Abstract

As a promising strategy to secure debt financing, firms can use their intellectual property rights (IPR) as collateral. Despite an ongoing shift to a more technology-based economy, the collateralization of IPR is still trailing behind the use of more traditional asset classes. In this paper, we address the challenges and opportunities of using IPR as collateral from a legal and economic angle by also exploring the role of and consequences for IP law. We develop a new taxonomy, i.e., a classification of the key determinants of using IPR as collateral. The taxonomy defines two pillars that govern the use of IPR collateral that distinguish between institutional and economic determinants. The institutional determinants cover contract law, IPR registries, and banking regulations. The economic determinants constitute the influence of IPR characteristics on the trade-off between the economic costs and benefits of collateralizing IPR. We apply the derived taxonomy to the legal and economic status quo in several industrialized economies to identify potential impediments to IPR-backed debt financing. Taken together, our taxonomy can be viewed as providing guidance for future research in the fields of law and economics on IPR as loan collateral for businesses.

I. Introduction

Financial constraints caused by a lack of collateral undermine the growth dynamics of firms, especially for small, intangible-rich firms.1,2 At the same time, the last decades were marked by an increasingly dominant role of intangible assets not only but also in technology-based small firms.3,4 Despite this development, tangible assets have thus far remained the most common way to secure external financing, in particular bank loans.5 Lacking tangible assets is therefore one of the main causes for the slow growth of many small firms.6 Hence, the question arises of whether and how the use of intangible assets, in particular intellectual property rights (IPR), as collateral for business loans can catch up with the traditional use of tangible assets.

In principle, pledging IPR as loan collateral provides firms with an additional source of financing, especially when other collateral is absent. Improving access to financing may create an important incentive for obtaining IPR particularly for small and medium-sized enterprises,7 which are generally considered to have relatively limited access to external sources of financing.8,9 Recent empirical evidence in the economics and financial literature shows that certain borrowers are indeed able to use their patents and trademarks as loan collateral.10,11,12 Yet, the market for IPR-backed loans is still underdeveloped and only a small share of the firms with IPR actually borrow against it.13 This is particularly puzzling against the backdrop of the increasingly dominant role of intangibles in firm value. To illustrate, in Europe, Asia, and the US the contribution of IPR-intensive sectors to GDP ranges between 38 and 45% (see Figure IA1,  Appendix). In the absence of specific frictions, it should be most effective for rational agents to deploy their most valuable assets to obtain financing.

In this paper, we address the challenges and opportunities of the use of IPR as collateral. We approach this issue from a legal and economic angle by also exploring the role of and consequences for IP law. We thereby aim to combine an economic analysis of intellectual property rights and their potential role as collateral with the investigation of the legal and institutional settings in different countries, most notably France, Germany, Japan, and the US. As economists, while naturally coming from an economic perspective, we are convinced that our overall analysis is highly relevant and useful for a legal audience. We develop a new taxonomy of the determinants of collateralizing IPR to better understand the obstacles to a more active use of IPR as collateral in lending. Thereby, we use the term taxonomy to denote our approach to classifying the different determinants for using IP as collateral. Hence, the taxonomy defines several institutional and economic determinants that are the basis for IPR as collateral. The institutional determinants comprise three different elements: contract law, IPR registries, and banking regulations. The first element defines the contractual law framework; it governs the legal transfer of IPR while leaving the user right with the borrower. The second element aims to strengthen the underlying property right and to enhance the transparency of its potential transfer from the borrower to the lender. The third element defines the costs of lending via banking regulations. The three elements should have considerable effects on the structure and volume of transaction costs for IPR-backed loans. The economic determinants constitute the joint influence of IPR and industry characteristics on the trade-off between the economic costs and benefits that firms face when using IPR as collateral. We argue that these determinants need to surpass a certain threshold in order to enable IPR-backed loans.

We apply the taxonomy to analyze the potential reasons for the relatively low prevalence of IPR-backed loans. We choose the German legal system as a starting point and then compare our findings to Japan, the US, and France. This allows us to account for institutions that vary across countries. Our results show that these four legal regimes provide the basic requirements for the collateralization of IPR. At the same time, for each of them we observe specific frictions, which potentially act as obstacles to a more frequent use of IPR as collateral.

We identify the certification and validation roles of a public IPR registry to be of highest importance. Since lending is generally associated with asymmetric information (prior to and after loan provision), the information provided by a public registry represents institutional support behind the loan agreements. In addition, we consider the international regulatory requirements for business loan providers as stipulated by the Basel III Accords, which affect the supply of loans. IPR does not fulfill the collateral eligibility criteria under Basel III. This failure means that IPR-backed loans are designated as unsecured loans, which potentially increases borrowing costs.

Next, we discuss the economic role of collateral in debt contracts by focusing on the benefits and costs to firms when pledging their IPR as loan collateral. As a key benefit, IPR collateral may act as a signaling or screening device that aims to overcome informational asymmetries between the lender and the borrower in which the IPR’s value to the borrower matters. Furthermore, IPR collateral may compensate for a lack of other sources of pledgeable income that makes the value of the IPR to the lender decisive. The main costs of using IPR as collateral come from low redeployability, high valuation costs, and high liquidation costs (i.e., high transfer costs in case of default). Overall, we argue that this cost-benefit trade-off is jurisdiction-, firm- and in particular asset-specific.14

We deliver new and fundamental insights into the emerging academic literature on the use of IPR as loan collateral, which may in particular be useful for many small firms. Several legal scholars have written valuable contributions discussing country-specific issues on the laws governing the use of IPR as collateral (see Kieninger15 for an excellent overview). In the economic literature, some recent studies empirically assess the use of IPR loans with a focus on single IPR types in very specific settings. For instance, Mann16 investigates the use of patents as loan collateral for a sample of large corporations. Hochberg, Serrano, and Ziedonis17 study the collateralizing of patents by start-ups backed by venture capital in three tech industries. Graham, Marco, and Myers18 show that US firms may also use trademarks as loan collateral. Our study bridges the two fields of law and economics by establishing a rather fundamental framework: We develop a new taxonomy of the determinants of IPR-backed loans, covering the central cornerstones that govern the use of IPR as loan collateral, i.e., institutional and economic determinants.

With this paper, we provide a number of key contributions. First, we introduce a new taxonomy of the key determinants of collateralizing IPR. Second, our analysis demonstrates and evaluates the current state of these determinants in several countries. Third, we draw main policy conclusions on the prevalence of collateralizing IPR. We hope to stimulate the discourse among policymakers, practitioners, and academics about the modernization of bank lending in line with an increasingly technology-driven economy. Our taxonomy can be viewed as guidance for future research on IPR as business loan collateral.

The paper is structured as follows: In Section II, we define different IPR types and the principal benefits of loan collateral, and provide statistics on the actual use of IPR collateral. In Section III, we derive the institutional and economic determinants of our framework. We discuss the application of these determinants against the background of several large economies around the globe in Section IV. In Section V, we summarize our main findings and provide a number of policy implications.

II. Intellectual property rights and their use as collateral

IPR can be distinguished on the basis of differences regarding the underlying subject of protection. Our analysis focuses on the four most common types of IPR: trademarks, patents, designs, and copyright. Table 1 shows the basic criteria for and the differences across these types. All IPR types grant their owner an exclusive legal right to use the protected object, product, service, or technology. Their common denominator is the promotion of economic activity in terms of inventive processes (patents and copyrights) or product quality and differentiation (trademarks and designs). Hence, all IPR types serve as protection against unlawful use or dissemination. However, IPR types differ with respect to their subject matter as well as other central aspects, such as (i) the requirements for obtaining the respective rights, (ii) the administrative steps that are required to activate protection, and (iii) the duration of protection. These differences might have direct implications for the degree to which the various IPRs are used as collateral.

Table 1:

Intellectual property rights: Definitions and Occurrences

IP rightTrademarkPatentDesignCopyright
Subject matterSigns distinguishing goods or services (i.e., brands, words, drawings, and/or symbols)Technical inventionAesthetic creative forms and non-functional product featuresOriginal works of authorship
(incl., literary dramatic, musical, and artistic works)
Conferred rightsExclusive right to use the trademark and prevent use for similar goods/servicesExclusive right to make, use, and sell the patented inventionExclusive right to make, use, and sell the designExclusive right to use, reproduce communicate to the public, or license
RequirementDistinctiveness, use in commerceNovelty, material, non-obviousness, industrial applicationSimilar to patentsOriginality of the work, irrespective of its literary or artistic merit
ActivationRegister entry (unexamined)ExaminationRegister entry (unexamined)Automatic upon creation
Max protection durationIndefinite20 years25 years70 years (for authors: lifetime plus 70 years)
Maintenance/ activation costsLowHighHighNone
BenefitsPromotes quality and competition; information providerIncentive to innovate; knowledge protection and diffusionProvides means for product differentiationInduce creativity by providing protection
IP rightTrademarkPatentDesignCopyright
Subject matterSigns distinguishing goods or services (i.e., brands, words, drawings, and/or symbols)Technical inventionAesthetic creative forms and non-functional product featuresOriginal works of authorship
(incl., literary dramatic, musical, and artistic works)
Conferred rightsExclusive right to use the trademark and prevent use for similar goods/servicesExclusive right to make, use, and sell the patented inventionExclusive right to make, use, and sell the designExclusive right to use, reproduce communicate to the public, or license
RequirementDistinctiveness, use in commerceNovelty, material, non-obviousness, industrial applicationSimilar to patentsOriginality of the work, irrespective of its literary or artistic merit
ActivationRegister entry (unexamined)ExaminationRegister entry (unexamined)Automatic upon creation
Max protection durationIndefinite20 years25 years70 years (for authors: lifetime plus 70 years)
Maintenance/ activation costsLowHighHighNone
BenefitsPromotes quality and competition; information providerIncentive to innovate; knowledge protection and diffusionProvides means for product differentiationInduce creativity by providing protection

Notes: The table defines the four most common IP right types, i.e., trademarks, patents, designs, and copyright. The characterization is based on the discussion of European IP rights in Neil Wilkof, Shamnad Basheer and Irene Calboli, Overlapping intellectual property rights (OUP 2023). For comparability, distinct definition criteria are displayed: the object which is subject to protection, the basic requirements that need to be fulfilled to obtain the right, the actual procedural steps needed for activation, the duration of protection without renewals after grant, the maximum number of renewals, i.e., the maximum duration of protection, and a qualitative assessment of the average costs to activate and maintain the IP type. All of these definitions cover IP rights filed and registered in Europe, i.e., at the EPO, EUIPO, or national IP offices. In general, these features also apply in other main IP jurisdictions, such as the US, Japan, or South Korea. The only notable difference is that in the US, trademark ownership is not granted on a first-to-file but on a first-to-use basis. Further, US trademarks are subject to a formal examination process.

Table 1:

Intellectual property rights: Definitions and Occurrences

IP rightTrademarkPatentDesignCopyright
Subject matterSigns distinguishing goods or services (i.e., brands, words, drawings, and/or symbols)Technical inventionAesthetic creative forms and non-functional product featuresOriginal works of authorship
(incl., literary dramatic, musical, and artistic works)
Conferred rightsExclusive right to use the trademark and prevent use for similar goods/servicesExclusive right to make, use, and sell the patented inventionExclusive right to make, use, and sell the designExclusive right to use, reproduce communicate to the public, or license
RequirementDistinctiveness, use in commerceNovelty, material, non-obviousness, industrial applicationSimilar to patentsOriginality of the work, irrespective of its literary or artistic merit
ActivationRegister entry (unexamined)ExaminationRegister entry (unexamined)Automatic upon creation
Max protection durationIndefinite20 years25 years70 years (for authors: lifetime plus 70 years)
Maintenance/ activation costsLowHighHighNone
BenefitsPromotes quality and competition; information providerIncentive to innovate; knowledge protection and diffusionProvides means for product differentiationInduce creativity by providing protection
IP rightTrademarkPatentDesignCopyright
Subject matterSigns distinguishing goods or services (i.e., brands, words, drawings, and/or symbols)Technical inventionAesthetic creative forms and non-functional product featuresOriginal works of authorship
(incl., literary dramatic, musical, and artistic works)
Conferred rightsExclusive right to use the trademark and prevent use for similar goods/servicesExclusive right to make, use, and sell the patented inventionExclusive right to make, use, and sell the designExclusive right to use, reproduce communicate to the public, or license
RequirementDistinctiveness, use in commerceNovelty, material, non-obviousness, industrial applicationSimilar to patentsOriginality of the work, irrespective of its literary or artistic merit
ActivationRegister entry (unexamined)ExaminationRegister entry (unexamined)Automatic upon creation
Max protection durationIndefinite20 years25 years70 years (for authors: lifetime plus 70 years)
Maintenance/ activation costsLowHighHighNone
BenefitsPromotes quality and competition; information providerIncentive to innovate; knowledge protection and diffusionProvides means for product differentiationInduce creativity by providing protection

Notes: The table defines the four most common IP right types, i.e., trademarks, patents, designs, and copyright. The characterization is based on the discussion of European IP rights in Neil Wilkof, Shamnad Basheer and Irene Calboli, Overlapping intellectual property rights (OUP 2023). For comparability, distinct definition criteria are displayed: the object which is subject to protection, the basic requirements that need to be fulfilled to obtain the right, the actual procedural steps needed for activation, the duration of protection without renewals after grant, the maximum number of renewals, i.e., the maximum duration of protection, and a qualitative assessment of the average costs to activate and maintain the IP type. All of these definitions cover IP rights filed and registered in Europe, i.e., at the EPO, EUIPO, or national IP offices. In general, these features also apply in other main IP jurisdictions, such as the US, Japan, or South Korea. The only notable difference is that in the US, trademark ownership is not granted on a first-to-file but on a first-to-use basis. Further, US trademarks are subject to a formal examination process.

Once a firm owns an IPR, it can be deployed – in principle – in any market transaction, such as IP sales, licensing, or as loan collateral. Sales and licensing transactions provide firms with equity at the cost of forgoing the exclusive ownership right. In contrast, when pledging IPR to secure loans, companies receive a lump sum payment without the risk of diluting or losing their exclusive rights to exploit the underlying intellectual property.

Despite an abundance of anecdotal evidence and discussion in the legal literature on the use of IPR as loan collateral, empirical evidence on this practice is scarce. Obtaining aggregate statistics on the use of IPR as loan collateral is difficult. As our analysis shows, there is no obligation to publicly report loan transactions in most jurisdictions worldwide. Plausibly, firms may decide not to publicly disclose the specificities of their loan contracts for strategic reasons. However, there are some exceptions, such as several European countries (i.e., Belgium, Luxembourg, the Netherlands, Sweden, and France), where registration of IPR collateral is mandatory in the case of patents. This allows important insights into the use of IPR as loan collateral in a setting where general loan-level information is scarce.

For the US, some studies in the economic literature show that specialized borrowers use patents as collateral in loan contracts.19,20 Ciaramella, Heller and Leitzinger21 provide first encompassing evidence on the use of trademarks, patents, and designs as loan collateral using IPR loan register entries in France for the years 1995-2018. They find that the majority of IPR used as collateral are trademarks (84%), followed by patents (26%) and designs (2%). Indeed, the distribution does not match the actual use of these IPR, which is more balanced (see Figure IA1,  Appendix). This suggests that IPR type-specific characteristics are important to determine its current use as loan collateral.

Because of the limited data availability, documenting the actual use of IPR as loan collateral is non-trivial. To exemplify the use of IPR collateral, we collected data on some of the aforementioned European countries (i.e., the Netherlands, Sweden, and France) and on one specific type of IPR, patents, for which data is most readily available for the years from 2000 to 2018. On average, about 120 firms from these three countries pledge patents each year, with no particular time trend.22 Given that IPR collateralization goes far beyond patents,23 the inclusion of all IPR types will likely yield much higher numbers. In the US, these numbers are distinctly higher.24 However, they may be driven by specific loan vehicles, such as the US blanket lien or UCC-1 lien, in which the entire asset portfolio is pledged. Taken together, these observations confirm the notion that the majority of loans still do not utilize IPR as collateral.

III. A taxonomy of the determinants of IPR-backed loans

In this section, we derive the taxonomy of the determinants of collateralizing IPR. At its core, the framework consists of two pillars as illustrated in Figure 1: one institutional and one economic pillar. The two pillars comprise several determinants, which jointly constitute the overall taxonomy. Each determinant in itself is viewed as a necessary but not sufficient factor that needs to reach a minimum threshold in order for IPR to be suitable for collateralization. Most broadly, the institutional pillar consists of three key determinants: (1) contract law, (2) IPR registries, and (3) international banking regulations. The economic pillar contains the characteristics of IPR that determine the economic cost-benefit analysis of IPR as collateral. In the following, we describe the two pillars and set out each determinant in detail, including their bifurcations. In this way, we develop our taxonomy of the determinants of IPR collateralization step-by-step.

The two main pillars of IPR collateralization
Figure 1:

The two main pillars of IPR collateralization

1. Institutional pillar

From an institutional perspective, the general legal framework marks the foundation of IPR-backed loan transactions. As contractual agreements, the mere existence of loan contracts is subject to the underlying legal setting. Hence, the legal framework is the conditio sine qua non for IPR to be used as loan collateral. In other words, the law may prohibit or allow the use of all or specific asset classes as collateral. In fact, specific laws prohibit the use of certain IPR collateral types, such as the use of patent applications in Japan,25 or collective trademarks in France.26 Hence, an existing legal framework provides the basis for the securitization of IPR.

We define three main elements of the institutional determinants as illustrated in Figure 1: contract law, public registers, and banking regulations. In our view, these elements define the most important dimensions to be considered when collateralizing IPR. These dimensions relate to features most directly linked to borrowers and lenders, but in principle concern all stakeholders. Additionally, we can distinguish between direct and indirect implications of institutions. Without claiming completeness, we consider these institutional elements as important complements for the use of IPR as loan collateral. As opaque and uncertain assets, IPR are distinctively different to tangible assets in all three institutional elements.27 Hence, we argue that these factors are particularly important in the context of IPR, despite their applicability for other non-IPR collateral assets. Most importantly, all three institutional factors should lead to a reduction of transactions costs for IPR-backed loans if they are implemented in an efficient manner. In the following, we describe the three elements in detail.

Contract law: Institutions are important in a very direct way because they steer the interactions of stakeholders. Most importantly, ownership rights need to be clearly defined. Specifically, domestic contract law provides the legal framework for private loan contracts, which allow the use of specific asset classes as collateral. This law directly affects the relationship of borrowers and lenders in a loan contract by defining rights and obligations. For example, more precise contract law defines specificities regarding the collateralizing of IPR that facilitates the establishment of the contract between borrowers and lenders. In contrast, poor institutions fail to define specific aspects of contract law, which introduces additional transaction costs.

For these reasons, we investigate the extent to which contract law helps or impedes the provision of loans that have IPR as collateral by considering different layers of national legislative systems. This consideration includes aspects related to the establishment of the respective loan contracts and their termination. The potential limitations in contract law involve two factors: a lack of specific rules and incomplete contracts.

Public registry: A major friction in debt financing is information asymmetries between borrowers and lenders.28 Information provided by trusted institutions are important as they can indirectly steer the collateralizing of IPR by influencing these asymmetries. Specifically, we focus on IP offices as the key intermediary for the communication of reliable and standardized IPR-related information to the public. In this way, IP offices can reduce information asymmetries by collecting and disseminating information. Access to this information induces transparency regarding the present and past statuses of an IPR. Timely and mandatory registration enhances the monitoring of IPR collateral prior to and during the loan contract. In some IP offices, this information includes details regarding the collateralization of IPR. Therefore, institutions may be a valuable intermediary for collecting, processing, and communicating information via standardized repositories.29

Banking regulations: Institutions can shape the opportunity costs of IPR regarding the supply of and demand for loans. That is, bank regulatory rules have a potentially strong influence on the prevalence of certain types of loan collateral, as they affect the cost of lending. Banking regulations subject banks to a set of rules, restrictions, or guidelines. Capital requirements are regulatory standards for banks that, via capital requirements rules, determine how much capital bank lenders are required to withhold for different types of collateral.30 All else being equal, higher capital costs reduce banks’ expected return on a loan and thus affect the supply of loans. Similarly, higher capital costs may lead to higher interest rates, which reduce the demand for loans.31,32 For these reasons, changes in capital requirements translate into a change in the opportunity costs for IPR-backed loans, especially if the rules vary across collateral types.

2. Economic pillar

Defining collateral: In principle, collateral is the claim of a lender (typically a bank) on the borrower’s assets in the event that it defaults on the loan or files for bankruptcy.33 This secured interest generally gives the lender priority over other creditors in claiming proceeds from the respective liquidated assets. For the lender, interest payments are cash flows obtained from borrowers. Hence, collateral can be viewed as an alternative source of loan repayment if the borrower is not able to cover the interest payments from other sources, in particular its operations. In economic terms, collateral thus reduces the lender’s cash flow risk. Thus, if a borrower has no collateral, then lenders may not be willing to provide a loan or may demand higher interest rates. Therefore, the provision of collateral is one way of improving access to external debt financing. Providing pledgeable income to the lender improves the borrower’s conditions for securing funding.

The functioning of collateral can best be described as an additional source of information.34 There is no need for collateral when the information between borrowers and lenders are perfectly symmetrical and both parties can use the potential collateralizable asset to the same extent.35 It follows that lenders use collateral to overcome asymmetric information. At the same time, collateral can also be the source of informational asymmetry. Hence, the decisive question is to what extent collateral can mitigate information problems. Both factors are particularly relevant in the context of IPR collateral, because here the question is to what extent IPR introduces additional frictions by itself.

Economic costs and benefits: In addition to the institutional pillar, the weighting of the economic benefits and costs of using IPR as collateral in business loans is pivotal for explaining the actual use of IPR collateral. The second pillar reflects the extent to which IPR may undertake the role of collateral in business loans and its main economic obstacles. The use of IPR as collateral has a number of distinct benefits that are related to their reliability and signaling strength. At the same time, IPR have inherent characteristics, which are typically associated with higher costs in the context of loan contracts, such as a relatively high degree of uncertainty. The three main IPR characteristics at the core of the economic cost-benefit trade-off are the following: the ability to redeploy IPR, asset-specificity (and, thus, valuation issues), and uncertainty about the validity and scope of the assets.36 Overall, these benefits and costs result in specific settings, which are especially conducive to the use of IPR as collateral but also to contexts in which they may clearly face limits.

Furthermore, with regard to one specific characteristic, these economic considerations are distinctively different to those in the institutional pillar. The economic benefits and costs are endogenously determined by the institutional factors in the first pillar. More explicitly, in our taxonomy we propose that the institutional determinants directly affect the economic determinants, while the reverse is not necessarily true, that is, at least not in the short- to medium-term. For example, institutions may directly affect the degree to which an asset can be redeployed but different degrees of redeployability do not directly affect the design of institutions. As a consequence, direct changes in the IP law concerning the institutional framework – intentionally or unintentionally – translate into changes in the economic benefit-cost analysis on the feasibility of the use of IPR as collateral. While, as such, both the institutional factors and the economic argument in favor of (or against) the use of IPR collateral are equally important for enabling the collateralization of IPR, their interrelationship is not symmetric.

The above can be summarized in Figure 2, i.e., our taxonomy of IPR-backed loans. The taxonomy decomposes the two main pillars into a set of determinants that are interdependent. The economic determinants are based on the asset value from both the borrower’s and the lender’s perspective. Institutional determinants directly impact the economic weighting of benefits and costs and are themselves rooted in an economic consideration – transaction costs.

The taxonomy of IPR-backed loans
Figure 2:

The taxonomy of IPR-backed loans

IV. Application of the taxonomy

In this section, we discuss our taxonomy in detail by applying it to actual characteristics in the legal frameworks of major economies worldwide. Where necessary, we focus on country-specific frameworks first and then use these insights to draw inferences on a more general level. Our goal is to describe the status quo along the dimensions of the institutional settings that shape the loans with IPR as collateral and the associated economic benefits and costs for market participants.

1. Institutional determinants

a) Enabling IPR loans with domestic contract law

Legal issues are tied to the country-specific legislative frameworks. We choose Germany as a benchmark scenario and subsequently compare our findings to other large industrialized economies: Japan, the US, and France. Germany is well suited for benchmarking because of its high IPR intensity (as illustrated in Section II), its strong banking-based focus, and the relatively high importance of German law for other legal regimes.37 Comparing our benchmark findings to other major IPR-intensive economies is important to gain more detailed insights on whether and how the legal framework determines the use of IPR as collateral.

In Germany, the combination of IP law with general credit security law governs the framework for collateralizing IPR. There are two relevant approaches to securitizing IPR: the pledge of rights and security assignments.38 For simplicity, we consider two-party contracts between the IPR owners (the debtors) and a lending institution, which is typically a bank. In principle, German law provides relatively clear instructions for the establishment and resolution of IPR-backed loan contracts.39 It further formulates a general guidance for the time the loan contract is active. In the following, we discuss these three parts of a loan agreement separately.

Establishing a contract: The German system differentiates between the pledge of rights and the security assignment as the means to collateralize IPR.40 Both cases stipulate the use of trademarks,41 patents,42 utility models,43 and designs44 as loan collateral.45 Further, the borrower is able to continue using the IPR commercially throughout the entire duration of the contract.

Despite these commonalities, the two securitization modes are based on two different legal concepts with distinct rights and duties. In particular, a pledge of rights is an accessory right in which a secured debt is a prerequisite for the existence of the pledge over the IPR.46 The borrower maintains ownership and control of the pledged IPR, while the lender is granted an exploitation right in the event of default. This control allows the borrower to autonomously decide about the appropriation of the IPR. For example, a borrower might use the pledged right in other licensing or loan contracts without asking for permission from the lender.

In contrast, a security assignment establishes a so-called fiduciary relationship between the borrower and the lender.47 Specifically, in this legal concept the owner and holder are split such that the lender becomes the owner of the IPR, while the borrower remains its holder. This is important, as the borrower cannot autonomously decide on the appropriation of the IPR during the loan contract. In practice, it is common to back-license the IPR, such that the borrower is still able to exploit the IPR independently of the lender.48

Maintaining a contract: During the term of the loan contract, different responsibilities arise with regard to the maintenance of the status of the IPR for both the borrower and the lender. In order to perpetuate an IPR, its owners have to pay recurring renewal fees. For a pledged IPR, the borrower is responsible for paying these maintenance fees and ensuring that the respective right does not lapse.49,50 Similar to the maintenance responsibilities, the borrowing entity is obliged to defend the IPR in the event of infringements.51 However, if the borrower does not fulfill these responsibilities, the lender is authorized to step in and pay the maintenance fees or defend the collateralized IPR in court. These rules apply for both the pledge of rights and the security assignment.52

Resolving a contract: In most cases, a loan contract ends with its fulfillment by the borrower, which results in a lapse of any exploitation rights (pledge of rights) or the release of the collateral (security assignment). In the event of default, several scenarios are possible. Loan contracts typically include a post-default agreement that specifies procedures and responsibilities regarding the pledged assets in the event of a loan default. If such an agreement is missing, German law governs certain aspects of the collateral, which applies to both the pledge of rights and the security agreement.

Generally, one can differentiate between default in the event of a borrower’s insolvency and an outside insolvency.53,54 The two cases differ with respect to the cause of the default. Borrowers file for insolvency if they are unable to pay their debt since the borrowers’ liabilities exceed their assets. An outside insolvency occurs due to insufficient liquidity on the borrower’s side or for strategic reasons. The latter happens for example if the value of the collateral falls drastically below the loan amount.55

In the event of insolvency, the collateral is transferred to a trustee. The latter’s task is to liquidate the collateralized assets and eventually repay the lender by using those proceeds.56 From a legal perspective, there is no clear definition of whether the trustee or the creditor acquires the IPR.57 This differentiation may be important as it determines whether the trustee or the loan provider has the right to decide how to further proceed with the IPR collateral. Specifically, the appointed party can decide on whether, how, and to whom the respective IPR should be sold. In practice, a common approach to mitigate this issue is that trustees and lenders specify a separate contract which governs these aspects in the event of insolvency.

An outside insolvency default in a pledge of rights leads to a public auction of the IPR if not otherwise specified in the private contract.58 The proceeds from auctions are intended to cover the lender’s claims. The lender cannot freely decide how to appropriate the collateral because the type of collateral realization is codified by law. This feature is often considered a weakness of the pledge of rights compared with the security assignment, which does not incorporate such a standardized approach.59 Since the lender is already the owner of the IPR, the most promising method is the private sale of the encumbered right.60

Overall, the German legal framework defines relatively precisely the establishment and resolution of IP-backed loan contracts as well as rights and duties for the time the contract is active. The parties involved can choose between two distinct ways of collateralizing IPR, namely the pledge of rights and the security assignment, allowing them to choose the strategy that is more appropriate for their needs. As an important element, the law allows the original owner to continue the exploitation of the IPR throughout the loan contract. This reduces the costs of engaging in IPR-backed loan agreements and, in principle, provides the ground for these transactions. However, the two-track system introduces certain inefficiencies, since potentially confusing security devices constitute indirect transaction costs.61,62 Moreover, the disposal right in an insolvency scenario is still an unresolved issue in Germany. A standardized procedure could strengthen IP-backed lending by decreasing uncertainties as well as the associated transactions costs.

Comparing Germany with Japan, the USA, and France: As a next step, we assess the key commonalities and differences of the German legal framework and IPR collateral laws regarding both the establishment and the resolution of the loan contract in three other IPR-intensive economies, Japan, the US, and France. In principle, IP laws worldwide have been aligned to some extent over the past decades.63 Despite these harmonization efforts, some significant differences prevail which might be relevant to the use of IPR as collateral.64 Therefore, comparing different legal regimes is essential for assessing the effectiveness of IPR collateral laws. Table 2 provides an overview of the legal frameworks regarding the use of IPR as collateral in the four jurisdictions discussed in this paper. Kieninger65 contains a comprehensive overview on IPR security laws worldwide.

Table 2:

Intellectual property rights as loan collateral across the world

GermanyJapanUSAFrance
Pleadgable IP types
Industrial propertyYesYesYesYes (no collective TMs)
CopyrightNoYesYesYes
Common security vehicles
Pledge of rightsYesYesYesYes
Security assignmentYesYes (‘mortgage’)NoYes (‘fiducia’)
Establishing a contract
RegistrationNo requirementsPledge: mandatory Mortgage: not possibleMandatory for some states and IP typesMandatory for most IPR; advisable for lender
Exploitation rightsWith borrower (automatically or via back-licensing)Pledge: with lender Mortgage: with borrowerWith lenderWith borrower
Maintenance dutiesWith borrowerWith borrowerWith borrowerWith borrower
Resolving a contract in default
Outside InsolvencyPledge: public auction Security: free choiceFree choicePublic auctionFree choice
In InsolvencyDebatedFree choicePublic auctionFree choice
GermanyJapanUSAFrance
Pleadgable IP types
Industrial propertyYesYesYesYes (no collective TMs)
CopyrightNoYesYesYes
Common security vehicles
Pledge of rightsYesYesYesYes
Security assignmentYesYes (‘mortgage’)NoYes (‘fiducia’)
Establishing a contract
RegistrationNo requirementsPledge: mandatory Mortgage: not possibleMandatory for some states and IP typesMandatory for most IPR; advisable for lender
Exploitation rightsWith borrower (automatically or via back-licensing)Pledge: with lender Mortgage: with borrowerWith lenderWith borrower
Maintenance dutiesWith borrowerWith borrowerWith borrowerWith borrower
Resolving a contract in default
Outside InsolvencyPledge: public auction Security: free choiceFree choicePublic auctionFree choice
In InsolvencyDebatedFree choicePublic auctionFree choice

Notes: The table provides an overview of the legal framework of IPR as collateral in four jurisdictions, France, Germany, Japan, and the US. It first shows four commonly pledgeable IP types for each country, trademarks, patents, designs, and copyright, followed by the most frequent security vehicles in each jurisdiction: pledge of rights and security assignment. The second half of the table shows the establishment as well as the resolution of loan contracts collateralized by IPR. First, the establishment of such a loan contract results in certain (maintenance) duties and (exploitation) rights. Second, the resolution in the event of a default brings up the question of whether the lender is allowed to freely decide on the future of the seized IPR.

Table 2:

Intellectual property rights as loan collateral across the world

GermanyJapanUSAFrance
Pleadgable IP types
Industrial propertyYesYesYesYes (no collective TMs)
CopyrightNoYesYesYes
Common security vehicles
Pledge of rightsYesYesYesYes
Security assignmentYesYes (‘mortgage’)NoYes (‘fiducia’)
Establishing a contract
RegistrationNo requirementsPledge: mandatory Mortgage: not possibleMandatory for some states and IP typesMandatory for most IPR; advisable for lender
Exploitation rightsWith borrower (automatically or via back-licensing)Pledge: with lender Mortgage: with borrowerWith lenderWith borrower
Maintenance dutiesWith borrowerWith borrowerWith borrowerWith borrower
Resolving a contract in default
Outside InsolvencyPledge: public auction Security: free choiceFree choicePublic auctionFree choice
In InsolvencyDebatedFree choicePublic auctionFree choice
GermanyJapanUSAFrance
Pleadgable IP types
Industrial propertyYesYesYesYes (no collective TMs)
CopyrightNoYesYesYes
Common security vehicles
Pledge of rightsYesYesYesYes
Security assignmentYesYes (‘mortgage’)NoYes (‘fiducia’)
Establishing a contract
RegistrationNo requirementsPledge: mandatory Mortgage: not possibleMandatory for some states and IP typesMandatory for most IPR; advisable for lender
Exploitation rightsWith borrower (automatically or via back-licensing)Pledge: with lender Mortgage: with borrowerWith lenderWith borrower
Maintenance dutiesWith borrowerWith borrowerWith borrowerWith borrower
Resolving a contract in default
Outside InsolvencyPledge: public auction Security: free choiceFree choicePublic auctionFree choice
In InsolvencyDebatedFree choicePublic auctionFree choice

Notes: The table provides an overview of the legal framework of IPR as collateral in four jurisdictions, France, Germany, Japan, and the US. It first shows four commonly pledgeable IP types for each country, trademarks, patents, designs, and copyright, followed by the most frequent security vehicles in each jurisdiction: pledge of rights and security assignment. The second half of the table shows the establishment as well as the resolution of loan contracts collateralized by IPR. First, the establishment of such a loan contract results in certain (maintenance) duties and (exploitation) rights. Second, the resolution in the event of a default brings up the question of whether the lender is allowed to freely decide on the future of the seized IPR.

In general, Japanese and German law are fairly comparable regarding the establishment and resolution of IPR loan contracts. Still, some notable differences exist with regard to the potential of collateralizing IPR. In Japan, it is generally possible to collateralize all forms of a registered IPR (trademarks, patents, utility models, and designs). Japan also explicitly adds the use of copyright as loan collateral.66 Similar to Germany, there are two legal approaches: the pledge and the security assignment.67 As an important difference, in Japan a firm cannot collateralize the right to obtain an IPR, i.e., IPR prior to its being granted.68 In Germany, in other European jurisdictions, and in the US, firms can use IPR as collateral prior to the grant. As a relevant side note, the Japanese Supreme Court has not yet faced any case where the security assignment of an IPR was disputed. Since it is governed by Japanese case law,69 the application of an IPR-backed security assignment could still entail a degree of uncertainty. Regarding the resolution of the loan contract, Japanese law does not demand a mandatory public auction (as in Germany) in the case of a loan default. IPR pledges are enforced privately and extrajudicially.70

Just like in Japan, in the US all registered IPR and copyright can be collateralized. Here, IPR collateral is governed by the general rules of the Uniform Commercial Code. Further, IPR-related aspects are determined by specific federal IP laws.71 With regard to security devices, the US is unique since it only allows for one approach to secured transactions.72 As such, it reduces transaction costs by avoiding the potentially confusing multiple security vehicles. Similar to the German and Japanese pledge-of-rights scheme, the borrower remains the owner of the asset during the time of the pledge, while the lender can seize the collateral once the borrower defaults.73 In the event of a loan default, the lender becomes the new owner of the collateral and can freely decide on the future of the IPR.74

French law also allows the collateralization of patents, utility models, designs, copyright, and trademarks (except collective marks).75 To establish a loan contract, two security devices are common in France, which are fairly similar to the structures in Germany. First, it is common to pledge an IPR equivalent to the pledge of rights in Germany. As a second mode, loan contracts can be set up as a fiducia.76 In a fiducia, the borrower transfers the ownership of the IPR to one or more fiduciaries, who act as a third-party guarantee. If the borrower repays the loans in full, it receives the ownership of the respective IPR again. However, if the borrower fails to fulfill the loan contract, the lender becomes the new owner of the collateralized IPR.77 The fiducia is similar to a security assignment in Germany with the key difference being the transfer of ownership to a third party (the fiduciary).

b) Facilitating access to information: Public IPR registry

Next, we apply the taxonomy to the second group of institutional determinants, public registers. By providing information regarding past and present IPR pledges, institutions have the potential to determine the availability of information. In particular, IP offices are a valuable provider of information for potential lenders since they gather relevant information on IPR. In the first part, we describe the role of IP offices in collecting information relevant to IPR-backed loans. In the second part of this section, we apply the taxonomy to one specific registration type, the registration of pledges, in the previously described jurisdictions of Germany, Japan, the US, and France.

Alongside domestic contract law governing IPR collateralization, government institutions play a crucial role in the use of IPR as loan collateral. Loan agreements are typically shaped by asymmetric information, which determine their scale and scope. By providing information regarding past and present IPR pledges, government institutions are able to lower these asymmetries and thus enhance the use of IPR collateral. In particular, IP offices are a valuable provider of information for potential lenders since they gather relevant information on IPR.78

IP offices collect information on the applicant and on the IPR itself throughout its entire life. For the lender, the valuation of the IPR is key to determining default probabilities and adequately risk-adjusting loan pricing. The lender therefore seeks to obtain information on the value-related characteristics of the IPR. Important factors could be its technological field, age, and the claims protected by an IPR. Further, a lender can reduce information asymmetries by assessing the previous behavior of prospective borrowers. As such, lenders are interested in information on firms’ patent portfolios, such as the payment of renewal fees and unambiguous proof of ownership.

Information on the application or registration of an IPR, the grant decisions, and the fulfillment of maintenance duties are the data most consistently gathered by IP offices. They are a by-product of the legal interactions between the IPR owner and the respective offices. However, there are other types of events that affect parties outside the realm of the IP office, such as litigation cases, the transfer or licensing of IPR to another company, or the securitization of IPR to receive a bank loan. These events do not directly affect the work of the IP office in granting rights and thus they are not collected consistently. Specifically, it is not always mandatory for the parties involved to report these events, nor are they incentivized to do so. This circumstance leads to inconsistent reporting standards across legal events, IPR types, and jurisdictions. Once information is not collected at all or only inconsistently, lenders are not able to track the history and present status of borrowers’ patent portfolios with certainty.

From a lender’s perspective, reliable information on the actual ownership and the presence or absence of any third-party claims are decisive for accepting IPR as collateral. For example, for real estate it is mandatory in most developed countries to update the public land register in a timely and thorough manner. This way changes in ownership can be traced easily and reliably. A similar construct for IPR would be desirable, such that lenders are better informed about the status of an IPR over time.

Comparing Germany with Japan, the USA, and France: In the following, we describe how registration requirements differ across Germany, Japan, the US, and France. In Germany, the registration of pledges at the German Patent and Trademark Office (DPMA) is possible but not mandatory.79 This is different to other asset classes, specifically land, for which the registration of ownership-related obligations is binding.80 The absence of mandatory registrations to secure IPR might impose frictions, especially in relative comparison with other asset classes. The absence of such registries marks a potential source of information asymmetries between borrowers and lenders.81 These asymmetries may eventually be detrimental to the willingness to accept IPR as collateral.

In Japan, the registration of the security assignments for trademarks, patents, utility models, and designs is mandatory in order for the contract to become effective.82 This rule does not apply to IPR pledges. Claims against third parties cannot be ensured without registration, such that strong incentives to register exist.83 These inconsistent requirements are able to soften information asymmetries only to a limited extent.

US law does not require IPR pledges to be registered in order to become effective, just like in Germany and Japan. However, in order to perfect a loan, registration is necessary.84 This requirement provides relatively strong incentives for lenders to register collateralized IPR. At the same time, there is no central registry in the US: Inconsistencies across federal and state law introduce uncertainty about which law governs the effective registration of IPR pledges.85 On the one hand, the United States Patent and Trademark Office (USPTO) provides a method for recording security interests with trademarks and patents.86 On the other hand, each state provides a filing system via UCC financing statements, where all types of collateral can be registered. Although there are strong incentives to register IPR pledges, it often remains unclear where they should be registered.87 It is therefore questionable whether the existing US registries are effective in mitigating information asymmetries. Nevertheless, aggregate statistics from the US suggest that IPR loans are commonly applied, exceeding IP-backed lending activities in Europe by far.88 One potential reason for this is that the US allows for so-called blanket liens, which are a general collection of corporate assets in security agreements. In such a case, IPR are pledged by default, not by choice. This practice is not allowed in several other jurisdictions, in particular in Europe, where IPR collateral has to be explicitly stated in loan agreements.89

The French system has relatively thorough registration requirements in place. The law states that the designation of the secured debt as well as the quantity, type, and nature of the IPR collateral must be registered to make it opposable.90 This requirement applies for both the pledge and the fiducia. Unlike in the abovementioned jurisdictions, the publication of registration in France is mandatory for the validity of the loan contract.91

c) Cost drivers of IPR securitization: banking regulations

As the final institutional determinant, we consider banking regulations. To describe how these regulations currently may affect the collateralization of IPR, we assess the regulatory capital requirements of IPR loans relative to loans that do not use IPR as collateral. In general, the Basel III Accords stipulate the capital requirements in most countries around the globe, including the US, all EU Member States, and Japan. For this reason, we do not provide a separate country-specific assessment as in the previous subsections. The Basel III Accords stipulate that banks hold a minimum capital buffer that equals 8% of risk-weighted assets. Risk weights can be calculated using two different approaches: an internal ratings based (IRB) approach in which banks need to receive supervisory approval, or a standardized approach. In both cases, capital requirements are a function of two main components, the probability of default and the exposure amount, i.e., the loss-given-default. Since these two components are independent of the specific characteristics of the examined assets, we cannot conclude that capital requirements per se discriminate between tangible and intangible assets.

However, a more detailed perspective on the regulatory framework discloses potentially discriminating factors. The IRB allows banks to use internal estimates of risk components to calculate capital requirements for a given exposure. This approach thus allows banks to determine the probability of default using an internal rating firms’ own discretion. It appears plausible that valuable asset portfolios improve the internal rating. Hence, valuable IP portfolios may be recognized by banks that use IRB to calculate default probabilities.

More specifically, under the IRB approach, the loss-given-default can be adjusted depending on the provision of eligible collateral. As the most basic case, eligibility criteria only define potential loan collateral as being financial assets and physical property, such as cash, receivables, or real estate. Loans secured against these assets require less capital as compared to unsecured loans. These discounts can be quite substantial and have risk weights that range between 0% and 25%. Importantly, intellectual property is not explicitly acknowledged under IRB, which means that IPR-backed loans do not have a mitigating effect on the banks’ regulatory capital but carry a risk weight of 100% (i.e., no discount) – just like unsecured loans. Even if banks indeed recognize the value of debtors’ IPR, this aspect may still drive a wedge between the banks’ willingness to provide IPR loans and those secured with eligible collateral.92

Second, banks may use a standardized approach, which is structured quite differently from the IRB. The standardized approach generally assigns firms with a risk weight of 100% but allows for a variable risk weight if the borrowing entity has received an external rating by an official institution that assesses credit. This is an important feature for our assessment, since external rating agencies can be expected to acknowledge valuable IPR portfolios in their ratings. In turn, banks can be expected to recognize the value of borrowers’ IPR portfolios using the standardized approach. However, this approach does not explicitly refer to the use of IPR as loan collateral.

Further, the standardized approach allows banks to apply a set of mitigation techniques for credit risk, such as the assignment of collateral.93 However, collateral is restricted to financial collateral, such as cash or debt securities. Unlike the IRB approach, the standardized approach does not take any further assets into account irrespective of whether they are of tangible or intangible nature. Hence, this relatively strict aspect of the standardized approach does not allow for discrimination among asset classes.

These considerations show that regulatory capital requirements do not per se discriminate between tangible and intangible assets such as IPR that are pledged in loan contracts. As one notable exception, IPR-backed loans qualify as unsecured loans for banks using an IRB approach. This feature introduces a discriminatory factor in the current institutional framework. However, additional specifications (i.e., the advanced IRB approach) may mitigate this difference. Overall, banking regulations might have only a modest, but rather negative effect on the use of IPR as collateral.

2. Economic determinants: Cost-benefit trade-off of collateral

In the following, we discuss the economic benefits and costs of using IPR as collateral in business loans. We thereby focus on three main IPR characteristics: redeployability, asset-specificity, and the uncertainty of claims. In this section, we discuss all IPR jointly, but would like to clearly stress that IPR differ with respect to these characteristics, although not in substance but in degree. We make use of these differences later on, when deriving a number of hypotheses stemming from our analysis in which we explicitly aim to identify and point out these differences among IPR types.

a) Economic benefits of IPR as collateral

One of the most prominent benefits of collateral is to mitigate adverse selection and, thus, potential credit rationing.94 Collateral may induce a self-selection mechanism, which avoids (non-price) credit rationing à la Stiglitz and Weiss.95 The underlying mechanism is the idea that it is less costly for low-risk borrowers to provide collateral as compared to high-risk borrowers. Lenders can exploit this relationship between the expected costs of collateral and risk-type to offer separating contracts that help to overcome credit rationing. Therefore, collateral may serve as an instrument to circumvent a main friction in the credit market, i.e., asymmetric information, which leads to non-price credit rationing.96

The screening and/or signaling mechanisms should potentially function even better with an IPR than with conventional tangible collateral such as real estate. With tangible assets, the relationship between the ability to put up collateral and the quality of the projects undertaken is less stringent than with IPR. It is much harder (and more costly) for firms with low capabilities to pretend high capabilities via IPR.97 Further, offering an IPR as collateral should be viewed as a valid signal, because the value of the collateralized asset is clearly more important for the borrower than for the lender. For example, the threat of losing the collateralized asset means forgoing a core asset for the borrower’s business operations. Given the potentially wide wedge between the value of IPR to the lender as compared to the borrower, this difference makes this mechanism specifically powerful. This mechanism functions particularly well if the IPR is specific to the borrower’s operations. Then, bad borrowers have a significantly lower incentive to pledge the valuable asset since they face a higher probability of losing it.

Another benefit of collateral is that it allows firms to compensate for a lack of other sources of pledegable income.98,99 In this context, collateralizing assets is beneficial, since it incentivizes management to generate sufficient pledgeable income from the project’s returns in order to avoid restructuring measures in which management foregoes at least some of their control rights.100 The threat of losing a collateralized asset in the event of default is a strong incentive for the borrower to undertake significant efforts to service the debt and avoid any measures that divert assets and pledgeable income. Another benefit of collateralizing assets is that it boosts pledgeable income per se.

For the purpose of incentivizing repayments, the value from the borrower’s perspective is decisive. The larger the value for the borrower, then the larger the incentive to repay. The collateral value for the lender plays the key role for the purpose of boosting pledgeable income per se. Since this latter purpose is often the crucial one, the wedge between the borrowers’ and the lenders’ valuations of IPR collateral comes into play. The pledging of collateral is costly to the extent that lenders may value the collateral less than the borrower, and hence transferring it to lenders involves a deadweight loss. This deadweight loss may be particularly pronounced for collateralized IPR, because of the inherent informational frictions.101 As such, the wedge in valuation is particularly pronounced if there is significant uncertainty and asymmetric information on the scope of the IPR as well as on the definition of the IPR.

b) Economic costs of IPR as collateral

There are a number of costs that lead to deadweight losses, which clearly impose economic barriers against IPR being used as collateral in business loans. A key aspect for the value of collateral to generate pledgeable income in the event of default is the degree to which the IPR can be redeployed. Assets that are more easily redeployed provide higher liquidation values102, 103 and are thus associated with lower credit spreads.104 This is consistent with the idea that higher redeployability increases the expected income available to lenders in the event of the borrower’s default. In turn, lower redeployability means higher costs of credit in the loan contract, which is particularly problematic in the case of IPR, such as patents.105 Redeployability is closely related to the firm-specificity of assets. IPR are predominantly internally generated,106 such that they are relatively often specifically geared towards their owners’ needs, decreasing their redeployability. This is in particular the case if the IPR is attached to the human inventor capital that is non-alienable. Furthermore, in the event of default this specificity may lead to pronounced renegotiation that eventually creates a hold-up problem that may severely limit the pledgeable value of the IPR collateral.

Overall, it is important to note that the issue of redeployability and owner-specificity of IPR is not a barrier to their use as business collateral per se but rather of degree: IPR is on average more likely to be confronted with such issues as compared to tangible assets. Further, the degree of redeployability strongly depends on the IPR itself, both across and within IPR types. In principle, IPR protecting specific technologies (e.g., patents) should be less applicable to other uses than IPR that protect consumer goods (e.g., trademarks, designs). Similarly, some IPR protect very specific ideas or technologies and therefore cannot be easily redeployed, while others are known to protect general purposes and are therefore easier to redeploy.

Despite its importance, valuing IPR is inherently challenging. The main reason for this is the high degree of asymmetric information and the uncertainty of returns,107 as well as the highly skewed distribution of the economic importance, i.e., the IPR value.108,109 The more pronounced the degree of uncertainty and asymmetric information regarding the definition and the scope of the IPR, the more challenging the valuation exercise for the lender. Especially in the context of SMEs, the prevalence of information asymmetries between borrowers and lenders may also depend on their relationship. As such, relationship lending or local banking may lower the transfer costs associated with the exchange of (informal) information and, in turn, reduce these information asymmetries.110,111

To assess potential IPR collateral, it is important to identify those IPR that indeed carry meaningful value. Loan providers (i.e., banks) do not necessarily have the expertise for such a specialized assessment, which often requires industry-specific knowledge. Therefore, an appropriate evaluation requires that the lender has a specialized in-house department, or the parties involved need to commission expert agencies.

A further problem associated with the valuation of IPR as collateral is their partial incompleteness, which can be challenged through invalidity claims. This process takes place via the respective government body in the case of trademarks or design patents, or via courts in the case of patents. Depending on the particular setting, these claims can be filed by any party involved. In this context, a very important difference arises from the actual registration requirements (see also Table 1). While some IPR, such as copyright, are activated at the creation of the underlying IP, others require registration (trademarks and designs) or thorough examination (patents). The patent examination process follows a standardized, rigorous procedure that already entails a substantial analysis of patent quality. This is different with regard to other IPR types, such as trademarks, designs, or copyright, which are established qua creation or registration.112 It follows then that the degree of uncertainty of the IPR granted through the application or the registration process is more pronounced with registered rights as compared to patents. The search process and the certification function of the government agencies shifts in the case of non-patent IPR types to the potential lender, thereby exacerbating the value challenge even further.

Another potential cost associated with IPR as collateral in business loans is shared by many assets that are only partially owned by the party using them: improper maintenance of the asset, i.e., the moral hazard that leads to underinvestment in the proper maintenance of the asset. For instance, Igawa and Kanatas113 show that there is underinvestment in the maintenance of the pledged assets, which is a problem that can only be overcome by over-collateralizing. However, this approach requires the availability of collateral and also comes with extra costs. One of the key maintenance issues with IPR is the necessity to renew IPR and the associated renewal fees. One potential way forward is that automatic renewal is contracted between the parties, but this automatic procedure in turn would potentially mean excessive maintenance.

Weighting of costs and benefits: In essence, the individual weighting of costs and benefits from the perspectives of both borrowers and lenders are decisive for the collateralization of IPR. This weighting applies even if the institutional framework provides an ideal environment for this use. It can be concluded only if the benefits exceed the costs to the parties directly involved in the loan contract. Our analysis has shown that this cost-benefit trade-off is specific to jurisdictions and firm characteristics, and in particular specific to the respective IPR assets. In order to show the use of this analysis in future empirical research, we derive in the appendix  a number of testable hypotheses, which may lay the ground for future empirical work in this context.

V. Conclusion

In this paper, we develop a taxonomy that allows us to address a puzzling observation. Despite a long-standing shift towards a knowledge-driven economy in which IPR constitute a major share of firm values, firms’ use of IPR as collateral in loan contracts is relatively scarce around the globe. We first define two pillars that comprise the main institutional and economic determinants for collateralizing IPR. We argue that the key institutional determinants are contract law, public registries, and international banking regulations. These elements address the borrower-lender relationship both directly and indirectly and determine potential transaction costs significantly. The economic determinants consist of the interplay between the economic benefits and the costs of IPR collateral. We propose that IPR collateral can have significant advantages regarding signaling, agency issues, and pledgeable income. We suggest that both pillars, i.e., all determinants, need to reach a certain threshold to effectively support and enable the collateralization of IPR.

Our taxonomy allows for a detailed analysis of the main underlying mechanisms of IPR as business loan collateral. Further, it enables us to formulate policy implications as well as hypotheses for specific conditions under which the use of IPR collateral should be applicable. We consider to be both decisive elements towards a better understanding of the role of IPR for the financing of organizations. Moreover, we hope to spur the discourse among policymakers, practitioners, and academics, in the fields of both law and economics, about the modernization of bank lending in line with a technology-based economy.

Policy Implications: Our discussions lead us to the following main policy implications. First, our analysis shows that the general contractual law set-up in the countries discussed (Germany, Japan, France and the US) provides the legal basis, which allows (or does not impede) the inclusion of IPR as collateral in business loans. While the main stage is set for the inclusion of IPR, our analysis indicates that a more standardized approach would strengthen IPR-backed lending by decreasing uncertainties and the associated transactions costs. In addition to this, we acknowledge that there is still plenty of room for improvement in building capacity. Institutions require adequate human resources and infrastructure to determine the pledgeability and value of IPR. A lack of these resources inhibits the collateralization of IPR. Second, we show that public registries for IPR play a decisive role as certification devices for IPR. While IPR registries are established in all main jurisdictions, we see the need for improvements in the permanent updating of requirements of such registries. To improve the current system, the establishment of IPR collateral registries would be a valuable addition. Such institutionalized registries based on a mandatory reporting regime for IPR collateral of all kinds could help reduce asymmetric information and hence frictions that are associated with IP-backed lending. This calls for gradual reforms at the national level in all the jurisdictions we have looked at in this paper. Third, our analysis of the banking regulatory framework shows that capital requirements and in particular the calculation of risk weights does not discriminate between IPR and other assets per se. Nevertheless, IPR-backed loans do not qualify as secured debt in all risk weighting approaches. Leveling this imbalance or even discriminating positively in favor of IPR collateral has to be carefully weighed against the costs of financial (in-)stability. While the former suggestions for gradual reforms are a matter for national policies, the changes in banking regulations should be addressed at the supranational level, not least to avoid regulatory arbitrage.

Hypotheses

Our analysis enables us to determine the circumstances under which IPR collateral might be particularly suited to attract debt financing. As such, we have shown that the actual cost-benefit trade-off is jurisdiction-, firm-, and, in particular, asset-specific. Based on these considerations, we derive a number of hypotheses in the following.

By comparing four IP-intensive jurisdictions, we highlight both commonalities and differences across legal regimes. One important variation is the number of security devices. While multiple security devices allow firms and banks a certain flexibility to choose among respective devices, it is also prone to introducing confusion and unnecessary layers of complexity. The latter may create additional frictions in IPR-backed lending. IPR are more likely to be used as collateral in a legal regime that defines clear rules and avoids confusing security devices:

 

Hypothesis 1: We predict that collateralizing IPR is most common in legal regimes with the least complex security devices, such as the US with its uniform collateral regime.

IP offices collect and provide information on IPR. However, they seldom record certain information that is highly relevant to the collateralization of IPR. Such information includes not only IPR pledges themselves but also reliable ownership information published by an official source. Without this information, lenders potentially consider IPR collateral as risky due to increased information asymmetries. Thus, IPR are more likely to be used as collateral in a jurisdiction which registers relevant IPR-related events.

 

Hypothesis 2: We predict that the collateralization of IPR is most common in a jurisdiction where the IP office provides reliable ownership information and registers the collateralized IPR. Hence, in jurisdictions like Germany, which does not register IPR pledges, the use of IPR as collateral is expected to be less common.

We compare the regulatory capital requirements of IPR loans relative to loans that use non-IPR collateral. Overall, we find that the regulatory framework does not distinguish between IPR and other asset classes per se. However, IPR-backed loans are classified as unsecured loans under the IRB approach, although this specification can be mitigated by applying an advanced IRB approach. Similarly, IPR is not acknowledged as eligible collateral under the standardized approach.

 

Hypothesis 3: Banks that deploy an advanced internal-ratings-based approach are more likely to issue IPR-backed loans as compared to banks that use either the standardized approach or the regular internal-ratings-based approach.

Our analysis of the economic costs and benefits shows that a main driver of the potential to use an IPR as loan collateral is its value to the borrower (which uses it as a signaling device).

 

Hypothesis 4: A higher signaling value of the IPR should increase the likelihood that it will be used as collateral. For instance, we expect borrower-specific and value relevant patents to be add-on ingredients in collateral contracts together with other assets.

In addition, its potential use as a source of pledgeable income in the case of default makes collateralizing IPR more attractive. This aspect is more pronounced, the higher the level of redeployability and the lower the asset specificity of the IPR are. We expect that more specific (e.g., related to specific technologies) and less easily redeployed IPR is less likely to be used in loan contracts as collateral.

 

Hypothesis 5: Hence, less specific IPR (such as trademarks in consumer-goods industries) or with a track record of being redeployed (previous ownership transfers, licensing deals, securitizations) are more likely to be used as collateral.

Furthermore, we argue that for the purpose of collateralizing IPR, proper valuation is key. We have pointed out that a high degree of uncertainty and asymmetric information regarding the definition of the IPR as well as of its scope makes the valuation exercise more challenging for the lender.

 

Hypothesis 6: The easier it is for the lender to value the IPR (e.g., single-item patents) the more often we expect the IPR to be used in loan contracts as collateral. Similarly, we conjecture that IPR bundles such as patent thickets or products protected by multiple IPR types are likely to be jointly valued and pledged.

Appendix

IPR intensive sector contribution to country-level value added Notes: The graph displays the value added (GDP) of IPR-intensive sectors as a fraction of total GDP for the EU28 countries, the US, Korea, Germany, France, and the UK. For EU28 and the three European countries we use 2014-2016 averages obtained from EPO and EUIPO, ‘Intellectual property rights intensive industries and economic performance in the European Union, Industry-Level Analysis Report, September 2019, Third edition’ (2019). For the US, 2014 values are used from USPTO, ‘Intellectual Property and the U.S. Economy: 2016 Update’ (2016). For the Korean data, we use 2015 values obtained from KIIPO, ‘Korea Institute of Intellectual Property (KIIP): Analysis on Economic Contribution of IP-Intensive Industries (English summary)’ (2019). The three sources define IPR-intensive sectors in detail. Values are computed for the four main IPR categories separately and the total of all IP-intensive sectors. GDP shares do not identify overlaps in the contribution to total GDP. For the US, no data on the design-intensive sectors were available.
Figure IA1:

IPR intensive sector contribution to country-level value added Notes: The graph displays the value added (GDP) of IPR-intensive sectors as a fraction of total GDP for the EU28 countries, the US, Korea, Germany, France, and the UK. For EU28 and the three European countries we use 2014-2016 averages obtained from EPO and EUIPO, ‘Intellectual property rights intensive industries and economic performance in the European Union, Industry-Level Analysis Report, September 2019, Third edition’ (2019). For the US, 2014 values are used from USPTO, ‘Intellectual Property and the U.S. Economy: 2016 Update’ (2016). For the Korean data, we use 2015 values obtained from KIIPO, ‘Korea Institute of Intellectual Property (KIIP): Analysis on Economic Contribution of IP-Intensive Industries (English summary)’ (2019). The three sources define IPR-intensive sectors in detail. Values are computed for the four main IPR categories separately and the total of all IP-intensive sectors. GDP shares do not identify overlaps in the contribution to total GDP. For the US, no data on the design-intensive sectors were available.

Footnotes

*

Max Planck Institute for Innovation and Competition; Marstallplatz 1, 80539 Munich, Germany. Phone: +49 (0)89 24246 565; E-Mail: [email protected].

**

Goethe University Frankfurt; Theodor-W.-Adorno-Platz 4, 60323 Frankfurt, Germany. Phone +49 (0)69-79834820; E-Mail: [email protected].

***

Goethe University Frankfurt and LIF-SAFE; Theodor-W.-Adorno-Platz 4, 60323 Frankfurt, Germany. Phone +49 (0)69-9834821; E-Mail: [email protected].

1

See Allen N Berger and Gregory F Udell, ‘A more complete conceptual framework for SME finance’ (2006) 30(11) Journal of Banking & Finance 2945.

2

Giulio Bottazzi, Angelo Secchi and Federico Tamagni, ‘Financial constraints and firm dynamics’ (2014) 42(1) Small Business Economics 99.

3

Erik Brynjolfsson, Daniel Rock and Chad Syverson, ‘The productivity J-curve: How intangibles complement general purpose technologies’ (2021) 13(1) American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 333.

4

Giovanni Dell’Ariccia and others, ‘Bank lending in the knowledge economy’ (2021) 34(10) The Review of Financial Studies 5036.

5

See, eg, Antonio Falato and others, ‘Rising intangible capital, shrinking debt capacity, and the US corporate savings glut’ (2022) 77(5) The Journal of Finance 2799.

6

Bronwyn H Hall and Josh Lerner, ‘The financing of R&D and innovation’ in Bronwyn H Hall and Nathan Rosenberg, Handbook of the Economics of Innovation, vol 1 (Elsevier 2010).

7

Stuart JH Graham and others, ‘High technology entrepreneurs and the patent system: Results of the 2008 Berkeley patent survey’ (2009) 24(4) Berkeley Technology Law Journal 1255; EPO, ‘Unlocking untapped value – EPO SME case studies on IP strategy and IP management’ (2017).

8

Berger and Udell (n 1).

9

Dirk Czarnitzki and Hanna Hottenrott, ‘R&D investment and financing constraints of small and medium-sized firms’ (2011) 36(1) Small Business Economics 65.

10

William Mann, ‘Creditor rights and innovation: Evidence from patent collateral’ (2018) 130(1) Journal of Financial Economics 25.

11

Yael V Hochberg, Carlos J Serrano and Rosemarie H Ziedonis, ‘Patent collateral, investor commitment, and the market for venture lending’ (2018) 130(1) Journal of Financial Economics 74.

12

Stuart Graham, Alan Marco and Amanda Myers, ‘Monetizing marks: Insights from the USPTO Trademark Assignment Dataset’ (2018) 27(3) Journal of Economics & Management Strategy 403.

13

See, eg, Eva-Maria Kieninger, ‘Security Rights in Intellectual Property: General Report’ in Eva-Maria Kieninger, Security Rights in Intellectual Property (Springer 2020).

14

We derive a number of testable hypotheses in the Appendix to translate these insights into a basis for future empirical work.

15

Kieninger (n 13).

16

Mann (n 10).

17

Hochberg, Serrano and Ziedonis (n 11).

18

Graham, Marco and Myers (n 12).

19

Mann (n 10).

20

Hochberg, Serrano and Ziedonis (n 11).

21

Laurie Ciaramella, David Heller and Leo Leitzinger, ‘Intellectual Property as Loan Collateral: Evidence from France’ (2022) <http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.4260877> accessed 10 March 2024.

22

These relatively small numbers are comparable to other major IPR-intensive economies, such as Japan. Data provided by the Japanese Patent Office shows that the number of patent pledges was between 120 and 193 for the years 2012 and 2017, respectively. See Megumi Hara and Yuriko Haga, ‘Security rights in intellectual property in Japan’ in Kieninger (n 13).

23

See, eg, Ciaramella, Heller and Leitzinger (n 21).

24

See, eg, Mann (n 10).

25

Patent Act, 1959, art 33.

26

Intellectual Property Code, 1992, art L. 715-2 (No 4).

27

For illustration, consider the example of real estate as the asset class that is most typically used as loan collateral. First, contract law clearly defines the use of real estate as loan collateral, including an encompassing description of the rights and duties throughout the processes of establishing, maintaining, and resolving a loan agreement. Second, economies with a developed banking system typically have land registries to which both potential lenders and borrowers have access, and which comprise up-to-date information on the assets’ legal status. Third, according to international banking regulations, loans that are secured with real estate enjoy a pre-defined status as collateralized loan that defines lenders’ opportunity costs of providing such loans.

28

See, eg, Hall and Lerner (n 6).

29

This is in line with prior research showing that the public disclosure of IPR-related information through standardized and centralized institutions supports transactions in the market for ideas. See Joshua S Gans, David H Hsu and Scott Stern, ‘The impact of uncertain intellectual property rights on the market for ideas: Evidence from patent grant delays’ (2008) 54(5) Management Science 982.

30

Asli Demirguc-Kunt, Enrica Detragiache and Ouarda Merrouche, ‘Bank capital: Lessons from the Financial Crisis’ (2013) 45(6) Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 1147.

31

Anjan V Thakor, ‘Capital requirements, monetary policy, and aggregate bank lending: theory and empirical evidence’ (1996) 51(1) The Journal of Finance 279.

32

Henri Fraisse, Mathias Lé and David Thesmar, ‘The real effects of bank capital requirements’ (2020) 66(1) Management Science 5.

33

Jean Tirole, The Theory of Corporate Finance (Princeton University Press 2010).

34

See Arnoud WA Boot, Anjan V Thakor and Gregory F Udell, ‘Equilibrium Analysis, Policy Implications’ (1991) 101(406) The Economic Journal 458.

35

This use illustrates the fact that full information is not a necessary condition here. It is sufficient that borrowers and lenders have similar expectations of the distribution of a project’s returns, and the returns from the collateralized assets are stochastic. See Gabriel Jimenez, Vicente Salas and Jesus Saurina, ‘Determinants of collateral’ (2006) 81(2) Journal of Financial Economics 255.

36

See also Gans, Hsu and Stern (n 29).

37

Rafael La Porta and others, ‘Law and finance’ (1998) 106(6) Journal of Political Economy 1113.

38

Further, there are also two other forms in which the IPR is only indirectly used as loan collateral. The first is a security usufruct in which a person or group of persons uses the real property (often land) of others. However, this scheme is only applicable in a very limited number of jurisdictions, for example, Germany, France, or parts of the US. As an alternative, security licenses can be applied to collateralize IPR. In this approach, royalty payments are securitized but not the IPR itself.

39

See Moritz Brinkmann, David Rüther and Bianca Scraback, ‘Security rights in intellectual property in Germany’ in Kieninger (n 13).

40

As with any kind of private contractual agreements, specific loan details can be individually determined between the parties involved. For the establishment and the resolution of IPR-backed loan contracts, German law provides relatively clear instructions. For the time the contract is active, German law maps out several rules as rather general guidance.

41

Trademark Act, 1995, s 27 sub-s 1.

42

Patent Act, 1980, s 15 sub-s 1.

43

Utility Model Act, 1936, s 22 sub-s 1.

44

Design Protection Act, 2004, s 29, s 31.

45

For German law it is important to highlight that it stipulates the use of trademarks and design rights explicitly, while for other IP rights one can only implicitly infer from their transferability that they can be used as loan collateral. Regarding copyright, not all parts of the bundle of rights of a copyright are transferrable. This limits copyright to exploitation rights.

46

German Civil Code, 2002, s 1252.

47

Brinkmann, Rüther and Scraback (n 39).

48

ibid.

49

ibid.

50

This applies to all IPR types, irrespective of the specific obligation that perpetuates the right. For example, a trademark owner has the responsibility to continue using its trademark, since its validity may eventually lapse if it has not been used within a certain time span, such as five years in the US.

51

Maximilian Decker, Geistiges Eigentum als Kreditsicherheit: Status Quo und Reformmöglichkeiten unter besonderer Berücksichtigung der Empfehlungen des UNCITRAL Legislative Guide on Secured Transactions und dessen Annex, vol 72 (Mohr Siebeck 2012).

52

German Civil Code, 2002, s 1273 sub-s 2, s 1227.

53

See, eg, Peter Georg Picht, Vom materiellen Wert des Immateriellen: Immaterialgüterrechte als Kreditsicherungsmittel im nationalen und internationalen Rechtsverkehr, vol 230 (Mohr Siebeck 2018).

54

Brinkmann, Rüther and Scraback (n 39).

55

See, eg, Luigi Guiso, Paola Sapienza and Luigi Zingales, ‘The determinants of attitudes toward strategic default on mortgages’ (2013) 68(4) The Journal of Finance 1473.

56

German Insolvency Act, 1994, s 50.

57

Brinkmann, Rüther and Scraback (n 39).

58

Civil Procedure Act, 2005, s 857.

59

Brinkmann, Rüther and Scraback (n 39).

60

Decker (n 51).

61

See Xuan-Thao Nguyen, ‘Financing Innovation: Legal Development of Intellectual Property as Security in Financing, 1845-2014’ (2014) 48 Ind. L. Rev. 509.

62

Notably, this issue is not specific to IPR collateral but applies to all forms of secured debt transactions. For more details on this, see Adam J Levitin, ‘The paper chase: securitization, foreclosure, and the uncertainty of mortgage title’ (2013) 63 Duke LJ 637.

63

For example, the American Inventors Protection Act (AIPA) was a major alignment of the US patent system enacted in 1999. Within Europe, the 2004 EU Enforcement Directive constituted a major legislative change that harmonized IPR law across Member States.

64

Bronwyn H Hall and Christian Helmers, ‘The impact of international patent systems: Evidence from accession to the European Patent Convention’ (2019) 48(9) Research Policy 103810.

65

Kieninger (n 13).

66

Copyright Act, 1970, art 66(1).

67

Hara and Haga (n 22).

68

ibid.

69

While Japan generally follows a civil-law system, the Japanese security assignment (‘Joto-tanpo’) has been developed through case law, since it is omitted from the Civil Code (see Hara and Haga (n 22)).

70

ibid.

71

Brian W Jacobs, ‘Using intellectual property to secure financing after the worst financial crisis since the Great Depression’ (2011) 15(2) Marquette Intellectual Property Law Review 449.

72

See Uniform Commercial Code, 1952, art 9.

73

Thomas M Ward, Intellectual Property in Commerce (Clark Boardman Callaghan 2009).

74

ibid.

75

Michel Séjean and Nicolas Binctin, ‘Security rights in intellectual property in France’ in Kieninger (n 13).

76

Commercial Code, 2004, art 2011.

77

Séjean and Binctin in Kieninger (n 75).

78

For example, one of the key advantages of real estate as loan collateral stems from the fact that the information on real estate used as collateral is documented in public registries.

79

Trademark Act, 1995, s 29 sub-s 2; EU Trademark Regulation, art 19 sub-s 2; EU Trademark Directive, 2015, art 23 sub-s 2; 36 Design Protection Act, 2004, s 30 sub-s 2; Community Design Regulation, 2002, art 29 sub-s 2; Patent Act, 1980, s 30 sub-s 2 in connection with German Patent and Trademark Office Regulation, 2004, s 29.

80

German Civil Code, 2002, s 1191.

81

Picht (n 53).

82

Perfection Act, 1998, art 4(1), art 14.

83

See Souichirou Kozuka and Naoe Fujisawa, ‘Old Ideas Die Hard: An Analysis of the 2004 Reformation of Secured Transactions Law in Japan and Its Impact on Banking Practices’ (2008) 31 T. Jefferson L. Rev. 293.

84

Uniform Commercial Code, 1952, art 9.

85

See Jacobs (n 71).

86

This includes design patents, whereas security interests in copyrights are reported at the US Copyright Office (U.S. Code, 1988, 17 s 205).

87

See Jacobs (n 71).

88

See Ciaramella, Heller and Leitzinger (n 21).

89

See, eg, Kevin Aretz, Murillo Campello and Maria-Teresa Marchica, ‘Access to collateral and the democratization of credit: France’s reform of the Napoleonic Security Code’ (2020) 75(1) The Journal of Finance 45.

90

For French patents, see Intellectual Property Code, 1992, art R.613-55; for French trademarks, see ibid, art R. 714-4 IPC; for French designs, see ibid, art R. 512-15.

91

See, eg, Séjean and Binctin (n 75).

92

In specific instances, banks can apply for an advanced IRB that allows them to reduce the risk weight of secured and unsecured loans. At maximum, financial institutions may lower risk weights for unsecured loans down to a floor rate of 25%. Still, relative to loans secured with real estate (10%) or other physical collateral (15%), the lower bound of risk weights for IPR-backed loan transactions remains preferential to tangible assets.

93

Other mitigation techniques, such as on-balance sheet netting, guarantees/credit derivatives, or maturity mismatch, are not relevant for our analyses.

94

Helmut Bester, ‘Screening vs. rationing in credit markets with imperfect information’ (1985) 75(4) The American Economic Review 850.

95

Joseph E Stiglitz and Andrew Weiss, ‘Credit rationing in markets with imperfect information’ (1981) 71(3) The American Economic Review 393.

96

See on the very related signaling character of collateral: David Besanko and Anjan V Thakor, ‘Collateral and rationing: sorting equilibria in monopolistic and competitive credit markets’ (1987) International economic review 671; David Besanko and Anjan V Thakor, ‘Competitive equilibrium in the credit market under asymmetric information’ (1987) 42(1) Journal of Economic Theory 167.

97

Notwithstanding, higher mimicking costs do not mean that pretending is not possible at all. For example, firms may choose to obtain a large but low-quality IPR portfolio. However, this portfolio appears as a fairly unlikely strategy, since large portfolios incur significant costs (see, eg, Andrej Gill and David Heller, ‘Leveraging Intellectual Property: The Value of Harmonized Enforcement Regimes’ (2022) <https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=4278423> accessed 10 March 2024). Therefore, firms would have to anticipate that their portfolio costs are off-set by lower costs of capital.

98

Patrick Bolton and David S Scharfstein, ‘A theory of predation based on agency problems in financial contracting’ [1990] The American Economic Review 93.

99

Oliver Hart and John Moore, ‘Default and renegotiation: A dynamic model of debt’ (1998) 113(1) The Quarterly Journal of Economics 1.

100

Tirole (n 33).

101

See, eg, Hall and Lerner (n 6).

102

See Oliver E Williamson, ‘Corporate finance and corporate governance’ (1988) 43(3) The Journal of Finance 567.

103

Andrei Shleifer and Robert W Vishny, ‘Liquidation values and debt capacity: A market equilibrium approach’ (1992) 47(4) The Journal of Finance 1343.

104

Efraim Benmelech and Nittai K Bergman, ‘Collateral pricing’ (2009) 91(3) Journal of Financial Economics 339.

105

See Hochberg, Serrano and Ziedonis (n 11).

106

Ryan H Peters and Lucian A Taylor, ‘Intangible capital and the investment-q relation’ (2017) 123(2) Journal of Financial Economics 251.

107

See, eg, Bronwyn H Hall and Dietmar Harhoff, ‘Recent research on the economics of patents’ (2012) 4(1) Annu. Rev. Econ. 541.

108

Dietmar Harhoff and others, ‘Citation frequency and the value of patented inventions’ (1999) 81(3) Review of Economics and Statistics 511.

109

Ashish Arora and Alfonso Gambardella, ‘The market for technology’ in Hall and Rosenberg (n 6) 641.

110

See Berger and Udell (n 1).

111

Andrea Bellucci and others, ‘Collateralization and Distance’ (2019) 100 Journal of Banking & Finance 205.

112

Notably, there are some important requirements for trademarks too. For example, since unused trademarks are subject to invalidation, the fact that they are active several years after registration implicitly suggests that they are actually in use.

113

Kazuhiro Igawa and George Kanatas, ‘Asymmetric information, collateral, and moral hazard’ (1990) 25(4) Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 469.

This is an Open Access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted reuse, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.