, relative to the pre-shock period.18 In our discussion, we abstract from the effects of other shocks, assuming effectively that the macroeconomic developments during 2020/1 have been dominated by the pandemic. The dotted line in Figure 4 shows the data, the solid line the model prediction under the baseline which—importantly—features the CARES transfers payments as discussed in the previous section.

Impulse Responses to Q-shock. For details on data see Online Appendix A. Output, consumption and investment are deflated with the actual price index |$P_t^F$| rather than the ideal price index |$P_t$|. Panel (e) depicts annualised month-on-month inflation rate (based on |$P_t^F$|), measured against the left axis (model) and against the right axis (right). Y-axis: Percentage deviation from steady state, annualised percentage points in case of (month-on-month) inflation and interest rate. X-axis: months.
Panel (a) in Figure 4 shows the adjustment of output which contracts sharply: Relative to the pre-COVID level, output declines by 10%. Here the prediction of the model is right on track: the maximum effect is very similar and takes place only a little bit earlier compared to the data (cf. the solid and the dotted lines). The recovery of economic activity predicted by the model is also very similar to the actual developments, even though it is a little bit slower towards the end of the period under consideration. We show the adjustment of consumption and investment in panels (b) and (c) of Figure 4. Again we observe that the predictions of the model align quite well with actual developments, although the model overpredicts the drop in investment somewhat. In any case, it bears noting that the contraction of consumption is stronger than the response of investment, both according to the data and the model. This pattern sets the COVID-19 recession apart from more conventional business cycles. Panel (d) shows the response of public debt, measured in percent of current output (and relative to the January level). It increases sharply, but less so in the model than in the data. This is unsurprising because the CARES package also features a number of additional expenditure items which we do not consider in our analysis. Towards the end of the period under consideration, the actual debt-to-output ratio declines rather swiftly because output rebounds. Nevertheless, the pandemic and the CARES package leave their mark on public debt for an extended period.
The developments of inflation are shown in panel (e) of Figure 4. Here, the model predictions fail to capture the actual dynamics observed during 2020/1 from a quantitative point of view.19 For this reason, we measure the model predictions against the left axis and the data against the right axis. Initially, the monthly inflation rate drops sharply in the data by some 10 percentage points (annualised). This drop of inflation is often taken as evidence that that the pandemic—while apparently a supply shock—induced substantial demand shortages, too (for instance, Fornaro and Wolf, 2020; Baqaee and Farhi, 2022). Yet, it turns out, that capturing the impact of the pandemic on inflation is both conceptually and quantitatively challenging, even in models which allow for the pandemic to operate via a demand contraction (Dietrich et al., 2022; Guerrieri et al., 2022). Against this background it is noteworthy that our model predicts the inflation developments fairly well—at least from a qualitative point of view. It predicts a strong drop of inflation in March 2020, followed by a gradual recovery over time. This is because in the model there is initially a contraction of both supply and demand. First and foremost, the Q-shock reduces the effective labour force and the effective capital stock in the economy, and thus lowers its productive capacity. But the same shock—and this is the focus of our analysis below—also adversely impacts aggregate demand, through the love-of-variety effect due to Guerrieri et al. (2022), but notably also as it increases idiosyncratic income risk. Households try to self-insure against this risk by increasing their liquid savings.20 This, in turn, generates a reduction of demand, as apparent from the consumption response shown in panel (b) of Figure 4.
Lastly, in panel (f) of Figure 4 we show the response of the policy rate. In line with actual developments, the model assumes a reduction of the policy rate by 1.5 percentage points in March 2020. This brings the policy rate to its lower bound which constrains monetary policy throughout the period under consideration.21
Overall, we find that the model predictions under the baseline align rather well with actual developments during 2020/1 with the exception of inflation. The alternative version of the model where the Q-shock is not fully anticipated predicts a much larger drop in inflation early in the COVID-19 recession (see Figure A.2 in Online Appendix B), suggesting that expectations have been excessively negative at the onset of the pandemic. Still, for the baseline we opt for the conservative scenario. All other aggregate dynamics are very similar in the two information treatments.
Against this background, we can determine the macroeconomic impact of the transfers under the CARES package through a counterfactual. Specifically, we simulate the model response to the same Q-shock as above, but assume—counterfactually—that workers in the |$\mathcal {Q}$|-state do not receive any additional unemployment benefit beyond the level which they receive in the regular unemployment state. In other words, there are no FPUC payments in the counterfactual and neither is there an unconditional transfer. The model prediction for this counterfactual scenario appear as the dashed lines in Figure 4. Comparing them to the baseline (solid line) lines allows us to quantify how the Coronavirus stimulus contributed to the economic adjustment to the pandemic.
We find that absent the stimulus, the collapse of economic activity at its trough would have been almost two percentage points larger. And the recovery during the second half of 2020 would have been markedly slower, such that the cumulative output loss would have been larger by about 13% (of monthly GDP). This is because—absent the CARES transfers—the economy would have suffered from a stronger contraction of consumption.22 Investment, too, would have declined more strongly. Perhaps unsurprisingly, the debt-to-output ratio would have increased somewhat less strongly.23 And while we do not observe a material difference in the response of monetary policy in Figure 4, panel (f), there is a noticeable difference between the counterfactual and the baseline in panel (e): Inflation declines considerably more strongly in the counterfactual. This, in turn, illustrates that transfer payments contribute to stabilising aggregate demand, in particular by providing insurance—a key aspect which we discuss in more detail in the next section.
3.3. The Transfer Multiplier
We finally turn to the question that motivates our analysis: How large is the transfer multiplier? To answer this question, it is important to distinguish transfers which are paid to the unemployed (via the FPUC) and the—by and large—unconditional transfer payments which have also been part of the CARES package. Panel (a) in Figure 5 displays the transfer multipliers for our baseline specification. Here, we measure time, as before, in months along the horizontal axis and the cumulative multiplier along the vertical axis: the cumulative output change in all periods up to horizon k that is due to the transfer, divided by the cumulative transfer payments up to the same horizon (see, for instance, Ramey, 2019). In the figure, we show the cumulative transfer multiplier from period 3 onward. This corresponds to April 2020 in our analysis when sizeable FPUC payments are starting to come online. Before April, hardly any (no) transfers are being payed out in the model (in the data).

Output Effect Of Transfers. Panel (a) shows cumulative multiplier computed as |$\sum _{j=1}^k y_i/\sum _{j=1}^k t_i$|, where |$y_i$| is the deviation of output from baseline, |$t_i$| is the transfer payment (both measured in percentage points of steady-state output) and k is the time since announcement in period 1 (February 2020), measured along the horizontal axis, shown for period |$k=3$| onward. Panel (b) shows output responses for baseline (solid line) and alternative specifications with conditional transfers only (dashed line) and without transfers (dash-dotted line). Y-axis: cumulative multiplier (panel b), percentage deviation from steady state (panel a). X-axis: months.
The solid line shows the multiplier for the total transfers to households provided for by the CARES Act. Initially, that is, in period 3 (April 2020), the cumulative multiplier is small, a finding familiar from earlier model-based analyses (Coenen et al., 2012; McKay and Reis, 2016; Giambattista and Pennings, 2017).24 To shed more light on our result, we decompose the multiplier: the dashed line and the dash-dotted line in Figure 5, panel (a), represent the multiplier for the conditional and the unconditional transfer under the CARES Act. Here we obtain values of close to unity and basically zero, respectively. The overall multiplier is an average of the two weighted with cumulative payments.
The difference is rather stark and two aspects are key for this. First, the conditional transfer is directed to the unemployed who have a high marginal propensity to consume. Importantly, this matters already before the transfer is paid out. As shown by Auclert et al. (2018), in HANK models such as ours, anticipated income changes impact current spending via the ‘intertemporal marginal propensity to consume’: households that operate near their liquidity constraint may raise expenditures in response to an expected increase in income in the near future.25 Second, the conditional transfer boosts aggregate demand because it reduces income risk. This happens even though transfers have not yet materialised. For these reasons the multiplier of the conditional transfer tends to be very large in period 1 and 2. We do not show it in the panel so as not to distort the picture. Over time the cumulative multiplier of conditional transfers declines as income risk is receding and conditional payments are materialising. Instead, the unconditional transfer multiplier increases somewhat in the medium run. As a result, cumulative multipliers become more aligned for longer horizons. For a one-year horizon we obtain values of about 0.8 and 0.4, respectively.
In panel (b) of Figure 5 we decompose the effect of the CARES transfers on output by contrasting the baseline response, which features both transfer components (solid line) to the output response for two alternative model specifications: one without transfers at all (dash-dotted line) and one where only the conditional transfers are being paid (dashed line). The figure shows that the conditional transfer payment is making almost all the difference (for in this case the response is almost the same as in the baseline). This is consistent with the results for the multiplier shown in panel (a) of the same figure, but still noteworthy because the overall amount of payments are about the same for both transfer types—in the model: |$\$274$| billion (conditional) versus |$\$283$| billion (unconditional).
The conditional transfer is more effective in stabilising the economy for three reasons. First, it insures the income risk associated with the |$\mathcal {Q}$|-state itself. Second, because it over-insures—via the exceptionally large replacement rates—the |$\mathcal {Q}$|-state, the conditional transfer provides additional resources to those households that transition into the |$\mathcal {U}$|-state after their quarantine ends. Third, because low-income households are more likely to end up in the |$\mathcal {Q}$|-state, it redistributes to low-income, high-MPC households.
We illustrate these three channels in Figure 6. For the purpose of this figure, we solve an alternative model where income of |$\mathcal {Q}$|- and |$\mathcal {E}$|-workers is pooled conditional on their productivity. Therefore, in this version of the model, the direct effect of |$\mathcal {Q}$|-state income risk is eliminated. The increase of |$\mathcal {U}$|-unemployment risk after quarantine, however, remains. What also remains, just as in the baseline, is that on average low-productivity workers receive more FPUC transfers than high-productivity workers. The transfers are just pooled across the |$\mathcal {Q}$|- and |$\mathcal {E}$|-workers.

Insurance Effects. Panel (a) decomposes output effect the of the conditional transfer into contributions due to insuring idiosyncratic income risk in |$\mathcal {Q}$|-state (light grey) and providing funds for self-insurance against income drop in |$\mathcal {U}$|-state (dark grey). Panels (b) and (c) show transfer multiplier of the conditional transfer in the baseline model (dashed) and panel (b) alternative model without idiosyncratic income risk in |$\mathcal {Q}$|-state (dash-dotted line), as well as panel (c) for alternatively sized transfer packages (dash- dot-dotted and dash-dotted lines). Y-axis: percentage points (left), cumulative multipliers (right). X-axis: months after start of stimulus.
Panel (a) of Figure 6 shows how the insurance effects play out in terms of stabilising output. In light grey, it shows by how much output in the alternative model exceeds output in the baseline as a result of the income risk associated with the |$\mathcal {Q}$|-state being fully insured. Recall that there are no FPUC payments, so that the full |$\mathcal {Q}$|-risk effect operates in the baseline model. And in the absence of this effect output falls less. On top of this, in dark grey, the figure shows how much greater the stabilising effect of FPUC payments is in the baseline model compared to the alternative with income pooling. This greater stabilisation results from FPUC payments being targeted to quarantined households, which use them to self-insure against the income risk associated with the regular |$\mathcal {U}$|-state. Because workers in the |$\mathcal {E}$|-state anticipate this their desire for precautionary saving is lower and aggregate demand higher. The total effect of both insurance effects is close to 1% of output at peak.
This insurance channel also shows itself in terms of multipliers in panel (b) of Figure 6. The dashed line is the transfer multiplier for the FPUC payments in our baseline model. When income is pooled in the |$\mathcal {Q}$|-state (dash-dotted line), the multiplier is significantly smaller because both the |$\mathcal {Q}$|-risk itself is insured and the FPUC payments are no longer targeted to high |$\mathcal {U}$|-risk households. However, the transfer multiplier of the FPUC payments is still larger than the unconditional transfer multiplier because of the targeting to low-income, high-MPC households.
Furthermore, panel (c) of Figure 6 shows that there are decreasing returns to providing additional insurance. Had the FPUC payments been half the size of the actual payments, the resulting multiplier would have been more than 20% larger (see dash-dot-dotted line). In absolute terms, this means that the effect of the first half of the FPUC payments ($137 billion) on GDP is thus $30 billion larger than the effect of the second half. Similarly, a further increase of FPUC payments (dash-dotted line) would have decreased the multiplier.
Finally, we assess the role of three other pandemic-related model features for our results. For this purpose, Figure 7, panel (a), compares the transfer multipliers of the baseline model to a variant where no goods are quarantined and, hence, the love-of-variety effect à la Guerrieri et al. (2022) is absent (panel b), to a variant without feedback from aggregate activity to quarantine (panel c), and to a variant where the full path of the Q-shocks is not known in February, but only learned by April (panel d).

Multiplier Dependence on Q-shock Features. Panel (a) replicates the baseline multipliers. Panel (b) shows multipliers when no goods are in quarantine. Panel (c) shows multipliers without feedback from aggregate activity to quarantines. Panel (d) shows multipliers when Q-shocks in March and April 2020 are not anticipated. X-axis: months after start of pandemic.
Eliminating the love-of-variety effect virtually leaves the transfer multipliers unchanged, even though it has a first-order effect on aggregate dynamics (which we illustrate in Figure A.2 in Online Appendix B). In contrast, removing the activity–quarantine feedback increases the multipliers substantially, in particular so during the first months. This illustrates a potential caveat of economic stimulus in a pandemic: some of its impact is lost to the extent that increased economic activity induces the state of the pandemic to worsen which, in turn, necessitates further quarantine measures.
Considering panel (d) in Figure 7, we observe that learning about the Q-shock sequence only gradually (incomplete anticipation) increases the multipliers. This is because, given the overall persistence of the Q-shock, the new ‘quarantines’ in May turn out lower than expected. In the baseline, this benign outcome is revealed already in February 2020, while, in the alternative, households expect a much bleaker situation with higher income risks. In this scenario, the conditional transfer turns out to be an even stronger instrument to stabilise economic activity. The multiplier of the unconditional transfer, instead, remains basically unchanged relative to the baseline. In Online Appendix C we also show that the multiplier is not affected by waves in product quarantines and, similar to the incomplete anticipation case, increases somewhat if households expect an additional wave of quarantine risks in late 2020.
3.4. Distributional Effects and Normative Implications
Our model captures key aspects of the pandemic recession fairly well in terms of both its macroeconomic impact and its heterogeneous impact at the household level. The incidence of unemployment, for instance, differs strongly across the income distribution as does the replacement rate, as Figures 2 and 3 illustrate. In what follows we highlight further distributional aspects of the pandemic which are widely debated (e.g., Adams et al., 2020; Chetty et al., 2020; Han et al., 2020; Hanspal et al., 2021). Afterwards, we compute the welfare effects of both the Q-shock and the Coronavirus stimulus.
Figure 8 shows the response of various inequality indicators to the Q-shock. In each instance, we compare the baseline with all transfers in place (solid line) to a counterfactual without unconditional transfers (dashed line) and with no transfers at all (dash-dotted line). Panel (a) shows the response of the top-10% income share. According to this measure, the pandemic leads to an increase in income inequality (except initially, that is in April 2020), even with transfer payments, and this increase is, with almost 10%, economically significant. At the same time, we observe that the transfer payments dampen the impact on income inequality: it would have risen even more in their absence. This finding is also supported by panel (b), which shows the top-10% wealth share. Here we see a decline in inequality in the baseline, an effect which would not have been observed without transfers. The stronger increase in government debt that finances transfers, together with the redistributive character of the transfers themselves, leads to an increase in the real rate on liquid assets and, thereby, fosters wealth accumulation of the relatively poor along the lines explained in Bayer et al. (2022a). This effect is quantitatively small, however. Finally, consumption inequality measured by the Gini and, shown in panel (c), still rises in all scenarios, but again the transfers dampen the increase, and quite strongly so. Without any transfers, the consumption Gini would have risen by 3% and, interestingly, it would have risen already in February due to increased precautionary savings of the poor. The expectation of conditional transfers eliminates this precautionary increase in consumption inequality—illustrating also in terms of this statistic the strong insurance effect of the FPUC payments.

Distributional Effects of CARES Transfer Payments. Solid line shows baseline response with both conditional and unconditional transfers, dash-dotted line without CARES transfers and dashed line with conditional transfer only. Y-axis: percentage deviation from steady state. X-axis: months.
Hence, the transfers under the CARES Act did not only contribute to stabilise economic activity. They also limited its fallout in terms of economic inequality. In a last step, we briefly assess their impact in terms of welfare. Panel (a) of Figure 9 shows the one-sided welfare effects of the pandemic had there been no transfers. All households lose, but, comparing along the wealth dimension, the welfare loss is the smallest for wealthy households that have the means to self-insure. Comparing along the income dimension (within wealth group), the high-productivity households lose more despite the fact that they have a lower incidence of quarantine. Their lifetime income suffers more from lower current factor prices. When it comes to the gains from transfers (panel b), the picture partly reverses. Still, the wealthy households gain relatively little from the transfers because they do not need the extra insurance. However, when stratifying by income, it is the low-income households who gain most from transfers. In terms of lifetime income, as well as current income, the CARES transfers more substantially boost the income of the poor than the income of the rich.26

Welfare Effects of Pandemic and CARES Transfer Payments. Within wealth groups, income terciles are ordered left to right from lowest income tercile to highest. The welfare gains are group averages of consumption equivalents (in percentage points). Note that the numbers include the indirect effects on future government spending which is assumed to be pure waste.
4. Conclusion
How large is the transfer multiplier? As often, the answer is: ‘it depends’. For the effects of the transfer payments implemented under the CARES Act differ fundamentally depending on whether transfers are conditional on the recipient being unemployed or not. We obtain this result as we study the COVID-19 recession and the fiscal transfers through the lens of a medium-scale HANK model. We calibrate the model to capture the developments of the unemployment rate during 2020/1, as well as the fiscal transfers payments of the Coronavirus stimulus package. We find that our model replicates well key feature of the data, both along the time-series dimension and the cross-section of households.
To understand the effect of transfers, we rely on counterfactual model simulations. We find, in particular, that conditional transfers (under the FPUC scheme) are effective in stabilising the aggregate economy, given the conditions under study, while unconditional transfers are not. This is noteworthy for a number of reasons, including the fact that both transfer components were of about the same size in the Coronavirus stimulus package. Conditional transfers are particularly effective, because they are directed to the unemployed who have a high marginal propensity to consume. In addition, as our analysis highlights, they limit income risk associated with unemployment, and thus help to avoid recessionary spirals of precautionary savings. Finally, we find that the conditional transfers helped to contain the increase of inequality caused by the COVID-19 recession as well its adverse welfare effects on the poor.
Transfers to households were only a part of the fiscal stimulus under the CARES Act. Among other things, it also provided for transfers to firms. It would be interesting to assess the impact of these policies, as well as other fiscal policy measures implemented in countries outside of the United States. As our current analysis makes clear, the effect of such measures is bound to interact in non-trivial ways with the specific conditions and institutions under which they are put in place. We leave a more comprehensive analysis for future research.
Additional Supporting Information may be found in the online version of this article:
Online Appendix
Replication Package
Footnotes
Initially, some observers suggested that unemployment would reach 30% in the second quarter of 2020; see, for instance, the remark by the president of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, James Bullard, reported by Bloomberg on 22 March 2020, or Faria-e-Castro (2020).
The Federal Reserve, too, took a series of measures in response to the COVID-19 crisis, including cutting its policy rate to zero. In our analysis, we account for Fed policy, but our focus is on the fiscal response to the crisis. Assuming uninsurable income risk, Wolf (2021) establishes conditions under which fiscal stimulus can be a perfect substitute for interest rate cuts.
We also study an alternative scenario where anticipation of the Q-shock is incomplete since, in some respects, the pandemic took firms by surprise (Hassan et al., 2021). Also, beliefs about the duration of the lockdown varied widely among firms and households (Bartik et al., 2020; Dietrich et al., 2022). Moser and Yared (2022) analyse the role of government commitment to the extent of future lockdowns. According to their analysis, lack of commitment leads to more severe lockdowns and larger losses in output and consumption.
There is also an element of conditionality in the $1,200 payment per person under the CARES Act, but this concerns only a small fraction of the population. We account for this in our model simulations, but refer to it as an ‘unconditional transfer’ for simplicity.
In related work, Auerbach et al. (2021) put forward a stylised model with COVID-19-related restrictions and economic slack. They show analytically that transfers to low-income households can increase spending on unrestricted items, and that targeted transfers to firms are particularly effective in stimulating the economy.
In absence of a better word, we choose to name the COVID unemployment state ‘quarantine’. It summarises literal quarantine/sickness, lockdown measures and voluntary consumption restraints that render certain activities impossible. The key features of this state are two: First, it captures the additional non-employment effects on factors and sectors of the pandemic and, second, FPUC payments are targeted and limited to workers in that state, which also limits them in time.
In the steady state, entrepreneurs are wealthy households and, as such, have a low marginal propensity to consume (MPC). Therefore, the assumption is very similar to the one made in TANK models, such as Bilbiie (2020), and increases business cycle propagation somewhat, along the lines discussed there.
The assumption of GHH preferences is motivated by the fact that many estimated DSGE models of business cycles find small aggregate wealth effects in the labour supply; see, e.g., Born and Pfeifer (2014). Bayer et al. (2022b) find the same for their HANK model when comparing the marginal likelihood of the model with GHH and King–Plosser–Rebelo preferences.
Given that we solve the model by a first-order perturbation in aggregate shocks, the assumption of risk-neutrality only serves as a simplification in terms of writing down the model as managers do not face idiosyncratic income risks. With a first-order perturbation, we have certainty equivalence for aggregate fluctuations, rendering stochastic discount factors of agents constant whose borrowing constraints or idiosyncratic risks do not change.
If the production unit is quarantined, quarantined capital is still depreciated at rate |$\delta _0 - \delta _1 + \delta _2/2$|. This means capital owners receive an average dividend payment on their capital |$r_t = r_t^F \bar{H}_t - (1-\bar{H}_t)\delta (0)$|.
We opt for simplicity here and assume that future government spending cuts ensure fiscal stability. Hagedorn et al. (2019) document how various financing options affect fiscal multipliers in HANK models.
Here we assume an average of the stipulated replacement rate (40%) and the worst case replacement rate (10%) computed by Krueger et al. (2016). This number takes into account that the eligibility, uptake and duration of unemployment benefits is limited.
Specifically, they find that below median labour income workers are three times more likely to become unemployed (see their Figure 5B).
Detailed data descriptions and sources (i.e., BEA, 2022; FRED, 2022) can be found in Online Appendix A.
Measured as total outlays documented by the Bureau of Economic Analysis in the personal income statistics under Pandemic Unemployment Compensation Payments. See also our Online Appendix A.
Given that the FPUC payments are tied to unemployment caused by the Q-shock, our analysis assumes that FPUC payments start already in March (rather than in April). Yet the payouts in March are very small. Assuming instead that the newly unemployed in March receive regular unemployment benefits does not alter our results below in a material way.
As detailed in Section 2, our simulation assumes a smooth transition from the |$\mathcal {Q}$|-state to regular unemployment. This is a computationally efficient way to approximate the discrete termination of the FPUC payments in July 2020. It also captures the initial uncertainty about the termination of the FPUC scheme, because it renders the duration of FPUC payments stochastic from an individual worker’s perspective.
Quarterly series are transformed to monthly frequency via cubic spline interpolation, see Online Appendix A.
According to widely held believes, actual inflation dynamics are to a considerable extent driven by fluctuations in commodity prices, also in the context of the pandemic (see, for instance, Budianto et al., 2021). We do not consider these in our model.
In terms of aggregate dynamics this looks like a ‘risk premium shock’, a driving force of business cycles in standard macro models (see, for instance, Smets and Wouters, 2007).
Concretely, we feed into the model a series of news about monetary policy, such that households correctly expect the policy rate to be at the effective lower bound from April 2020 to December 2021. This is also in line with the 2020 FOMC projections for the federal funds rate. After 2021, we assume that the policy rate follows the Taylor rule again.
Cox et al. (2020) provide evidence in support of our results. They use household-level bank data and document that, after an initial drop, spending has rebounded most rapidly for low-income households since mid-April 2020. According to the authors this suggests that the CARES stimulus programme played an important role in limiting the effects of labour market disruptions on spending.
Erceg and Lindé (2014) identify conditions under which fiscal stimulus may lower the debt-to-output ratio, notably in the context of the zero lower bound. Similarly, there is evidence that contractionary fiscal policy measures can at times raise the debt-to-output ratio (Born et al., 2020). We abstract from the possibility that the economic fallout from the COVID-19 pandemic impairs fiscal sustainability, since it is arguably less of an issue in the United States. Hürtgen (2021) analyses fiscal sustainability during the COVID-19 pandemic for selected euro-area countries.
Recent time-series studies obtain larger estimates (Gechert et al., 2021).
This effect is absent in TANK models, since there the borrowing constraint of non-optimising households is always binding.
Note that, on average, the CARES transfers overcompensate welfare losses due to the pandemic. This reflects the assumption that the increased transfers are financed by cuts in future government expenditures which the model treats as pure waste in welfare terms. A more detailed welfare analysis would require knowledge of how the transfers will be ultimately financed and the welfare consequences thereof.
Notes
The data and codes for this paper are available on the Journal repository. They were checked for their ability to reproduce the results presented in the paper. The replication package for this paper is available at the following address: https://doi.org/10.5281/zenodo.7492142.
We would like to thank Francesco Lippi (the editor), as well as four anonymous referees. We also thank (virtual) seminar audiences at the Atlanta Fed, Banque de France, ECB, University of Hamburg, Macroeconomic Policy Institute (IMK), MMCN Webinar Series on Macroeconomic Modelling and Pandemics, Virtual Macro Seminars (VMACS) and the 2020 meeting of the VfS Committee on Macroeconomics. Dominik Hees provided excellent research assistance. Christian Bayer gratefully acknowledges support through the ERC-CoG project Liquid-House-Cycle funded by the European Union’s Horizon 2020 Program under grant agreement No. 724204.