Abstract

The maximum sustainable yield (MSY) concept is widely considered to be outdated and misleading. In response, fisheries scientists have developed models that often diverge radically from the first operational version of the concept. We show that the original MSY concept was deeply rooted in ecology and that going back to that version would be beneficial for fisheries, not least because the various substitutes have not served us well.

Introduction

Although maximum sustainable yield (MSY) is enshrined in national and international law (e.g. in the UN Convention on the Law of the Sea—UNCLOS 1982), the original concept of Schaefer (1954) derived from the logistic curve of population growth is frequently viewed by fisheries and other scientists as an outdated notion, which has been bypassed by a better understanding of ecological and human systems (Larkin, 1977; Corkett, 2002; Finley and Oreskes, 2013).

Sidney Holt, to whom this issue of the Journal and thus this essay is dedicated, also loathed the concept (Pauly, 2020), as frequently expressed in his private correspondence with the authors. Especially, he often pointed out that there was no single MSY value for a given stock, but rather what he termed “local” MSY values because MSY depends on the size or age at first capture, i.e. the selectivity of the gears used in the fishery (Beverton and Holt, 1957; Froese et al., 2018). He also often found the published results of fitting catch and effort data to an equilibrium parabola as highly questionable. As we shall see, this is understandable, but near the end of his life, he relented and proposed a rational application of the concept in a letter to the European Commission (Holt and Froese, 2015).

As well, the MSY concept is often criticized by aquatic ecologists who believe that this single-species construct stands in the way of ecosystem-based fisheries management (EBFM) or one of its variants. We have been part of the latter group, judging the original MSY concept as too simplistic with often very unsatisfactory fits, but after using a new Bayesian Monte Carlo Markov Chain approach for fitting the model to available time-series data of catch and cpue for hundreds of stocks globally (Palomares et al., 2020) (rather than using the original parabola fitting, which Sidney Holt rightly ridiculed), we now think we were wrong. We now believe that the MSY concept, although it applies to single-species management (Froese et al., 2008, 2016b), can be, if applied correctly, more useful than many of the overly data-hungry and potentially over-parameterized implementations of EBFM.

To reestablish the compromised credibility of MSY, however, we must first look at its history (Tsikliras and Froese, 2016) roots, which actually go back to very basic Darwinian concepts.

Density-dependent population growth

Evolutionary biology (and there is no other; see Dobzhansky, 1973) postulates that:

  1. all organisms produce more offspring than can be accommodated by the environment they inhabit;

  2. These offspring all differ in heritable fashion; and

  3. (1) and (2) will lead to differential survival and the enhancement of advantageous traits (Darwin, 1859).

While (2) and (3) need not further concern us, notably because they involve longer time-periods than considered here, item (1) is crucial because it implicitly identifies the intrinsic growth rate (r) and carrying capacity (k) for each population of organisms (Figure 1).

This (virus and) bacteria-to-whale plot is from Blueweiss et al. (1978), with addition by Pauly (1982a), and it shows that the intrinsic growth rate of populations (r) can be roughly predicted from the size of the organisms in question. However, additional parameters must be considered for more precise estimations; see e.g. FishBase (www.fishbase.org) for fish.
Figure 1.

This (virus and) bacteria-to-whale plot is from Blueweiss et al. (1978), with addition by Pauly (1982a), and it shows that the intrinsic growth rate of populations (r) can be roughly predicted from the size of the organisms in question. However, additional parameters must be considered for more precise estimations; see e.g. FishBase (www.fishbase.org) for fish.

Malthus (1798), whose influence on Darwin was crucial (Herbert, 1971; Pauly, 2004), was the first to explicitly define the growth rate of a population and to compute it for a (human) population. Mathematically, Malthus’ model is commonly expressed as:
(1)
where Nt1is the population size in numbers at time t1, Nt2is at time t2, and r is the intrinsic rate of population growth.
Verhulst (1838) was the first to define carrying capacity mathematically. His model can be represented as:
(2)
where dN/dt is the instantaneous increase in numbers at population size Nt and k is the carrying capacity of the environment for this population.

Things are more complicated than that in nature where population growth rate and carrying capacity vary, but the concepts embodied in (1) and (2) have served us well. Thus, a huge amount of work in ecology is devoted to establishing the carrying capacity and its changes in various ecosystems (see e.g. Del Monte-Luna et al., 2004). Similarly, an enormous amount of research is devoted to estimating the intrinsic growth rate of populations, which is primarily a function of the body size of the organisms in question (Figure 1), but which can vary as a function of longevity and fecundity, as illustrated in FishBase (www.fishbase.org) for fishes.

The first half of the 20th century saw different attempts to identify principles or a “law” that would provide a quantitative criterion by which to assess the status of a fishery, and much good science was performed in the hope to achieve this (Baranov, 1918; Graham, 1935).

The first abuse

Unfortunately, politics intervened on the way, and the first version of MSY was put together as a rhetorical device by Chapman (1949). His invention (Figure 2) was a Gaussian curve of sustainable yields as a function of fishing intensity; on its left side was “inadequate” fishing, as reportedly occurred with the Pacific tuna stocks in Central and South America that the US fleet wanted to exploit, and on its right side was “excessive” fishing, as reportedly occurred in Alaska salmon that Japan wanted to fish (Finley, 2011; Pauly, 2012; Finley and Oreskes, 2013).

The first and fake representation of a “model” featuring maximum sustainable yield, as published by Chapman (1949). W. M. Chapman never presented a rationale for the Gaussian shape.
Figure 2.

The first and fake representation of a “model” featuring maximum sustainable yield, as published by Chapman (1949). W. M. Chapman never presented a rationale for the Gaussian shape.

Needless to say, this construct, published in an obscure magazine of the US State Department, had no underlying theory describing a Gaussian relation between sustainable yields and effort, but it won the day: Chapman’s “MSY” became the basis of international fisheries negotiation to the great chagrin of Ray Beverton and especially Sidney Holt, who, in the early 1950s, had jointly developed, based on Graham (1935), a scientifically sound approach to rational fisheries management (Beverton and Holt, 1957).

Putting things right

In 1954, M. B. Schaefer resolved the embarrassing situation by formulating his surplus yield model (Schaefer, 1954, 1957), which builds on (1) and (2) above, i.e.
(3)
where Y is the equilibrium yield or the surplus production of biomass, Bt is the biomass at time t, and B0 is the “virgin” or unexploited biomass, the equivalent of carrying capacity k expressed as weight of the population.

Schaefer (1954) set his model in the context of the biology and ecology of his time, as evidenced by his citation of texts such as Lotka (1925), Pearl (1925), Gause (1934), and Nicholson (1947). The Schaefer surplus production model was quickly accepted by the authors of fisheries science textbooks, probably because it summarized in a simple equation a variety of concepts (mortality, growth, and reproduction) that fishery biology students had to know about (Figure 3).

Basic elements of the Schaefer surplus production model. (a) A population invading an open space or recovering from a catastrophic decline will typically grow in sigmoid fashion, i.e. exponentially at first, then with at a declining rate as carrying capacity is approached. (b) The first derivative of the population growth curve [red line in (a)] plotted against the biomass from a parabola of surplus production vs. biomass, whose maximum occurs at B0/2 (see text).
Figure 3.

Basic elements of the Schaefer surplus production model. (a) A population invading an open space or recovering from a catastrophic decline will typically grow in sigmoid fashion, i.e. exponentially at first, then with at a declining rate as carrying capacity is approached. (b) The first derivative of the population growth curve [red line in (a)] plotted against the biomass from a parabola of surplus production vs. biomass, whose maximum occurs at B0/2 (see text).

Subsequent implementations of the MSY concept did not try to fit independent pairs of catch and abundance to the equilibrium parabola resulting from (3), but rather to estimate the values of r and k that best explain the observed interannual changes in biomass (Bt+1) given the biomass (Bt) and catch (Ct) in the previous year (4) (see Quinn and Deriso, 1999 for similar implementations):
(4)

Recent state-of-the-art implementations of (4) are implemented as state-space models using a Bayesian approach combined with Monte Carlo Markov Chain sampling so that prior information on productivity and stock status can be considered and observation and process errors can be separated from the uncertainty in estimates of r and k (Froese et al., 2017; Pedersen and Berg, 2017; Winker et al., 2018).

A further development combines (4) with a simple hockey-stick model of recruitment, such that parameter r, which combines rates of mortality, somatic growth, and recruitment, is reduced linearly if stock size Bt falls below 25% of unexploited stock size B0 (Froese et al., 2017):
(5)

Model drift

Other fisheries practitioners have modified the original Schaefer model, but without presenting a convincing theory for their changes. Thus, Pella and Tomlinson (1969) proposed replacing the parabola of the Schaefer model by a family of lumped curves derived from:
(6)
where r and Bt are as defined previously, and m was an added parameter determining the shape of the curves, without a firm base in evolutionary ecology or population dynamics, often fixed beforehand based on assumptions, or estimated ad hoc from the data at hand (Figure 4a).
Examples of the equilibrium (= sustainable) yield curves that can be reportedly generated by the Pella–Tomlinson model. (a) By varying the parameter m, a family of curves can be generated. Thus, for example, with m = 0.27, the model predicts MSY to occur at about 12% of carrying capacity (adapted from Figure 1 in Pella and Tomlinson, 1969). (b) An application of the Pella–Tomlinson model to catch and effort data on Pacific halibut, compared to the parabolic Schaefer model (Ricker, 1975, example 13.5), supposedly demonstrating the superiority of the former model (adapted from Figure 4 in Rivard and Bledsoe, 1978).
Figure 4.

Examples of the equilibrium (= sustainable) yield curves that can be reportedly generated by the Pella–Tomlinson model. (a) By varying the parameter m, a family of curves can be generated. Thus, for example, with m =0.27, the model predicts MSY to occur at about 12% of carrying capacity (adapted from Figure 1 in Pella and Tomlinson, 1969). (b) An application of the Pella–Tomlinson model to catch and effort data on Pacific halibut, compared to the parabolic Schaefer model (Ricker, 1975, example 13.5), supposedly demonstrating the superiority of the former model (adapted from Figure 4 in Rivard and Bledsoe, 1978).

The often extremely bad fit of the curve(s) in question to the available data (see e.g. the non-symmetric curve in Figure 4b) should have caused this approach to be dropped. But the Pella and Tomlinson model offered the flexibility that some managers and scientists had asked for. Unfortunately, that flexibility can be abused by arbitrarily choosing a low value of m in (6), resulting in MSY occurring at biomass levels that are much lower than ½ carrying capacity, thus presenting a given stock in better condition than predicted by the original Schaefer model.

Shortly thereafter, Fox (1970) proposed an “exponential” version of the surplus yield model with the new property that “the population can never be eliminated by any finite level of fishing effort” (Fox, 1970, p. 84). This model, which can be seen as a special case of the Pella–Tomlinson model (with m =1.0 and B/BMSY at 37% of carrying capacity), also has no basis in biology. It produces a yield curve with a long tail on the right side, instead of the symmetric parabola of the original Schaefer model. It was, for example, applied to multispecies assemblages in the Gulf of Thailand, which tended to generate concave catch-per-effort over effort curves (Pauly and Chuenpagdee, 2003). The long tail on the right (similar to that in Figure 4b) of such multispecies curves is partly due to the transformation of the exploited ecosystem in question, i.e. the loss of large, slow-growing species (low r) and their replacement by smaller, more resilient species (high r). Stationarity of parameters (here: r and k) over the examined period, the basic (if often unstated) assumption of assessment models, was abandoned in such applications.

Moreover, attempts to produce better fits of non-symmetric curves to the available data by ignoring the equilibrium assumption led to misinterpretations of the data and very dangerous conclusions for managers. For example, looking at Figure 4b and assuming low effort marks the beginning of the fishery on a stock with close to unexploited biomass, then the initial catches obtained from low effort will be high because of the high abundance of fish in the water, as predicted by the non-symmetric curve. But these are not equilibrium catches and rather will decrease towards the predictions of the parabola if the respective effort was maintained. Similarly, the two points with the highest effort in Figure 4b, if maintained indefinitely, are unlikely to produce the relatively high yields predicted by the non-symmetric curve, but much more likely the lower equilibrium yields predicted by the parabola. Considering that such high effort would probably push stock size down into the range where recruitment may be impaired (5), true equilibrium yield may be well below half of what is predicted by the supposedly better fit of the non-symmetric curve.

In summary, we have the situation that the fisheries management agencies of several major countries of the world used MSY biomass levels of 30–40% of carrying capacity and very gradual decline in biomass after the peak in yield, while seemingly relying on a model explicitly stating that biomasses lower than 50% of carrying capacity are overfished and stock decline will be rapid. This is further aggravated by the fact that the official stock assessments that produced these estimates are often biased downward because they are based on time-series that are truncated (Prefontaine, 2009), i.e. fail to include available information that suggest much higher earlier biomass (see e.g. Rosenberg et al., 2005).

Note that applications of the yield-per-recruit model of Beverton and Holt (1957) also often suggest maximum productivity between 30 and 40% of unfished biomass. However, this is typically the result of much too high fishing pressure with suboptimal selectivity causing high fishing mortality of juveniles. We reproduce here as Figure 5 the graph that Sidney Holt (Holt and Froese, 2015) sent to the European Commission in support of his argument that target fishing pressure should be well below the MSY level. If the proposed target level of Flower ≈ 0.6Fmsy is combined with the length at first capture that generates the maximum catch for a given F (Beverton and Holt, 1957), then the resulting relative biomass is above 50% of carrying capacity (see Figure 2b in Froese et al., 2016b). This demonstrates the compatibility of the yield-per-recruit model of Beverton and Holt (1957) and the MSY model of Schaefer (1954), if both are applied with optimal selectivity and catch levels.

This figure (from Holt and Froese, 2015, with permission) had as its original caption: “Relation between fishing effort or cost of fishing and predicted long-term catches. Note that 95% of the theoretical maximum catch can be obtained with substantially lower effort and cost (Flower) and thus with substantially higher profits for the fishers”.
Figure 5.

This figure (from Holt and Froese, 2015, with permission) had as its original caption: “Relation between fishing effort or cost of fishing and predicted long-term catches. Note that 95% of the theoretical maximum catch can be obtained with substantially lower effort and cost (Flower) and thus with substantially higher profits for the fishers”.

Another form of abuse of the MSY concept occurs when it is applied to an ensemble of discrete populations. An example of such abuse is the computation of a single MSY based on adding the biomasses of independent seamount-specific populations of orange roughy (Aplostethus atlanticus). This obviously does not make sense because the orange roughy populations on different seamounts do not interact such that a declining biomass of one would affect the density, and hence population growth, of the other (Clark et al., 2000). In addition, these orange roughy stocks were managed with a so-called “hard limit” at 10%, a “soft” limit at 20%, and a target value of 30–40% of carrying capacity (MRAG, 2016), a double misuse of the MSY concept which led to the collapse of numerous seamount spawning aggregations (Clark, 2001).

A similar strategy is currently applied to the krill fishery in Antarctica, which justifies its extraction of local populations of krill (Euphausia superba) with the observation that “[t]he actual annual catch is around 0.3% of the unexploited biomass of krill”, referring to all krill populations in Antarctica rather than to the exploited populations (see www.ccamlr.org/en/fisheries/krill-fisheries-and-sustainability).

The point here is that rates of mortality, growth, and reproduction, which are, we recall, the mechanisms that determine the intrinsic rate of population growth, occur at the scale of local populations, not of species composed of multiple populations.

Why MSY and EBFM are compatible

In principle, most fisheries scientists and relevant legislations and regulations agree that MSY should be a limit, and not a target, for fisheries management (UNFSA, 1995; Froese et al., 2008, 2016b; CFP, 2013; Punt et al., 2014), notably because if it were a target, and successfully implemented, then there would be a 50% probability that the biomass of the managed stock would be below the level that can produce MSY. This generally implies that target biomass should be set above the MSY level, as is done explicitly in recently formulated fisheries regulations (e.g. CFP, 2013).

Moreover, attempts to maximize the rent from fisheries, whether implemented via F0.1 (Gulland and Boerema, 1973) or by setting effort at the level which generates maximum economic yield (MEY), as e.g. required in Australia (DAFF, 2007; HSP, 2018), also imply that optimal biomass for stable stock and profitable fishing should be above the MSY level. At biomass levels of e.g. 60% or more of carrying capacity, populations should be much more capable of fulfilling their ecological roles as prey or predator than at the 30–40% levels targeted by supposedly more advanced fisheries models, while at the same time supporting good catches close to the economic optimum.

Thus, with MSY as a limit (see above), fisheries scientists would propose a goal that produces high return for fisheries, high catch for consumers, and far more fish in the water than at present. Moreover, single-species stocks of forage fish should be maintained at biomass levels above 60% of carrying capacity to provide food for fish-eating seabirds, marine mammal populations, and other large predators (Cury et al., 2011; Pikitch et al., 2012).

We are aware that it is not possible to manage multispecies fisheries such that they would get the sum of single stock MSYs. This is obvious from the above mentioned general need to preserve high levels of forage fish to stabilize ecosystems and fisheries, but also from special predator–prey interactions such as documented for central Baltic cod (Gadus morhua) and sprat (Sprattus sprattus) (Köster and Möllmann, 2000) or from cyclic alternations between systems dominated by anchovy (Engraulis ringens) or sardine (Sardinops sagax) off Peru (Muck, 1989). Another example is negative correlation between biomass of northern shrimp (Pandalus borealis) and Atlantic cod (G. morhua) (Worm and Myers, 2003). In two of his last papers (Froese et al., 2016a; Pauly et al., 2016), Sidney Holt joined us in refuting a proposal calling for simultaneous MSY level exploitation of all species in the oceans, from zooplankton to birds and whales (Garcia et al., 2012). In contrast, given the present realities, rebuilding commercially important fish populations towards levels near 60% of unexploited biomass would satisfy what presently appear to be conflicting demands for more fish for consumers, profits for the fisheries sector, and more fish in the water for the conservation community and thus for all.

We are also aware that the assumption of stationarity inherent in most of the above considerations is questionable in an increasing number of cases, given anthropogenic impacts on both the biosphere and the climate. Thus, while the intrinsic rate of population growth (r) may not be much impacted by our activities, the carrying capacity (k) of many exploited populations has changed radically in recent years. Thus, the carrying capacity of multiple species of cephalopods appears to have increased in recent decades, due to the fisheries-induced depletion of large fish, their main predators (Doubleday et al., 2016), as has the carrying capacity of penaeid shrimps in different parts of the world (Pauly, 1982b; Walters et al., 2008) and that of lobster in the Gulf of Maine (Steneck et al., 2011). This is similar to the effect of ocean warming, the reason why fish, since the mid-1970s, tend to shift or expand their distributions poleward, as shown in multiple contributions covering one or a few species (e.g. Perry et al., 2005) or the bulk of the exploited marine fauna (Cheung et al., 2013). In all such cases, the simple models presented here would estimate the average carrying capacity over the period considered. While that may be sufficient for a preliminary assessment of stock status, it may be better to split the time-series data into reasonably stable periods and assess those separately.

Conclusion

In summary, Larkin’s (1977) epitaph for MSY was premature and likely influenced by the misapplications and distortions of the concept occurring in the 1970s. As for Sidney Holt, he had every reason to be outraged by the politics around the MSY concept, such as illustrated in Figure 2, and the lack of biology in its subsequent developments. He especially despised the notion of a single MSY value, when, in fact, that value is a function of length or age at first capture. He, however, conceded, if grudgingly, that surplus production models were better than no assessment in data-limited situations and better than the various schemes to continue overfishing, such as the Fupper approach illustrated in Figure 5. We believe that we have much to gain by rehabilitating M. B. Schaefer’s concept of MSY.

Data availability statement

No new data were generated or analysed in support of this research.

References

Baranov
F. I.
1918
.
On the question of the biological basis of fisheries
.
Nauchnyl˘ issledovatelskil˘ iktiologisheskil˘ Institut, Izvestiia
,
1
:
81
128
.

Beverton
R. J. H.
,
Holt
S. J.
1957
. On the Dynamics of Exploited Fish Populations. Ministry of Agriculture, Fisheries and Food. Fishery Investigations, London, Series II, XIX.
533
pp.

Blueweiss
L.
,
Fox
H.
,
Kudzma
V.
,
Nakashima
D.
,
Peters
R.
,
Sams
S.
1978
.
Relationships between body size and some life history parameters
.
Oecologia
,
37
:
257
272
.

CFP
.
2013
.
Regulation (EU) No 1380/2013 of the European Parliament and of the Council of 11 December 2013 on the Common Fisheries Policy
.
Official Journal of the European Union
,
354
:
22
61
.

Chapman
W. M.
1949
. United States policy on high sea fisheries. In Department of State Bulletin, XX(498):
67
80
.

Cheung
W. W. L.
,
Watson
R.
,
Pauly
D.
2013
.
Signature of ocean warming in global fisheries catch
.
Nature
,
497
:
365
368
.

Clark
M.
2001
.
Are deepwater fisheries sustainable?—the example of orange roughy (Hoplostethus atlanticus) in New Zealand
.
Fisheries Research
,
51
:
123
135
.

Clark
M. R.
,
Anderson
O. F.
,
Francis
R. C.
,
Tracey
D. M.
2000
.
The effects of commercial exploitation on orange roughy (Hoplostethus atlanticus) from the continental slope of the Chatham Rise, New Zealand, from 1979 to 1997
.
Fisheries Research
,
45
:
217
238
.

Corkett
C. J.
2002
.
Fish stock assessment as a non-falsifiable science: replacing an inductive and instrumental view with a critical rational one
.
Fisheries Research
,
56
:
117
123
.

Cury
P. M.
,
Boyd
I. L.
,
Bonhommeau
S.
,
Anker-Nilssen
T.
,
Crawford
R. J.
,
Furness
R. W.
,
Mills
J. A.
, et al.
2011
.
Global seabird response to forage fish depletion—one-third for the birds
.
Science
,
334
:
1703
1706
.

DAFF
.
2007
. Commonwealth Fisheries Harvest Strategy: Policy and Guidelines. Australian Government, Department of Agriculture, Fisheries and Forestry.
55
pp.

Darwin
C. R.
1859
.
On the Origin of species by Means of Natural Selection, or the Preservation of Favoured Races in the Struggle for Life
.
John Murray
,
London
.
502
pp.

Del Monte‐Luna
P.
,
Brook
B. W.
,
Zetina‐Rejón
M. J.
,
Cruz‐Escalona
V. H.
2004
.
The carrying capacity of ecosystems
.
Global Ecology and Biogeography
,
13
:
485
495
.

Dobzhansky
T.
1973
.
Nothing in biology makes sense except in the light of evolution
.
The American Biology Teacher
,
35
:
125
129
.

Doubleday
Z. A.
,
Prowse
T. A.
,
Arkhipkin
A.
,
Pierce
G. J.
,
Semmens
J.
,
Steer
M.
,
Leporati
S. C.
, et al.
2016
.
Global proliferation of cephalopods
.
Current Biology
,
26
:
R406
R407
.

Finley
C.
2011
.
All the Fish in the Sea: Maximum Sustainable Yield and the Failure of Fisheries Management
.
University of Chicago Press, Chicago
.
224
pp.

Finley
C.
,
Oreskes
N.
2013
.
Maximum sustained yield: a policy disguised as science
.
ICES Journal of Marine Science
,
70
:
245
250
.

Fox
W. W.
1970
.
An exponential yield model for optimizing exploited fish populations
.
Transactions of the American Fisheries Society
,
99
:
80
88
.

Froese
R.
,
Demirel
N.
,
Gianpaolo
C.
,
Kleisner
K. M.
,
Winker
H.
2017
.
Estimating fisheries reference points from catch and resilience
.
Fish and Fisheries
,
18
:
506
526
.

Froese
R.
,
Stern-Pirlot
A.
,
Winker
H.
,
Gascuel
D.
2008
.
Size matters: how single-species management can contribute to ecosystem-based fisheries management
.
Fisheries Research
,
92
:
231
241
.

Froese
R.
,
Walters
C.
,
Pauly
D.
,
Winker
H.
,
Weyl
O. L. F.
,
Demirel
N.
,
Tsikliras
A. C.
, et al.
2016a
.
A critique of the balanced harvesting approach to fishing
.
ICES Journal of Marine Science
,
73
:
1640
1650
.

Froese
R.
,
Winker
H.
,
Coro
G.
,
Demirel
N.
,
Tsikliras
A. C.
,
Dimarchopoulou
D.
,
Scarcella
G.
, et al.
2018
.
A new approach for estimating stock status from length frequency data
.
ICES Journal of Marine Science
,
75
:
2004
2015
.

Froese
R.
,
Winker
H.
,
Gascuel
D.
,
Sumaila
U. R.
,
Pauly
D.
2016b
.
Minimizing the impact of fishing
.
Fish and Fisheries
,
17
:
785
802
.

Garcia
S. M.
,
Kolding
J.
,
Rice
J.
,
Rochet
M. J.
,
Zhou
S.
,
Arimoto
T.
,
Beyer
J. E.
, et al.
2012
.
Reconsidering the consequences of selective fisheries
.
Science
,
335
:
1045
1047
.

Gause
G. F.
1934
.
The Struggle for Existence
.
Williams and Wilkins
,
Baltimore
.
163
pp.

Graham
M.
1935
.
Modern theory of exploiting a fishery and application to North Sea trawling
.
Journal du Conseil Permanent International pour l’Exploration de la Mer
,
10
:
264
274
.

Gulland
J. A.
,
Boerema
L. K.
1973
.
Scientific advice on catch levels
.
Fishery Bulletin
, US,
71
:
325
335
.

Herbert
S.
1971
.
Darwin, Malthus, and selection
.
Journal of the History of Biology
,
4
:
209
217
.

Holt
S. J.
,
Froese
R.
2015
. Comment sent to EU Council, EU Fisheries Committee and European Commission, criticising the ongoing overfishing in EU waters, as exemplified by the recent total allowable catches for the Baltic Sea. https://www.fishbase.de/rfroese/CommentEU-Fishing.docx.

HSP
.
2018
. Commonwealth Fisheries Harvest Strategy Policy. Department of Agriculture and Water Resources, Canberra. CC BY 4.0. 23 pp.

Köster
F. W.
,
Möllmann
C.
2000
.
Trophodynamic control by clupeid predators on recruitment success in Baltic cod?
ICES Journal of Marine Science
,
57
:
310
323
.

Larkin
P. A.
1977
.
An epitaph for the concept of maximum sustainable yield
.
Transactions of the American Fisheries Society
,
106
:
1
11
.

Lotka
A. J.
1925
.
Elements of Physical Biology
.
Williams & Wilkins
,
Baltimore
.
460
pp.

Malthus
T. R.
1798
. An Essay on the Principle of Population, as It Affects the Future Improvement of Society. With Remarks on the Speculations of Mr. Godwin, M. Condorcet and Other Writers, J. Johnson, St. Paul’s Churchyard, London.
126
pp.

MRAG
.
2016
.
Full Assessment: New Zealand Orange Roughy Fisheries
.
Volume 2: Stakeholder Comment
;
Surveillance Levels. Natural Resource Assessment & Management— MRAG Americas Inc.

Muck
P.
1989
.
Major trends in the pelagic ecosystem off Peru and their implications for management
. In
The Peruvian Upwelling Ecosystem: Dynamics and Interactions
,
7
, pp.
386
403
. Ed. by D. Pauly, P. Muck, J. Mendo, and I. Tsukayama. ICLARM Conference Proceedings 18, 438 p.

Nicholson
A. J.
1947
. Fluctuation of animal populations. Australian and New Zealand Association for the Advancement of Science. Section D. Zoology. In Perth Meeting, August, 1947, pp.
134
147
.

Palomares
M. L. D.
,
Froese
R.
,
Derrick
B.
,
Meeuwig
J. J.
,
Noel
S.-L.
,
Tsui
G.
,
Woroniak
J.
, et al.
2020
.
Fishery biomass trends of exploited fish populations in marine ecoregions, climatic zones and ocean basins
.
Estuarine, Coastal and Shelf Science
,
243
:
106896
.

Pauly
D.
1982a
. Studying single-species dynamics in a multi-species context. In ICLARM Conference Proceedings on the Theory and Management of Tropical Fisheries, 9, pp. 33–70. Ed. by D. Pauly and G. I. Murphy.

Pauly
D.
1982b
.
A method to estimate the stock–recruitment relationships of shrimps
.
Transactions of the American Fisheries Society
,
111
:
13
20
.

Pauly
D.
2004
.
Darwin’s Fishes: An Encyclopedia of Ichthyology, Ecology and Evolution
.
Cambridge University Press, Cambridge
.
340
pp.

Pauly
D.
2012
.
Review of ‘All the Fish in the Sea: maximum Sustainable Yield and the Failure of Fisheries Management’, by Carmel Finley
.
The Quarterly Review of Biology
,
87
:
168
168
.

Pauly
D.
2020
.
Retrospective: Sidney Holt (1916–2019)—influential fisheries scientist and savior of whales
.
Science
. 367: 744. doi:10.1126/science.aba8964.

Pauly
D.
,
Chuenpagdee
R.
,
2003
. Development of fisheries in the Gulf of Thailand Large Marine Ecosystem: analysis of an unplanned experiment. In
Large Marine Ecosystems of the World: Trends in Exploitation, Protection, and Research
, pp.
337
354
. Ed. by
Hempel
G.
,
Sherman
K.
,
Elsevier Science
,
Amsterdam
.
438
pp.

Pauly
D.
,
Froese
R.
,
Holt
S. J.
2016
.
Balanced harvesting: the institutional incompatibilities
.
Marine Policy
,
69
:
121
123
.

Pearl
R.
1925
.
The Biology of Population Growth
.
Alfred A. Knopf
,
New York
.
260
pp.

Pedersen
M. W.
,
Berg
C. W.
2017
.
A stochastic surplus production model in continuous time
.
Fish and Fisheries
,
18
:
226
243
.

Pella
J. J.
,
Tomlinson
P. K.
1969
.
A generalized stock production model
.
Inter-American Tropical Tuna Commission Bulletin
,
13
:
419
496
.

Perry
A. L.
,
Low
P. J.
,
Ellis
J. R.
,
Reynolds
J. D.
2005
.
Climate change and distribution shifts in marine fishes
.
Science
,
308
:
1912
1915
.

Pikitch
E.
,
Boersma
P. D.
,
Boyd
I. L.
,
Conover
D. O.
,
Cury
P.
,
Essington
T.
,
Heppell
S. S.
, et al.
2012
. Little Fish, Big Impact: Managing a Crucial Link in Ocean Food Webs. Lenfest Ocean Program, Washington, DC.
108
pp.

Prefontaine
R.
2009
. Shifting baselines in marine fish assessments: implications for perception of management and conservation status. Honours Bachelor thesis,
Dalhousie University
,
Halifax, Canada
.
35
pp.

Punt
A. E.
,
Smith
A. D. M.
,
Smith
D. C.
,
Tuck
G. N.
,
Klaer
N. L.
2014
.
Selecting relative abundance proxies for BMSY and B
MEY.
ICES Journal of Marine Science
,
71
:
469
483
.

Quinn
T. J.
,
Deriso
R. B.
1999
.
Quantitative Fish Dynamics
.
Oxford University Press, Oxford
.
542
pp.

Ricker
W. E.
1975
.
Computation and interpretation of biological statistics of fish populations
.
Bulletin of the Fisheries Research Board of Canada
,
382
:
191
.

Rivard
D.
,
Bledsoe
L. J.
1978
.
Parameter estimation for the Pella-Tomlinson stock production model under nonequilibrium conditions
.
Fishery Bulletin, US
,
76
:
523
534
.

Rosenberg
A. A.
,
Bolster
W. J.
,
Alexander
K. E.
,
Leavenworth
W. B.
,
Cooper
A. B.
,
McKenzie
M. G.
2005
.
The history of ocean resources: modeling cod biomass using historical records
.
Frontiers in Ecology and the Environment
,
3
:
78
84
.

Schaefer
M. B.
1954
.
Some aspects of the dynamics of populations important to the management of the commercial marine fisheries
.
Bulletin of the Inter-American Tropical Tuna Commission
,
1
:
27
56
.

Schaefer
M. B.
1957
.
A study of the dynamics of the fishery for yellowfin tuna in the eastern tropical Pacific Ocean
.
Inter-American Tropical Tuna Commission Bulletin
,
2
:
243
285
.

Steneck
R. S.
,
Hughes
T. P.
,
Cinner
J. E.
,
Adger
W. N.
,
Arnold
S. N.
,
Berkes
F.
,
Boudreau
S. A.
, et al.
2011
.
Creation of a gilded trap by the high economic value of the Maine lobster fishery
.
Conservation Biology
,
25
:
904
912
.

Tsikliras
A.C.
,
Froese
R. 2016.
Encyclopedia of Ecology
, 2nd edition,
1
:
108
115
. Maximum Sustainable Yield,
Fath
B.D.
,
Oxford
:
Elsevier
.

UNFSA
.
1995
. Agreement for the Implementation of the Provisions of the United Nations Convention on the Law of the Sea of 10 December 1982, Relating to the Conservation and Management of Straddling Fish Stocks and Highly Migratory Fish Stocks. 2167 UNTS 88. http://www.un.org/Depts/los/convention_agreements/texts/fish_stocks_agreement/CONF164_37.htm (last accessed July 2020).

Verhulst
P.-F.
1838
.
Notice sur la loi que la population suit dans son accroissement
.
Correspondance Mathématique et Physique
,
10
:
113
121
.

Walters
C.
,
Martell
S. J.
,
Christensen
V.
,
Mahmoudi
B.
2008
.
An Ecosim model for exploring Gulf of Mexico ecosystem management options: implications of including multistanza life-history models for policy predictions
.
Bulletin of Marine Science
,
83
:
251
271
.

Winker
H.
,
Carvalho
F.
,
Kapur
M.
2018
.
JABBA: just another Bayesian biomass assessment
.
Fisheries Research
,
204
:
275
288
.

Worm
B.
,
Myers
R. A.
2003
.
Meta-analysis of cod-shrimp interactions reveals top-down control in oceanic food webs
.
Ecology
,
84
:
162
173
.

This article is published and distributed under the terms of the Oxford University Press, Standard Journals Publication Model (https://academic.oup.com/journals/pages/open_access/funder_policies/chorus/standard_publication_model)
Handling Editor: Emory Anderson
Emory Anderson
Handling Editor
Search for other works by this author on: