Abstract

This paper studies how frictions in the acquisition of new customers distort the allocation of activities across heterogeneous producers. We add bilateral search frictions in a Ricardian model of trade and use French firm-to-firm trade data to estimate search frictions faced by French exporters in foreign markets. Estimated coefficients display a strong degree of heterogeneity across countries and products that correlates with various proxies for information frictions. Markets with high estimated frictions are shown to display less dispersion in sales between high- and low-productivity firms, a consequence of the distortive impact of frictions. A counterfactual reduction in the level of search frictions significantly improves the efficiency of the selection process by pushing the least productive exporters out of the market while increasing export sales at the top of the productivity distribution.

1. Introduction

Customer acquisition, which is central for firms’ economic development, is subject to various forms of frictions, such as search frictions or asymmetric information.1

Despite their prevalence in most product markets, the abundant literature on the sources of misallocation among heterogeneous producers has overlooked such frictions.2 In this paper, we ask whether and how frictions in the acquisition of new customers distort the effectiveness of resource allocation across heterogeneous producers. We do so in the context of international goods markets, in which search frictions are pervasive, interact with other barriers to trade, and for which we have rich data to estimate search frictions.

We develop and estimate a model of firm-to-firm trade displaying frictions that affect the matching of sellers and buyers in international markets. We discuss the consequences of these frictions for the efficiency of selection into exporting, and the size of the firm’s customer base, conditional on trade. By reducing the strength of competition, search frictions penalize the most productive producers and thus distort the allocation of resources. As a consequence, the export premium of high-productivity firms is dampened in frictional product markets. We develop a structural estimator of search frictions that exploits firm-to-firm trade data. Estimates recovered for a large cross-section of products and destination countries are used to quantify the impact of search frictions on the selection of firms into export markets.

The starting point is a Ricardian model of trade à la Eaton and Kortum (2002). Their model constitutes a useful benchmark to study the efficiency of selection into export activities because it displays an extreme form of selection: Ex-post, only the most-productive technology can eventually be exported. We introduce random search in the Ricardian framework. A discrete number of ex-ante homogeneous consumers in each market meet with a random number of heterogeneous producers of a perfectly substitutable good.3 Conditional on her random choice set, the consumer chooses the lowest-cost supplier. As in Eaton and Kortum (2002), iceberg trade costs and technological parameters shape Ricardian advantages. Search frictions, however, interact with Ricardian comparative advantages to determine the geography of international trade: conditional on comparative advantages, higher bilateral frictions dampen bilateral trade.4

Whereas search frictions and iceberg costs have the same qualitative impact on bilateral trade at product-level, search frictions further distort the allocation of resources among exporters of a given origin country. High search frictions reduce the average number of sellers met by any consumer thus dampening the strength of competition. Reduced competitive pressures benefit, in relative terms, low-productivity exporters: High-productivity firms always suffer from a high degree of bilateral frictions, but sufficiently low-productivity firms can instead display higher export propensities toward more frictional markets. The non-monotonicity is in contrast with the properties of purely Ricardian models in which iceberg costs have a monotonous impact along the distribution of firms’ productivity.5

We show how the model can identify search frictions structurally using firm-to-firm trade data. The structural estimator exploits the product-level dispersion in the customer base of exporters from a given origin in a particular destination. In the model, the dispersion comes from search frictions affecting individual firms’ export probabilities. More frictions reduce the dispersion across individual firms by dampening high-productivity firms’ export premium. Because iceberg trade costs do not have such a distortive effect, exploiting this moment of the data is useful to recover search frictions separately from other trade barriers.

The empirical counterpart of this moment is computed using firm-to-firm trade data covering the universe of French exporters and each of their individual clients in the European Union. Search frictions are estimated by a generalized method of moments for about 13,000 product and destination country pairs. The recovered distribution displays substantial dispersion, with most product markets featuring moderated search frictions, whereas a small number of product |$\times$| destination pairs are found to be highly frictional. In the last quartile of the distribution, the probability of meeting zero consumers for a French firm willing to export is above 4% and can reach 50% in the last decile. Search frictions are estimated to be stronger in more downstream and more input-specific product markets. Within a product, they are more pronounced in distant countries but lower in countries where the population of French migrants is larger, where citizens tend to speak a common language or where the degree of social connectedness is stronger. Importantly, the estimated model is able to fit the distribution of the number of consumers that exporters serve within a country and product, including the skewness of the distribution.

What are the distributional consequences of search frictions? We first show that estimated search frictions are on average larger in those product markets in which French firms have a Ricardian comparative advantage. This correlation magnifies the distortive impact of search frictions because it implies French firms have more difficulties matching with foreign buyers in those markets in which they would be in a strong competitive position with respect to foreign competitors, in the absence of search frictions. We then test and confirm the model’s prediction that search frictions dampen the export premium of high-productivity exporters. Our results indicate that the export premium of firms in the top quartile of the distribution of sectoral domestic sales (resp. sectoral labor productivity) increases from 32.2% to 40.0% (resp. 22.3%–30.0%) when moving from the ninth to the first decile of the distribution of estimated search frictions.

Based on these insights, we conclude the analysis with a counterfactual experiment in which we reduce search frictions in all foreign markets, keeping other structural parameters unchanged. With a calibrated reduction in search frictions that corresponds to a shift from the third to the second quartile of the estimated distribution of frictions, we estimate sizeable efficiency gains. On average, the export probability is reduced for firms below the 70th percentile of the productivity distribution, whereas the expected number of partners, conditional on exporting, increases by more than 1 above the 58th percentile and more than 5 in the top 15% of the distribution. Overall, the redistribution of export sales from low- to high-productivity firms increases the interquartile range of exports by 18%. A quantitatively comparable reduction in iceberg costs instead benefits low-productivity firms, in relative terms.6

In comparison with other barriers to international trade, search frictions thus have important misallocative consequences. Reducing such frictions might thus be of especially strong policy relevance. It also comes with a cost for the least efficient firms that are likely to exit the market. Within the toolbox of export-promoting agencies, programs aimed at increasing the visibility of domestic sellers abroad can be an efficient tool for increasing export flows in a non-distortive way, especially if they target small but highly productive firms.

Related Literature.

Our paper is related to different strands of the literature. The role of search and information frictions in international markets is the topic of an old empirical and theoretical literature. Rauch (2001) thus explains the role of migrant networks in international markets by way of such frictions. More recently, a series of papers provide evidence of such frictions being an important barrier to international trade, using various natural experiments of a decrease in information frictions, namely, the launching of a telegraph line between London and New York in Steinwender (2018), the opening of the Japanese high-speed train in Japan in Bernard, Moxnes, and Saito (2018a), the adoption of broadband internet in Norwegian municipalities in Akerman, Leuven, and Mogstad (2022), and the development of online markets in Lendle et al. (2016). In related work, Chen and Wu (2021) study the interplay between reputation and information frictions in the online trade of T-shirts.

Several recent contributions have also studied this topic theoretically. Krolikowski and McCallum (2021) introduce random matching frictions in a Melitz (2003) type framework. In their model, matched producers trade with a single buyer within a country. We instead focus on the role of search frictions in explaining heterogeneity in firms’ customer base. Chaney (2014) and Allen (2014) both develop models in which frictions hit the seller-side of the economy. We instead introduce frictions on the demand side, with consumers having an imperfect knowledge of the supply curve. From this point of view, our model is closer to Dasgupta and Mondria (2018). Their model of inattentive importers assumes buyers optimally choose how much to invest in information processing to discover potential suppliers. In comparison with theirs, our model is based on simpler assumptions about the search technology, which is purely random in our case. Our model is instead richer on the modeling of the supply side, as we allow for multiple heterogeneous producers in each origin country, whereas they have a single firm per exporting country. The tractability of our framework allows us to derive closed-form solutions, estimate frictions structurally, and test how the estimated frictions affect the selection of exporters into foreign markets.7

We also contribute to a series of recent papers that have used firm-to-firm trade data to study the matching between exporters and importers in international markets (Bernard, Moxnes, and Ulltveit-Moe 2018b; Carballo, Ottaviano, and Volpe Martincus 2018; Eaton, Kortum, and Kramarz 2022). The main stylized fact we document, exporters’ heterogeneity in terms of the number of buyers they serve in a given destination, is robust across country datasets.8 In Bernard, Moxnes, and Ulltveit-Moe (2018b) and Carballo, Ottaviano, and Volpe Martincus (2018), the heterogeneity is studied in monopolistic competition models with two-sided heterogeneity. A distinctive feature of our model in comparison with theirs is the distortive effect of frictions that we confirm prevails in the data. The distortion also characterizes the model in Eaton, Kortum, and Kramarz (2022), in which the matching of exporters and importers is also governed by random search in a firm-to-firm framework. Eaton, Kortum, and Kramarz (2022) focus on how country-level frictions affect individual firms’ decisions to oursource some productive tasks, with an end-effect on the labor market. We instead focus on the impact of search frictions on the allocation of activities across exporters within narrowly defined foreign markets. Our empirical strategy allows us to remain flexible regarding the amount of heterogeneity of search frictions across products and destinations. To our knowledge, we are the first to provide systematic evidence of the export premium of high-productivity firms being dampened in frictional markets.9

The introduction of a countable number of firms also relates our work to recent papers that examine trade patterns in models with a finite number of firms (Eaton, Kortum, and Sotelo 2012; Gaubert and Itskhoki 2021). Whereas in these papers, the coexistence of several firms in a given market is due to imperfect substitutability of the varieties produced, we instead consider perfectly substitutable varieties that can co-exist in a market due to the combination of search frictions and the presence of multiple buyers. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, we present the data and stylized facts on firm-to-firm trade, which we later use to build and test the model. We most specifically focus on the number of buyers served by a given firm, our proxy for a firm’s customer base, and study how that number varies across firms, products, and destinations. We notably study its correlation with proxies for search and information frictions. Section 3 describes our theoretical model and derives analytical predictions regarding the expected customer base that an exporter will serve in its typical destination, depending on its productivity and the level of search frictions. Section 4 explains how we estimate the magnitude of search frictions using a GMM approach. We also provide summary statistics on the estimated frictions and the model fit. Section 5 uses the estimated coefficients to discuss how search frictions affect the allocation of resources across exporters. Finally, Section 6 concludes.

2. Data and Stylized Facts

2.1. Data

The empirical analysis is conducted using detailed data covering the universe of French exporting firms. The data are provided by the French Customs and are described in Bergounhon, Lenoir, and Mejean (2018). The dataset covers each single transaction that involves a French exporter and an importing firm located in the European Union, in 2007. Using another reference year, such as 1997 or 2016, does not alter the results. Firms with annual export sales in Europe below 150,000 euros are allowed to fill a simplified form that does not contain information on the product category. The restriction concerns 31% of firms that accumulate less than 1% of aggregate exports.10 For each transaction, the dataset contains the identity of the exporting firm (its SIREN identifier), an identifier for the importer (an anonymized version of its VAT code), the date of the transaction (month and year), the product category (at the eight-digit level of the combined nomenclature), and the value of the shipment. From the firm identifier, we can recover the exporter’s sector of activity using data from the French statistical institute. In the rest of the analysis, data will be aggregated across transactions within a year, at the exporter–importer–hs6 product level. A unit of observation will thus be an exporter–importer–product triplet.

The analysis uses a sample restricted to a subset of each firm’s product portfolio that constitutes the core of the firm’s activity. Core products are defined as those that represent at least 10% of the firm’s export sales plus all products that constitute at least 10% of sales for at least one firm in the same four-digit NAF sector. Information frictions are expected to be less of a problem for non-core products that the firm sells occasionally. The restriction reduces the number of exporter |$\times$| product pairs covered by almost 50% without having much of an impact on the aggregate value of exports (⁠|$-$|8%), on the population of importers (⁠|$-$|4%), and on the population of exporters (which is left unaffected). The restriction thus helps focus the analysis on exporters that actually compete for serving foreign markets with their core products. We have also reproduced the estimation of search frictions on the full dataset with most results being qualitatively unchanged.

In 2007, we have information on 44,280 French firms exporting to 572,553 individual importers located in the 26 countries of the European Union. Total exports by these firms amount to 216 billion euros, which represents 53% of France’s worldwide exports. Online Appendix Table D.1 displays the number of individuals involved in each bilateral trade flow. Most of the time, the number of importers is larger than the number of exporters selling to this destination, that is, French exporters interact with more foreign partners than foreign buyers with French partners. The asymmetry is more pronounced once we focus on product-specific trade flows. The number of active exporter–importer pairs and the number of exporter–importer–product triplets are an order of magnitude smaller than the number of potential relationships, which is equal to the number of active exporters times the number of importers. The density of trade networks is low, on average.

The firm-to-firm dataset is complemented with several product-level and aggregate variables used to run gravity regressions. Distance data are taken from CEPII (Mayer and Zignago 2011). We control for the market’s overall demand using HS6-specific imports in the destination, less the demand for French products. Multilateral import data are from the CEPII-BACI database (Gaulier and Zignago 2010). Finally, we use three alternative proxies for information frictions at country-level: the stock of French migrants in each destination, taken from the UN database on Trends in International Migrant Stock, the probability that individuals in France and the destination speak the same language (constructed by Melitz and Toubal 2014), and a measure of social connectedness between France and the destinations, computed by Bailey et al. (2021) using anonymized Facebook data. The stock of French migrants is measured per thousand inhabitants in the destination. Social connectedness is defined as the probability that two users in France and the destination country have a friendship link.

2.2. Descriptive Statistics

The most important novelty in firm-to-firm trade data is the identification of both sides of international trade flows, not only individual exporters but also their foreign clients in each destination. This information is of particularly high quality in the context of intra-EU trade as the corresponding data are collected for tax purposes and are thus exhaustive. We now present stylized facts exploiting this dimension to characterize the nature of interactions between sellers and buyers engaged in international trade. The facts are later used to motivate the model’s assumptions and back out a number of theoretical predictions. These stylized facts are to a large extent consistent with facts uncovered from other data sources, including customs data (see e.g. Bernard, Moxnes, and Ulltveit-Moe 2018b; Carballo, Ottaviano, and Volpe Martincus 2018), and online trade data for a specific product (Chen and Wu 2021). In comparison with these papers, we also show that the number of buyers in a firm’s portfolio is correlated with proxies for information frictions, conditional on other gravity variables.

Figure 1 shows the strong heterogeneity in the number of buyers per seller within a destination, our proxy for their customer base.11 The left panel documents the share of sellers interacting with a given number of buyers, and the right panel depicts their relative weight in overall exports. To illustrate the amount of heterogeneity across destination countries, Figure 1 displays the distribution obtained in the average European destination (circle points), as well as those computed for two specific destinations, which represent extreme cases around this average, namely, Romania and Germany (triangle and diamond points, respectively).

Distribution of the number of buyers per seller. The figure displays the proportion of sellers (left panel) and the share of trade accounted for by sellers (right panel) that serve $\times$ buyers or fewer in a given destination in 2007. A seller is defined as an exporter–HS6 product pair. The green circles correspond to the average across EU destinations. The blue triangles and red diamonds are respectively obtained from exports to Romania and Germany.
Figure 1.

Distribution of the number of buyers per seller. The figure displays the proportion of sellers (left panel) and the share of trade accounted for by sellers (right panel) that serve |$\times$| buyers or fewer in a given destination in 2007. A seller is defined as an exporter–HS6 product pair. The green circles correspond to the average across EU destinations. The blue triangles and red diamonds are respectively obtained from exports to Romania and Germany.

In France’s typical export market, 60% of firms interact with a single buyer, and 88% with at most five buyers. On the other side of the spectrum, 1% of firms interact with more than 100 buyers in the same destination. As the right panel in Figure 1 shows, firms interacting with a single buyer in their typical destination account for about a third of French exports and are thus smaller than the average firm in the distribution. Still, 80% of trade is made up of firms interacting with at most 10 buyers. Based on such evidence, we conclude that French exports are dominated by sellers interacting with a small number of buyers.

Our structural estimation of search frictions exploits the heterogeneity across sellers, within a product, and destination. At this level, heterogeneity in terms of the number of buyers is significantly correlated with the seller’s size (Bernard, Moxnes, and Ulltveit-Moe 2018b; Carballo, Ottaviano, and Volpe Martincus 2018). In our data, the coefficient of correlation between the log of the firm’s worldwide exports and the log of the number of partners served in a particular destination is equal to 0.28. Alone, the firm’s size explains 37% of the within-variance.

Whereas there is strong heterogeneity in the number of partners served by French exporters, the other side of the graph displays by far less heterogeneity. As shown in Figure A.1 (green circles), 90% of foreign buyers identified in our data purchase a given product from a single French exporter, and virtually all importers have less than five partners in France.12

We close this section with an empirical analysis using the gravity framework to show how the buyer margin correlates with the geography of French exports. Table 1 summarizes the results. The gravity equation is run at the product level (columns (1)–(4)) and within a firm (columns (5)–(7)). Our dataset covers French exports to 26 EU countries. As a consequence, standard gravity variables such as distance, the border effect, and the common language dummy end up strongly correlated. This explains that our specification has less control variables than a typical gravity regression based on multilateral data. Namely, bilateral trade is explained by distance to France, two proxies for market size, the country’s (product-specific) import demand and GDP per capita, and a proxy for search and information frictions, namely, the likelihood that citizens in France and the destination speak the same language taken from Melitz and Toubal (2014). Table A.1 reproduces the same regressions using two alternative proxies for information frictions.

Table 1.

Product- and firm-level gravity equations.

Dependent variable (all in log)
Product-levelFirm-level
Value of## buyersMean exportValue of# buyersExports
exportssellersper sellerper buyer–sellerexportsper buyer
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)(7)
log distance−0.972***−0.413***−0.262***−0.298***−0.284***−0.183***−0.101**
(0.0734)(0.0345)(0.0263)(0.0466)(0.0606)(0.0283)(0.0502)
log import demand0.845***0.269***0.154***0.422***0.459***0.203***0.256***
(0.0147)(0.00687)(0.00514)(0.00909)(0.0110)(0.00794)(0.00930)
log GDP per capita0.119***0.0932***0.0615***−0.0357−0.0190−0.0313**0.0123
(0.0326)(0.0153)(0.0105)(0.0234)(0.0262)(0.0159)(0.0177)
Proba common language1.084***1.492***0.389***−0.796***1.056***0.752***0.304**
(0.315)(0.146)(0.107)(0.173)(0.176)(0.0920)(0.125)
Observations63,09663,09663,09663,096621,816621,816621,816
R-squared0.6330.7740.4120.5840.6850.4280.717
Fixed effectsProductProductProductProductFirmFirmFirm
Dependent variable (all in log)
Product-levelFirm-level
Value of## buyersMean exportValue of# buyersExports
exportssellersper sellerper buyer–sellerexportsper buyer
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)(7)
log distance−0.972***−0.413***−0.262***−0.298***−0.284***−0.183***−0.101**
(0.0734)(0.0345)(0.0263)(0.0466)(0.0606)(0.0283)(0.0502)
log import demand0.845***0.269***0.154***0.422***0.459***0.203***0.256***
(0.0147)(0.00687)(0.00514)(0.00909)(0.0110)(0.00794)(0.00930)
log GDP per capita0.119***0.0932***0.0615***−0.0357−0.0190−0.0313**0.0123
(0.0326)(0.0153)(0.0105)(0.0234)(0.0262)(0.0159)(0.0177)
Proba common language1.084***1.492***0.389***−0.796***1.056***0.752***0.304**
(0.315)(0.146)(0.107)(0.173)(0.176)(0.0920)(0.125)
Observations63,09663,09663,09663,096621,816621,816621,816
R-squared0.6330.7740.4120.5840.6850.4280.717
Fixed effectsProductProductProductProductFirmFirmFirm
Notes: Standard errors, clustered in the country |$\times$| HS2 chapter dimension, are in parentheses, with |$^{***}$| and |$^{**}$|⁠, respectively, denoting significance at the 1% and 5% levels. “log Distance” is the log of the weighted distance between France and the destination. “log Import demand” is the log of the value of the destination’s demand of imports for the hs6–product, less the demand addressed to France. “log GDP per capita” is the log-GDP per capita in the destination. “Proba Common Language” is the probability that a French citizen and a citizen from the destination country speak the same language, as computed by Melitz and Toubal (2014). The dependent variable is either the log of product-level French exports in the destination (column (1)) or one of its components, namely, the number of sellers involved in the trade flow (column (2)), the mean number of buyers they serve (column (3)), and the mean value of a seller–buyer transaction (column (4)):

where |$x_{pd}$| denotes the value of French exports of product p in destination d, which is the sum of all firm-to-firm transactions |$x_{sbpd}$|⁠. |$S_{pd}$| is the set of the sellers serving this market and |$B_{spd}$| is the set of the importers purchasing product p from seller s. |$\#^S_{pd}$|⁠, |$\#^B_{spd}$|⁠, and |$\#^{SB}_{pd}$| denote the number of sellers, the number of buyers seller s is connected to, and the total number of active seller–buyer pairs in market |$pd$|⁠, respectively.

Column (5) uses the log of firm-level bilateral exports as left-hand-side variable, whereas columns (6) and (7) use one of its components, the number of buyers served (column (6)) or the value of exports per buyer (column (7)): Likewise, the decomposition of firm-level exports in columns (5)–(7) of Table 1 is based on the following decomposition of trade into an extensive and an intensive terms:
Table 1.

Product- and firm-level gravity equations.

Dependent variable (all in log)
Product-levelFirm-level
Value of## buyersMean exportValue of# buyersExports
exportssellersper sellerper buyer–sellerexportsper buyer
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)(7)
log distance−0.972***−0.413***−0.262***−0.298***−0.284***−0.183***−0.101**
(0.0734)(0.0345)(0.0263)(0.0466)(0.0606)(0.0283)(0.0502)
log import demand0.845***0.269***0.154***0.422***0.459***0.203***0.256***
(0.0147)(0.00687)(0.00514)(0.00909)(0.0110)(0.00794)(0.00930)
log GDP per capita0.119***0.0932***0.0615***−0.0357−0.0190−0.0313**0.0123
(0.0326)(0.0153)(0.0105)(0.0234)(0.0262)(0.0159)(0.0177)
Proba common language1.084***1.492***0.389***−0.796***1.056***0.752***0.304**
(0.315)(0.146)(0.107)(0.173)(0.176)(0.0920)(0.125)
Observations63,09663,09663,09663,096621,816621,816621,816
R-squared0.6330.7740.4120.5840.6850.4280.717
Fixed effectsProductProductProductProductFirmFirmFirm
Dependent variable (all in log)
Product-levelFirm-level
Value of## buyersMean exportValue of# buyersExports
exportssellersper sellerper buyer–sellerexportsper buyer
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)(7)
log distance−0.972***−0.413***−0.262***−0.298***−0.284***−0.183***−0.101**
(0.0734)(0.0345)(0.0263)(0.0466)(0.0606)(0.0283)(0.0502)
log import demand0.845***0.269***0.154***0.422***0.459***0.203***0.256***
(0.0147)(0.00687)(0.00514)(0.00909)(0.0110)(0.00794)(0.00930)
log GDP per capita0.119***0.0932***0.0615***−0.0357−0.0190−0.0313**0.0123
(0.0326)(0.0153)(0.0105)(0.0234)(0.0262)(0.0159)(0.0177)
Proba common language1.084***1.492***0.389***−0.796***1.056***0.752***0.304**
(0.315)(0.146)(0.107)(0.173)(0.176)(0.0920)(0.125)
Observations63,09663,09663,09663,096621,816621,816621,816
R-squared0.6330.7740.4120.5840.6850.4280.717
Fixed effectsProductProductProductProductFirmFirmFirm
Notes: Standard errors, clustered in the country |$\times$| HS2 chapter dimension, are in parentheses, with |$^{***}$| and |$^{**}$|⁠, respectively, denoting significance at the 1% and 5% levels. “log Distance” is the log of the weighted distance between France and the destination. “log Import demand” is the log of the value of the destination’s demand of imports for the hs6–product, less the demand addressed to France. “log GDP per capita” is the log-GDP per capita in the destination. “Proba Common Language” is the probability that a French citizen and a citizen from the destination country speak the same language, as computed by Melitz and Toubal (2014). The dependent variable is either the log of product-level French exports in the destination (column (1)) or one of its components, namely, the number of sellers involved in the trade flow (column (2)), the mean number of buyers they serve (column (3)), and the mean value of a seller–buyer transaction (column (4)):

where |$x_{pd}$| denotes the value of French exports of product p in destination d, which is the sum of all firm-to-firm transactions |$x_{sbpd}$|⁠. |$S_{pd}$| is the set of the sellers serving this market and |$B_{spd}$| is the set of the importers purchasing product p from seller s. |$\#^S_{pd}$|⁠, |$\#^B_{spd}$|⁠, and |$\#^{SB}_{pd}$| denote the number of sellers, the number of buyers seller s is connected to, and the total number of active seller–buyer pairs in market |$pd$|⁠, respectively.

Column (5) uses the log of firm-level bilateral exports as left-hand-side variable, whereas columns (6) and (7) use one of its components, the number of buyers served (column (6)) or the value of exports per buyer (column (7)): Likewise, the decomposition of firm-level exports in columns (5)–(7) of Table 1 is based on the following decomposition of trade into an extensive and an intensive terms:

Column (1) confirms the results found in the rest of the literature, namely, that product-level bilateral trade is larger toward closer, bigger, and wealthier destination markets. Trade is also positively correlated with the language proximity of the origin and destination countries, our baseline proxy for frictions. The effect is robust to the choice of a proxy for information frictions, as shown in Table A.1. Information frictions also have a significant impact on exports in our sample within a firm as confirmed in column (5).

In columns (2)–(4) and (6)–(7), bilateral trade flows are further decomposed into intensive and extensive components. Importantly, the buyer dimension of the data allows us to examine the buyer’s extensive margin, as measured by the number of buyers in each exporter’s portfolio of clients (see also Bernard, Moxnes, and Ulltveit-Moe (2018b) for a similar decomposition based on Norwegian data). All margins of bilateral trade significantly contribute to the sensitivity of trade to gravity variables. In particular, the “buyer” extensive margin is responsible for 27% of the overall distance elasticity at the product level, a number that jumps to 64% once gravity coefficients are identified within a firm.13 Likewise, the buyer margin accounts for a substantial share of the overall impact of information frictions: Around one-third when the gravity equation is estimated at the product-level and between 54% and 73% at firm-level, depending on the chosen proxy for information frictions, that is, the language proximity in Table 1, the stock of French migrants in the destination, or the degree of social connectedness in Table A.1. Our interpretation of this finding is that a high probability of speaking the same language, a large stock of French migrants in the destination, or a high degree of social connectedness help alleviate information frictions in international markets, which in turn facilitates the matching between exporters and importers.

This analysis thus confirms previous results in the literature regarding the heterogeneity across exporting firms, in terms of the number of buyers they serve in a destination. This number is systematically correlated with the size of the exporter. It also varies within a firm across destinations, with, on average, fewer buyers served in distant destinations or in destinations displaying more information frictions. In the next section, we build a model that is consistent with these features of the data.

3. Model

This section presents a Ricardian model of firm-to-firm trade with search frictions. The analysis is conducted at the level of a product, given factor prices. To alleviate notations, we neglect the product dimension until necessary, although all parameters can be understood as being potentially product-specific. After having summarized the main assumptions, we derive a number of analytical predictions that we later use in the structural estimation. We then discuss possible extensions of the model and alternative theoretical frameworks. All analytical details are postponed to Online Appendix B.

3.1. Assumptions

The economy is composed of N countries indexed by |$i=1,\!...,N$|⁠. The partial equilibrium analysis focuses on a single good produced into perfectly substitutable varieties. As in Eaton, Kortum, and Sotelo (2012), a discrete number of producers of the good are located in each country j. These firms produce with a constant-returns-to-scale technology using an input bundle whose unit price |$w_j$| is taken as exogenous. The productivity of a firm |$s_j$| located in country j is independently drawn from a Pareto distribution of parameter |$\theta$| and support |$[\underline{z},+\infty [$|⁠. The number of firms with productivity higher than z is the realization of a Poisson variable with parameter |$T_j z^{-\theta }$|⁠. In the rest of the analysis, firms will be designated by their productivity, with |$z_{s_j}$| being the realized productivity of firm |$s_j$|⁠. The exporter–hs6 product pairs studied in Section 2 are the empirical counterpart of these firms.

The model has bilateral iceberg trade costs but no fixed cost. To serve market i with one unit of the good, firms from country j need to produce |$d_{ij}>1$| units. The cost of serving market i for a firm |$s_j$| is thus equal to |${w_jd_{ij}}/{z_{s_j}}$|⁠. Given input prices and international trade costs, the number of firms from j that can serve market i at a cost below p is a Poisson random variable of parameter |$\mu _{ij}(p)=T_j(d_{ij}w_j/p)^{-\theta }$|⁠. Summing over all producing countries, the number of firms from any country in the world that can serve country i at a cost below p is distributed Poisson of parameter |$\mu _i(p)=p^{\theta } \sum _{j=1}^{N} T_j(d_{ij}w_j)^{-\theta }=p^{\theta }\Upsilon _i$|⁠. As in Eaton and Kortum (2002), |$\Upsilon _i=\sum _{j=1}^{N} T_j(d_{ij}w_j)^{-\theta }$| reflects “multilateral resistance” in country i: the higher |$\Upsilon _i$| is, the more competitors with low costs can serve the country.

We depart from the representative consumer’s assumption used in most of the literature and instead assume each country is populated by a finite number |$B_i$| of (ex-ante) homogeneous buyers, each one characterized by its own iso-elastic demand function
where |$c_{b_i}$| is the quantity of the good purchased by buyer |$b_i$| given the price |$p_{b_i}$| she is offered, and a demand shifter |$\bar{X}_i$| that we assume is shared across all buyers within a market. Because of search frictions, each buyer |$b_i$| meets with a random subset of the potential suppliers of the good, with each supplier from country j having a probability |$\lambda _{ij}$| of being drawn. Conditional on the subset of producers met, the buyer decides which one to purchase from, by comparing the prices they offer.
To simplify the analysis, we will assume that producers price at their marginal cost. As a consequence, buyer |$b_i$| chooses to purchase the good from the lowest-cost supplier, who she meets and pays the price
where |$\Omega _{b_i}$| is the set of producers drawn by buyer |$b_i$|⁠. The number of potential suppliers in the set |$\Omega _{b_i}$| reflects the extent of search frictions in the economy. In a frictionless world, for |$\lambda _{ij}=1\,\,\forall \,\,(i,j)$|⁠, each buyer |$b_i$| would meet with all suppliers. Within a destination, all buyers would thus end up paying the same price for the homogeneous good and the model would collapse into a representative buyer’s Ricardian setup à la Eaton and Kortum (2002). The frictionless equilibrium has a distribution of firms that is degenerate ex-post with only the most efficient technology being eventually active. Our model does not display such a degenerate ex-post distribution. Each buyer |$b_i$| meets with a random number of potential suppliers, drawn from a Poisson distribution of parameter |$\sum _j \lambda _{ij}T_j \underline{z}^{-\theta }$|⁠. Likewise, the number of suppliers from j (resp. from any country) offering a price below p can be represented by a Poisson process of parameter |$\lambda _{ij}\mu _{ij}(p)$| (resp. |$\sum _j \lambda _{ij} \mu _{ij}(p)$|⁠). Under this assumption, any supplier from j has a strictly positive probability of ending up serving market i. In the rest of the analysis, |$\lambda _{ij}$| is interpreted as an inverse measure of bilateral frictions. A coefficient closer to 1 implies buyers from i gather more information on potential suppliers in country j and are thus more likely to identify the most competitive one.
Given the property of the Poisson distribution, the minimum price at which a buyer |$b_i$| can purchase the good can be shown to follow a Weibull distribution
where |$\kappa _i\equiv ( \sum _{j}\lambda _{ij}T_j (w_j d_{ij})^{-\theta })/(\sum _j T_j (w_j d_{ij})^{-\theta })$| measures the expected number of suppliers met, in relative terms with respect to the maximum number of suppliers that would compete under no search frictions. |$\kappa _i$| can also be interpreted as a weighted average of bilateral search frictions, with the weights representative of the relative comparative advantage of the different origin countries in market i: |$\kappa _i=\sum _j \omega _{ij} \lambda _{ij}$| with |$\omega _{ij}\equiv (T_j (w_j d_{ij})^{-\theta })/(\sum _j T_j (w_j d_{ij})^{-\theta })$|⁠.

The ex-post distribution of prices in this economy depends on the strength of competition there, as measured by |$\Upsilon _i$|⁠, and the amount of heterogeneity in firms’ prices, which is inversely proportional to |$\theta$|⁠. In comparison with the frictionless equilibrium, expected prices are systematically inflated by search frictions (since |$\kappa _i<1$|⁠). The presence of search frictions indeed implies that buyers fail to identify the lowest-cost supplier in the whole distribution of potential producers. This lack of information is distortive, thus inflating the average price paid by consumers in country i. The size of this distortion is inversely related to the expected number of suppliers met, |$\kappa _i$|⁠. It is larger when |$\lambda _{ij}$| and |$T_j (w_j d_{ij})^{-\theta }$| are negatively correlated, that is, when search frictions are high in markets where the country has a Ricardian comparative advantage. Intuitively, being unable to meet with all potential suppliers is all the more costly for consumers when search frictions increase the relative probability that they meet with poorly competitive firms. In the rest of the analysis, we thus refer to |$\kappa _i$| as an inverse measure of the distortive impact of frictions.

3.2. Analytical Predictions

In this section, we first derive predictions regarding the magnitude of bilateral trade flows between any two countries. Such predictions help understand how search frictions modify the predictions of Ricardian models à la Eaton and Kortum (2002). We then derive predictions regarding export probabilities along the distribution of firms’ productivities, which we later use to identify search frictions in the data.

3.2.1. Product-Level Trade

Our model inherits the property of the Eaton and Kortum (2002) model that explains the geography of trade by the probability for a given unit of consumption to be sourced in a particular origin country. Namely, the ex-post share of country j’s (product-level) consumption that is imported from country i, denoted |$\pi _{ij}$|⁠, can be shown to be exactly equal to the ex-ante expected probability that any buyer |$b_i$| ends up interacting with a supplier from j:
where |${\mathbb {1}}_{b_ij}^{(1)}$| is a dummy variable equal to 1 if the lowest-cost supplier met by |$b_i$| originates from country j and |$\mathbb {E}(\cdot)$| is the expectation operator. Properties of the Poisson distribution imply the probability of the lowest-cost supplier being located in j is constant and independent of |$b_i$|⁠. Trade shares thus simplify into
(1)
The share of country i’s absorption of the product that is sourced from country j thus depends on (i) the relative competitiveness of its firms in comparison with the rest of the world, |$T_j(d_{ij}w_j)^{-\theta }/\Upsilon _i$|⁠, and (ii) the relative size of search frictions its firms encounter while serving market i, |$\lambda _{ij}/\kappa _i$|⁠. The first ratio is the formula derived in Eaton and Kortum (2002). It shows how the combined impact of technology and geography determines international trade flows in a Ricardian world. The key insight from our model is that search frictions can distort trade flows, in comparison with this benchmark. The impact of search frictions is captured by the second term in equation (1). Taking the derivative of equation (1) with respect to |$\lambda _{ij}$| implies
that is, the market share of a country always increases following a reduction in bilateral frictions.
Finally, note the model is compatible with structural gravity. Namely, log-linearizing equation (1) implies
(2)
where |$FE_i\equiv \ln \Upsilon _i \kappa _i$| and |$FE_j\equiv \ln T_j (w_j)^{-\theta }$|⁠. The cross-sectional variation in bilateral trade flows can be explained by a full set of origin- and destination-country fixed effects and a number of bilateral variables correlated with the magnitude of trade frictions. In comparison with standard gravity-compatible models, the difference is that our model predicts physical trade barriers |$d_{ij}$| as well as information frictions |$\lambda _{ij}$| to enter the gravity equation.14A corollary is that predictions on product-level trade cannot be expected to help identify search frictions, separately from other barriers to trade because both sources of frictions have the same qualitative impact on trade.

3.2.2. Firm-to-Firm Matching

We now study the matching process between any two firms. Such predictions are novel to our model and can be used together with firm-to-firm trade data to estimate search frictions. Because we observe the universe of French exporters and their customers abroad, we take the point of view of individual sellers and derive predictions regarding the expected number of customers they can reach, in each destination.

Consider the probability that a given supplier from j, France in our data, serves a buyer in i. Given buyers are ex-ante homogeneous, multiplying the probability by |$B_i$| directly delivers the expected number of buyers served by an exporter, which we measure in the data. In our framework, this probability is the product of the probability that |$s_j$| meets with |$b_i$| times the probability that it is the lowest-cost supplier, within |$b_i$|’s random set
(3)
By assumption, the probability of being drawn by a buyer is constant and only depends on the size of bilateral search frictions. More productive sellers, however, have a higher probability of ending up serving any buyer from i because, conditional on being drawn, they have a higher chance of being the lowest-cost supplier. And conditional on productivity, a seller has a higher chance of serving a buyer located in a market that can be served at a low average cost |$w_jd_{ij}$|⁠, where competition is limited (⁠|$\Upsilon _i$| low), and that displays highly distortive average search frictions (⁠|$\kappa _i$| small). These predictions are consistent with the evidence presented in Section 2.2.

The probability in equation (3) is log-supermodular in bilateral search frictions and firms’ productivity. Search frictions do not equally affect firms at different points of the productivity distribution. This property of the model is illustrated in Figure 2, which shows the probability of a match |$\rho _{ij}(z_{s_j})$| as a function of the firm’s productivity for four alternative values of the bilateral meeting probability. Consistent with empirical evidence, the probability of serving a foreign buyer is increasing in the firm’s productivity. However, the slope of the relationship is reduced when search frictions increase (for a lower value of |$\lambda$|⁠). Under some parameter restrictions, one can further show that reducing search frictions improves export prospects for high-productivity firms while reducing low-productive firms’ export probability. These results are summarized in Proposition 1 (see the proof in Online Appendix B).

Probability of serving a buyer as a function of the seller’s productivity. This figure illustrates how the probability of serving a buyer varies with the seller’s productivity, for four different values of bilateral frictions.
Figure 2.

Probability of serving a buyer as a function of the seller’s productivity. This figure illustrates how the probability of serving a buyer varies with the seller’s productivity, for four different values of bilateral frictions.

 
Proposition 1.
The impact of search frictions varies along the distribution of productivities, with high-productivity firms benefiting more, in terms of export performances, from a reduction in search frictions
(4)
and
High-productivity firms always benefit from a reduction in frictions (an increase in the meeting probability |$\lambda _{ij}$|⁠)
For low-enough search frictions, an increase in |$\lambda _{ij}$| instead has a negative impact on firms at the bottom of the distribution; that is,
(5)
where |$\rho _{ij}(\underline{z})$| is the export probability in i of a firm from j with productivity |$\underline{z}$|⁠.

The ambiguous impact of more bilateral search frictions (a lower meeting probability |$\lambda _{ij}$|⁠) on the probability of serving a particular buyer conditional on the level of productivity can be explained by the opposite impact of the visibility and competition channels. On the one hand, a decrease in search frictions increases the likelihood that seller |$s_j$| will serve any buyer in country i as it enhances its probability of meeting with the buyer (“visibility” channel). On the other hand, conditional on being drawn, less bilateral search friction means |$s_j$| faces fiercer competition from other domestic suppliers. As a consequence, the probability that it is the lowest-cost supplier met by any particular buyer is reduced, especially if the seller’s productivity is low. For high-productivity sellers, the visibility channel dominates and they always benefit from a reduction in search frictions. For low-productivity sellers instead, the competition channel is stronger, which explains that their privately optimal value of the meeting probability, defined as the level of |$\lambda _{ij}$|⁠, which maximizes their export probability, is low. If frictions are not too strong so that the expected number of sellers from j that buyers from i meet is above 1 (⁠|$\lambda _{ij}\underline {z}^{-\theta }T_j>1$|⁠), the competition channel dominates the visibility channel at the bottom of the productivity distribution, and sufficiently low-productivity sellers benefit from more frictions.15

A direct consequence of the heterogeneous impact of frictions along the productivity distribution is that the export premium of high-productivity firms is affected by the level of frictions
(6)
where |$\rho _{ij}(z^H)$| and |$\rho _{ij}(z^L)$| denote export probabilities in country i of a firm from j with a high-productivity |$z^H$| and a low-productivity |$z^L$|⁠, respectively. Equation (6) is positive, which reflects the fact that, everything else being equal, high-productivity firms are more likely to serve any buyer in country i. However, it is increasing in |$\kappa _i$| and |$\lambda _{ij}$|⁠, which is consistent with the idea that more distortive search frictions reduce the competitive advantage of high-productivity firms. In markets displaying high and distortive search frictions, buyers meet with a small number of relatively low competitive firms, on average. As a consequence, the strength of competition is reduced and the export premium of high-productivity firms is smaller. We provide evidence of this distortive impact of frictions in Section 5.
Whereas reducing search frictions can improve the allocative efficiency, iceberg costs do not have the same distortive impact. The export premium of high-productivity firms is exacerbated in countries featuring high iceberg trade costs; that is,
The reason is that an increase in iceberg costs deteriorates the relative competitiveness of all French firms—but the competitiveness loss is stronger for low-productivity ones. Low-productivity firms thus become less likely to serve the buyer, conditional on a match. Whereas search frictions and iceberg costs have the same qualitative impact on product-level trade, their impact on individual firms’ export probabilities is instead different. This discrepancy explains that the heterogeneity in export performances across firms is useful to identify search frictions separately from iceberg costs.

3.3. Discussion

In this subsection, we discuss the robustness of our results to various assumptions. We also compare our model with alternative frameworks used in the literature to describe the matching of sellers and buyers in international markets. The discussion relies on the qualitative properties of these alternative models and assumptions. Analytical details are relegated to Online Appendix B.

Possible Extensions.

In Section 3.1, we have assumed marginal cost pricing within each buyer’s random choice set. As shown in Online Appendix B.4, the model’s main properties are robust to assuming that firms Bertrand compete. The reason is that the distribution of markups recovered under Bertrand competition is invariant to the nationality of either the supplier or the buyer, exactly as in the Bernard et al. (2003) extension of the Eaton and Kortum (2002) model. As a consequence, the geography of trade discussed in Section 3.2.1 is the same as in the baseline model and so is the expression for export probabilities derived in Section 3.2.2.

A more crucial assumption is that the probability of meeting with a seller is invariant along the productivity distribution. Arguably, high-productivity firms may benefit from more visibility, and we shall expect the lack of visibility to matter mostly for relatively small firms.16 We show in Online Appendix B.5 that the distortive effect of search frictions does not necessarily disappear if we relax the assumption that meeting probabilities are constant along the productivity distribution and instead allow high-productivity firms to benefit from more visibility. As in the baseline case, an upward shift in the distribution of meeting probabilities increases the likelihood that any firm meets with a buyer while, in the meantime, strengthening competition, conditional on a match. In comparison with the baseline case, the competition effect should in general be stronger because the additional sellers met in the less frictional equilibrium are more productive, on average. However, the visibility channel now varies along the distribution of productivities. Whereas the outcome of the model obviously depends on the exact functional form linking meeting probabilities and sellers’ productivity, we show that under a reasonable parametric assumption, the model still displays the log-supermodularity of |$\rho _{ij}(z_{s_j}\!)$| in |$\lambda _{ij}$| and |$z_{s_j}$|⁠. Whereas increasing meeting probabilities rise the relative probability of high-productivity firms serving any particular foreign buyer, a reduction in the mean level of search frictions still improves the relative export performances of high-productivity firms, a consequence of the distortive impact of frictions.

General Equilibrium.

As discussed in Online Appendix B.3, the model could be incorporated into a general equilibrium framework. Such extension can be achieved by assuming that there is a continuum of products as in Atkeson and Burstein (2008) and Gaubert and Itskhoki (2021). Equilibrium factor prices are then pinned down by good market equilibrium conditions. For similar reasons as in Eaton, Kortum, and Kramarz (2022), such extension can bring the model closer to the class of models described in Arkolakis, Costinot, and Rodrìguez-Clare (2012), with the additional complication implied by the rich product heterogeneity assumed in our model.17 Whereas numerically solving this model is beyond the scope of this paper, the general equilibrium effect of a change in frictions is unlikely to affect the predictions described earlier, at least qualitatively. Unlike search frictions, wage adjustments indeed affect all firms symmetrically.

Comparison with Alternative Models.

Besides the model’s robustness to alternative assumptions, another natural question is the extent to which the theoretical predictions later used to identify search frictions could be rationalized in a completely different model of the matching between sellers and buyers. In the Online Appendix, we discuss three alternative frameworks. In Online Appendix B.6, we first discuss the properties of a discrete choice model in which buyers display heterogeneous preferences for horizontally differentiated varieties offered by sellers originating from various countries. As notably discussed in Head and Mayer (2014), such model can deliver a gravity structure, exactly as a Ricardian framework does. We set up such model and show that the product-level prediction for the geography of trade is similar to this and our baseline model, if one interprets |$\lambda _{ij}$| as a dyadic preference parameter shaping the (Pareto) distribution of consumers’ valuation for varieties produced in a particular country. Such model has nothing to say about the heterogeneity across sellers in their ability to serve a particular market, however. As this heterogeneity is at the core of our identification strategy, we can rule out that consumers’ heterogeneous preferences, alone, shape the empirical moment used to identify search frictions.18

In Online Appendix B.7, we then describe a partial equilibrium version of a model that introduces market penetration costs à la Arkolakis (2010) in the discrete version of the Melitz model proposed by Eaton, Kortum, and Sotelo (2012). We then study how variations in both variable and fixed trade costs affect the number of buyers served by each exporter in such framework. In Online Appendix B.8, we develop a model of two-sided heterogeneity à la Bernard, Moxnes, and Ulltveit-Moe (2018b). The supply side of the model is again taken from Eaton, Kortum, and Sotelo (2012), but buyers are assumed heterogeneous in terms of the level of their demand. Sellers choose the number and identity of buyers they want to serve, which generates negative assortative matching between buyers and sellers. Both models can rationalize the stylized facts in Section 2.2, most notably the increasing relationship between a firm’s number of buyers and its productivity. None of these models, however, displays the distortive trade friction that is central in our analysis. In these models, reducing trade friction increases the probability of export everywhere along the productivity distribution. This is in contrast with what we have in our model, in which reducing search frictions has a non-monotonic impact on low- and high-productive firms. We provide evidence of such non-monotonicity in Section 5, which we argue is difficult to explain in alternative contexts.

4. Estimation

In this section, we describe the GMM estimator used to estimate search frictions. Details on the choice of the empirical moment and the implementation are postponed to Online Appendix C. We then discuss the results. To simplify notations and since the empirical analysis solely uses data on French exporters, the index for the country of origin (j in Section 3) is now neglected and individual firms are just identified by their productivity z. On the other hand, we will introduce the product dimension k that was neglected until now. |$\lambda _i^k$| will thus denote the level of frictions faced by French producers of product k, in market i. In the data, destination countries are all located in the European Union.

4.1. Details on the Estimation Strategy

Results in Section 3.2.2 provide insights into the expected number of buyers in each destination. The randomness of the matching process, however, generates dispersion around this mean. To confront the model with the data, we thus derive the probability that a given French exporter has exactly M buyers in country i, conditional on its productivity. Given the independence of draws, one can show that it follows a binomial law of parameters |$B_i^k$| and |$\rho _{i}^k(z)$|⁠:
Integrating over the expected distribution of productivities gives the expected number of French exporters with exactly |$M>0$| buyers in i:19
(7)
where |$I_{a}(b,c)=B(a;b,c)/B(b,c)$| denotes the regularized incomplete beta function. In the context of our model, equation (7) represents the theoretical counterpart of the distribution of sellers’ number of buyers represented in Figure 1 (left panel). The expected number of firms serving a given number of clients is decreasing in M, which is consistent with evidence in Section 2.2. This property comes from the independence of matches: The probability that a given seller is drawn by a large number of buyers shrinks rapidly when the number of buyers increases. The shape of |$h_{i}^k(M)$| is also a function of |$\lambda _{i}^k$|⁠. Conditional on |$\pi _{i}^k$| and |$B_i^k$|⁠, one can use the predicted value for |$h_{i}^k(M)$| and its counterpart in the data to recover a structural estimate for |$\lambda _{i}^k$|⁠, for each product and destination.
Our empirical analysis relies on the following transformation of equation (7) into a convergent moment:20
(8)

This moment is related to the curvature of the distribution of sellers’ number of partners represented in Figure 1 (left panel), while being uncorrelated with the intercept, which is more tightly linked to the number of suppliers in France and buyers in the destination market. As illustrated in the simulations reported in Figure 3, this moment is correlated positively with |$\lambda _{i}^k$| and is thus useful for identification. Intuitively, when frictions get very high, the probability of a seller reaching more than 1 buyer approaches 0, resulting in a variance that approaches 0.

Correlation between the variance of the $h(M)/h(1)$ ratios and the value of the meeting probability. This figure shows the theoretical relationship between the underlying meeting probability ($\lambda$, x-axis) and the variance of the $h(M)/h(1)$ ratios, that is, the theoretical moment used to identify search frictions. The relationship is derived conditional on the underlying number of buyers (B) and using three ratios, namely, ${h(2)}/{h(1)}$, ${(h(3)+h(4))}/{h(1)}$, and ${(\sum _{m=5}^B h(m))}/{h(1)}$.
Figure 3.

Correlation between the variance of the |$h(M)/h(1)$| ratios and the value of the meeting probability. This figure shows the theoretical relationship between the underlying meeting probability (⁠|$\lambda$|⁠, x-axis) and the variance of the |$h(M)/h(1)$| ratios, that is, the theoretical moment used to identify search frictions. The relationship is derived conditional on the underlying number of buyers (B) and using three ratios, namely, |${h(2)}/{h(1)}$|⁠, |${(h(3)+h(4))}/{h(1)}$|⁠, and |${(\sum _{m=5}^B h(m))}/{h(1)}$|⁠.

In theory, the dispersion can be calculated across |$B_i^k-1$| ratios. However, these ratios do not convey a lot of relevant information, because they are almost all equal to 0 in the data, above a certain level of M.21 For this reason, we decided to restrict our attention to the variance computed over three empirically relevant |$h_{i}^k(M)/h_{i}^k(1)$| ratios, namely, |$M=\lbrace 2,[3,4],[5,B_i^k]\rbrace$|⁠, |$M=\lbrace 2,3,[4,B_i^k]\rbrace ,$| or |$M=\lbrace [2,3],[4,5],[6,B_i^k]\rbrace$| depending on the product and destination. In unreported results, we have estimated search frictions using the variance over four rather than three ratios, namely, |$M=\lbrace 2,[3,4],[5,6,7],[8,B_i^k]\rbrace$|⁠. The correlation between the baseline estimates and estimates recovered from the alternative definition is high, at 0.75, thus suggesting our strategy is not too sensitive to the precise moments aggregated within the variance operator.

We estimate search frictions with a generalized method of moments. As just explained, we focus on the theoretical moment defined in equation (8), which, conditional on |$B_i^k$|⁠, solely depends on |$\lambda _{i}^k$|⁠. The empirical counterpart of this theoretical moment is observed in our data
(9)
where |$\mathbb {1}\lbrace B_{i}^k(z)=M\rbrace$| is an observed dummy equal to 1 when firm z has exactly M buyers of product k in destination i, and |$m_1$|⁠, |$m_2$|⁠, and |$m_3$| denote the first, second, and third elements of |$M=\lbrace 2,[3,4],[5,B_i^k]\rbrace$|⁠, |$M=\lbrace 2,3,[4,B_i^k]\rbrace ,$| and |$M=\lbrace [2,3],[4,5],[6,B_i^k]\rbrace$|⁠, respectively.
The following convergence result applies (see details in Online Appendix C):
(10)
where |$\Omega _{i}^k(\lambda _{i}^k)$| is the variance of |$\widehat{\operatorname{Var}_{i}^k}$|⁠.22 Using the convergence result, identifying |$\lambda _{i}^k$| uniquely is possible. With an asymptotic least squares estimation strategy, the estimated variance of estimated frictions writes
with |$\Omega _{i}^k(\lambda _{i}^k)$| the optimal matrix of weights defined in Online Appendix C.

With a targeted moment that has an analytical formula, the implementation is straightforward. The only practical difficulty concerns the measurement of |$S^k$| and |$B_i^k$| in the data. Indeed, the theoretical moment in (8) identifies |$\lambda _{i}^k$| conditional on |$B_{i}^k$|⁠. Moreover, the total number |$S^k$| of potential suppliers is needed to compute both the optimal weights entering the objective function and the asymptotic variance of the estimator.

We recover measures of the population of buyers in each destination country and sector using predictions of the model regarding trade shares. Under the assumptions of the model, |$\pi _{i}^k$| is both the share of French products in country i’s absorption of product k and the ratio of the number of buyers from i buying their consumption from a French producer divided by the total number of buyers in i (⁠|$\pi _{i}^k=B_{iF}^k/B_{i}^k$|⁠). |$\pi _{i}^k$| can easily be recovered from sectoral bilateral trade and absorption data.23|$B_{iF}^k$| is observed in our data. Based on this, one can recover a value of |$B_{i}^k$| for each destination and sector.24

Information on the number of potential suppliers by |$hs6$| product is not available in any administrative dataset. We measure |$S^k$| based on information on the number of firms in each sector available from the INSEE-Repertoire Siren database. All firms belonging to a sector in which at least one firm makes 10% of its exports in a product are considered potential suppliers of the product. Atalay, Hortacsu, and Syverson (2014) use a comparable strategy to proxy for the number of firms susceptible to purchasing a firm’s output.

Using information on the number of potential sellers and buyers in each country and destination plus the information on the number of buyers in each seller’s portfolio, one can recover estimated values for the meeting probabilities. Because the minimization program is somewhat sensitive to the initial value, we use a grid search algorithm over 200 values of |$\lambda _{i}^k$| to select the algorithm’s starting point for each country and product.

4.2. Results

Summary Statistics.

Search frictions are estimated at the (product |$\times$| country) level for a total of 13,253 |$\lambda _{i}^k$| parameters, among which 13,219 are statistically significant at the 5% level. Table 2, first column, provides summary statistics on the estimated parameters. Remember that in the model, the |$\lambda _{i}^k$| coefficient is defined as the share of sellers from France that a given buyer in country i would meet, on average. We see an important level of dispersion in these probabilities. Indeed, 10% of product-country pairs have a meeting probability below 0.00%, whereas 10% have a meeting probability above 2.48%. The second column in Table 2 provides statistics regarding the probability that a French firm willing to export meets with zero buyer in the destination, which is equal to |$(1-\lambda _{i}^k)^{B_i^k}$| in the context of our model. The median probability of meeting zero buyer is 0.03% but increases to 4% and 57% for the top 25% and top 10% of product |$\times$| country pairs, respectively. These results are found robust over time, using 1997 and 2016 data as references.

Table 2.

Summary statistics on estimated coefficients.

MeetingProbabilityNumber
probabilityof meetingof buyers
zero buyer
|$\lambda _{i}^k$||$(1-\lambda _{i}^k)^{B_{i}^k}$||$B_{i}^k$|
(en %)(en %)
Mean1.0512.196159
Percentile 100.010.00296
Percentile 250.080.00715
Percentile 500.350.031,946
Percentile 751.074.395,677
Percentile 902.4856.5615,399
# Observations13,25313,25313,253
MeetingProbabilityNumber
probabilityof meetingof buyers
zero buyer
|$\lambda _{i}^k$||$(1-\lambda _{i}^k)^{B_{i}^k}$||$B_{i}^k$|
(en %)(en %)
Mean1.0512.196159
Percentile 100.010.00296
Percentile 250.080.00715
Percentile 500.350.031,946
Percentile 751.074.395,677
Percentile 902.4856.5615,399
# Observations13,25313,25313,253

Notes: The first column in this table presents summary statistics on the |$\lambda _{i}^k$| coefficients, estimated by country |$\times$| hs6 product. The second column summarizes the subsequent probabilities that a French exporter meets with no buyer in the destination computed as |$(1-\lambda _{i}^k)^{B_i^k}$| for each country and product. Statistics on the number of potential buyers are reported in the third column.

Table 2.

Summary statistics on estimated coefficients.

MeetingProbabilityNumber
probabilityof meetingof buyers
zero buyer
|$\lambda _{i}^k$||$(1-\lambda _{i}^k)^{B_{i}^k}$||$B_{i}^k$|
(en %)(en %)
Mean1.0512.196159
Percentile 100.010.00296
Percentile 250.080.00715
Percentile 500.350.031,946
Percentile 751.074.395,677
Percentile 902.4856.5615,399
# Observations13,25313,25313,253
MeetingProbabilityNumber
probabilityof meetingof buyers
zero buyer
|$\lambda _{i}^k$||$(1-\lambda _{i}^k)^{B_{i}^k}$||$B_{i}^k$|
(en %)(en %)
Mean1.0512.196159
Percentile 100.010.00296
Percentile 250.080.00715
Percentile 500.350.031,946
Percentile 751.074.395,677
Percentile 902.4856.5615,399
# Observations13,25313,25313,253

Notes: The first column in this table presents summary statistics on the |$\lambda _{i}^k$| coefficients, estimated by country |$\times$| hs6 product. The second column summarizes the subsequent probabilities that a French exporter meets with no buyer in the destination computed as |$(1-\lambda _{i}^k)^{B_i^k}$| for each country and product. Statistics on the number of potential buyers are reported in the third column.

Correlates of Search Frictions.

In Figure 4, we examine how the estimates correlate with different countries and product attributes. The top panel focuses on country-specific attributes. Each point in the figure shows the result of a univariate regression of the zero-match probability on the corresponding (standardized) country-level variable, conditional on product fixed effects. As expected, our estimates correlate negatively with the three proxies for information frictions, namely, the stock of French migrants in the destination, the index of social connectedness, and the share of citizens from France and the destination that speak a common language. Because we cannot rule out the influence of other forces affecting the empirical moment used in the structural estimation, we also correlate our estimates with additional variables. First, our estimates are positively correlated with distance, which means that French exporters have more difficulties meeting foreign buyers located in distant countries. Zero-match probabilities are also positively correlated with the size of the population in the destination country. This correlation is consistent with the presence of congestion effects in large markets (Eaton, Kortum, and Kramarz 2022). It may also reveal the influence of consumer heterogeneity, a determinant of trade that our model neglects but has been discussed extensively in the trade literature.25 Consumers’ heterogeneity can affect the matching of sellers and buyers in international markets, and thus the moment used for identification. To investigate this possibility further, we correlate our estimated zero-match probabilities with two proxies for the extent of consumers’ heterogeneity, namely, the Historical Index of Ethnic Fractionalization (Drazanova 2020) and a Gini index of income inequalities. Zero-match probabilities are reduced in countries that are more heterogeneous in terms of cultural preferences, but they are higher in more unequal countries. Whether frictions increase with consumer heterogeneity or whether our estimates of frictions capture income heterogeneity is hard to assess at this stage. In any case, the correlation between our estimates and bilateral variables such as distance or common proxies for search frictions suggests that estimated frictions capture more than consumer heterogeneity. Last, frictions tend to be stronger in new EU member states which display more recent trade ties with the rest of the European Union.

Correlates of the no-match probabilities with product and country attributes. This figure shows the estimated coefficient recovered from a regression that has the probability of zero match on the left-hand side of the estimated equation and the variable described on the left of the graph as the right-hand side variable. All explanatory variables are standardized. Results of the regressions are summarized in the top panel control for product fixed effects, whereas country fixed effects are used as a control in the bottom panel. The spikes correspond to a 95% confidence interval around the estimated coefficients.
Figure 4.

Correlates of the no-match probabilities with product and country attributes. This figure shows the estimated coefficient recovered from a regression that has the probability of zero match on the left-hand side of the estimated equation and the variable described on the left of the graph as the right-hand side variable. All explanatory variables are standardized. Results of the regressions are summarized in the top panel control for product fixed effects, whereas country fixed effects are used as a control in the bottom panel. The spikes correspond to a 95% confidence interval around the estimated coefficients.

We then examine the correlation between estimated frictions and product-level characteristics. The bottom panel of Figure 4 reports the results of separate regressions of zero-match probabilities on each of these characteristics and country fixed effects. We first examine whether frictions are correlated with product differentiation as measured by estimates of the elasticity of substitution (Imbs and Mejean 2015) or by Khandelwal’s (2010) quality ladder. These measures of differentiation are not systematically tied to our measures of search frictions. However, search frictions are lower for products sold in organized exchange markets as indicated by the positive correlation with the Rauch (2001) dummy. We also find a strong and positive correlation between input specificity (Nunn 2007) and search frictions, which suggests that frictions are higher among product categories featuring stronger investments in specific inputs. Last, search frictions are found lower among more upstream product categories as measured by Antràs et al. (2012) and for products that are mostly traded intra-firm.

Test of Empirical Predictions.

To assess the validity of our estimates, we confront the model’s predictions to the data. Section 3.2.1 unambiguously shows an increase in bilateral search frictions within a product category between France and a trade partner should lead to a reduction in French exports. We test this prediction of the model in Table 3. We first regress the logarithm of French exports (computed by destination–product pair) on standard gravity variables, namely, distance, market size, and income per capita. All specifications include product fixed effects to capture differences in French comparative advantages across product categories. In column (2), we add our estimates of search frictions. Consistent with the model’s prediction, estimated search frictions are negatively correlated with French exports. This negative correlation is robust to the inclusion of other proxies for information frictions in columns (3)–(5). Controling for search frictions does not significantly influence the coefficient on distance (columns (1) and (2)).

Table 3.

Search frictions and French market shares.

(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)
Dependent variable: log of product-level exports
log distance−0.928***−0.916***−0.701***−0.466***−0.284***
(0.0849)(0.0835)(0.103)(0.0828)(0.0856)
log import demand0.736***0.737***0.774***0.837***0.842***
(0.0217)(0.0217)(0.0238)(0.0217)(0.0213)
log GDP per capita−0.427***−0.425***−0.404***−0.380***−0.453***
(0.0638)(0.0636)(0.0624)(0.0529)(0.0569)
Proba no match−0.185***−0.180***−0.148***−0.167***
(0.0490)(0.0484)(0.0460)(0.0448)
Common language0.802***
(0.298)
Social connectedness0.268***
(0.0281)
Share migrants0.272***
(0.0227)
Observations12,80212,80212,80212,80212,802
R-squared0.7940.7940.7950.8010.807
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)
Dependent variable: log of product-level exports
log distance−0.928***−0.916***−0.701***−0.466***−0.284***
(0.0849)(0.0835)(0.103)(0.0828)(0.0856)
log import demand0.736***0.737***0.774***0.837***0.842***
(0.0217)(0.0217)(0.0238)(0.0217)(0.0213)
log GDP per capita−0.427***−0.425***−0.404***−0.380***−0.453***
(0.0638)(0.0636)(0.0624)(0.0529)(0.0569)
Proba no match−0.185***−0.180***−0.148***−0.167***
(0.0490)(0.0484)(0.0460)(0.0448)
Common language0.802***
(0.298)
Social connectedness0.268***
(0.0281)
Share migrants0.272***
(0.0227)
Observations12,80212,80212,80212,80212,802
R-squared0.7940.7940.7950.8010.807

Notes: Standard errors, clustered in the country dimension, are in parentheses, with |$^{***}$| denoting significance at the 1% level. “log Distance” is the log of the weighted distance between France and the destination. “log Import demand” is the log of the value of the destination’s demand of imports for the hs6–product, less the demand addressed to France. “log GDP per capita” is the log-GDP per capita in the destination. “Proba no match” is the estimated probability of the seller meeting with zero buyer in the destination. “Common language” is the probability that citizens from France and the destination speak a common language. “Social connectedness” is the social connectedness between France and destinations as measured by Bailey et al. (2021) using anonymized data from Facebook. ”Share migrants” is the number of French citizens in the destination country, per 1,000 inhabitants. The dependent variable is the log of product-level bilateral exports.

Table 3.

Search frictions and French market shares.

(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)
Dependent variable: log of product-level exports
log distance−0.928***−0.916***−0.701***−0.466***−0.284***
(0.0849)(0.0835)(0.103)(0.0828)(0.0856)
log import demand0.736***0.737***0.774***0.837***0.842***
(0.0217)(0.0217)(0.0238)(0.0217)(0.0213)
log GDP per capita−0.427***−0.425***−0.404***−0.380***−0.453***
(0.0638)(0.0636)(0.0624)(0.0529)(0.0569)
Proba no match−0.185***−0.180***−0.148***−0.167***
(0.0490)(0.0484)(0.0460)(0.0448)
Common language0.802***
(0.298)
Social connectedness0.268***
(0.0281)
Share migrants0.272***
(0.0227)
Observations12,80212,80212,80212,80212,802
R-squared0.7940.7940.7950.8010.807
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)
Dependent variable: log of product-level exports
log distance−0.928***−0.916***−0.701***−0.466***−0.284***
(0.0849)(0.0835)(0.103)(0.0828)(0.0856)
log import demand0.736***0.737***0.774***0.837***0.842***
(0.0217)(0.0217)(0.0238)(0.0217)(0.0213)
log GDP per capita−0.427***−0.425***−0.404***−0.380***−0.453***
(0.0638)(0.0636)(0.0624)(0.0529)(0.0569)
Proba no match−0.185***−0.180***−0.148***−0.167***
(0.0490)(0.0484)(0.0460)(0.0448)
Common language0.802***
(0.298)
Social connectedness0.268***
(0.0281)
Share migrants0.272***
(0.0227)
Observations12,80212,80212,80212,80212,802
R-squared0.7940.7940.7950.8010.807

Notes: Standard errors, clustered in the country dimension, are in parentheses, with |$^{***}$| denoting significance at the 1% level. “log Distance” is the log of the weighted distance between France and the destination. “log Import demand” is the log of the value of the destination’s demand of imports for the hs6–product, less the demand addressed to France. “log GDP per capita” is the log-GDP per capita in the destination. “Proba no match” is the estimated probability of the seller meeting with zero buyer in the destination. “Common language” is the probability that citizens from France and the destination speak a common language. “Social connectedness” is the social connectedness between France and destinations as measured by Bailey et al. (2021) using anonymized data from Facebook. ”Share migrants” is the number of French citizens in the destination country, per 1,000 inhabitants. The dependent variable is the log of product-level bilateral exports.

Model Fit.

Having shown our estimates of search frictions correlate with observables in a theory-consistent way, we now evaluate the model’s ability to reproduce key features of the data. We use our parameter estimates to simulate the expected number of sellers interacting with zero to ten buyers within a destination market. Based on this, we can compute the cumulated distribution of sellers’ number of buyers in a market, and compare it with the data.26 Figure 5 summarizes the results obtained when pooling all product |$\times$| country pairs. Country-specific Figures are reproduced in the Online Appendix (Figure D.4). A visual inspection shows the model performs relatively well on the left-hand side of the distribution, but the right-tail is fatter in the data than in the model. The |$\lambda _i^k$| parameters are estimated from the dispersion in the stock of buyers across French sellers serving the same destination. We do not consider the expected number of sellers serving one client in our set of moments. Interestingly, our simple model reproduces almost perfectly the share of sellers serving a single buyer within a destination, that is, the fit is good regarding the curvature of CDF and its intercept. Although the first moment is targeted in our estimation, the second is not.

Model fit: distribution of sellers’ degrees. The figure compares the CDF of the distribution of exporters’ degrees in the data and the estimated model. The CDF is first simulated at the country $\times$ product level based on estimated parameters and then aggregated across country $\times$ product pairs.
Figure 5.

Model fit: distribution of sellers’ degrees. The figure compares the CDF of the distribution of exporters’ degrees in the data and the estimated model. The CDF is first simulated at the country |$\times$| product level based on estimated parameters and then aggregated across country |$\times$| product pairs.

The ability of the model to match the share of sellers serving a single buyer is further evaluated in Table 4. Instead of aggregating across products within countries, we predict the share of sellers serving one buyer for each product–country pair. Table 4 reports the correlation between the observed and predicted shares. In the first column, we report the unconditional correlation. In column (2), country fixed effects are introduced, whereas column (3) has country and product fixed effects. The |$R^2$| of the first regression implies that our simple model accounts for 17% of the dispersion in the share of sellers serving a single buyer. The correlation with the predicted shares is highly significant in the three specifications, which confirms the correlation is valid within countries across products as well as across products within countries. Quantitatively similar results are obtained when we investigate the model’s ability to explain the share of sellers with two or three buyers.

Table 4.

Model fit: share of one-buyer sellers.

Dependent variable: empirical share of one buyer
(1)(2)(3)
Predicted share0.289***0.267***0.172***
(0.005)(0.005)(0.005)
Constant0.390***
(0.003)
# observations13,25313,25313,253
Fixed effectsNoCountryCountry
Product
R-squared0.1720.2500.563
Dependent variable: empirical share of one buyer
(1)(2)(3)
Predicted share0.289***0.267***0.172***
(0.005)(0.005)(0.005)
Constant0.390***
(0.003)
# observations13,25313,25313,253
Fixed effectsNoCountryCountry
Product
R-squared0.1720.2500.563

Notes: The predicted share of sellers with one buyer is calculated as |$h_{ij}(1)/\sum _{M=1}^{B_i}h_{ij}(M)$|⁠. Robust standard errors are in parentheses, with |$^{***}$| denoting significance at the 1% level.

Table 4.

Model fit: share of one-buyer sellers.

Dependent variable: empirical share of one buyer
(1)(2)(3)
Predicted share0.289***0.267***0.172***
(0.005)(0.005)(0.005)
Constant0.390***
(0.003)
# observations13,25313,25313,253
Fixed effectsNoCountryCountry
Product
R-squared0.1720.2500.563
Dependent variable: empirical share of one buyer
(1)(2)(3)
Predicted share0.289***0.267***0.172***
(0.005)(0.005)(0.005)
Constant0.390***
(0.003)
# observations13,25313,25313,253
Fixed effectsNoCountryCountry
Product
R-squared0.1720.2500.563

Notes: The predicted share of sellers with one buyer is calculated as |$h_{ij}(1)/\sum _{M=1}^{B_i}h_{ij}(M)$|⁠. Robust standard errors are in parentheses, with |$^{***}$| denoting significance at the 1% level.

5. The Distortive Impact of Search Frictions

Having explained how firm-to-firm trade data can be used to recover estimates for search frictions, we now turn to the paper’s main question, namely, how such frictions distort the selection of firms in international markets.

5.1. Search Frictions and Ricardian Comparative Advantage

As explained in Section 3, the strength of search-induced distortions depends on how they correlate with comparative advantages. Intuitively, search frictions are all the more distortive if they hit firms that would, on average, display strong comparative advantages in the frictionless economy. We now investigate whether it is the case in the data, using cross-sectoral measures of revealed comparative advantages and the dispersion in estimated frictions, across products.

Revealed comparative advantages are measured using a strategy inspired by Costinot, Donaldson, and Komunjer (2012). Exploiting the gravity structure of the model, equation (2) can be used to recover a statistical decomposition of bilateral exports into its different components
(11)
where we now explicitly introduce the product dimension k. |$\pi _{ij}^k$| thus measures the share of producers from country j in country i’s consumption of product k. In this equation, the exporter–product fixed effect |$FE_{j}^k$| absorbs the impact of Ricardian technological advantages that affect a country’s sales in all export destinations. A positive correlation between this term and estimated search frictions is thus indicative of magnified distortions, that is, search frictions that are particularly high in those product markets in which French exporters have a Ricardian comparative advantage.

To test whether it is the case in the data, we first estimate equation (11) using the CEPII-BACI multilateral trade database available at the product level for 2007. Estimated revealed comparative advantages for France are then correlated with the product-specific average of estimated search frictions. Results shown in Figure 6 show a strong positive correlation between France’s comparative advantages and the average probability of the seller meeting with zero buyers in the destination, our proxy for the magnitude of search frictions. Note that the correlation is strongly positive, at 21%, despite the fact that estimated revealed comparative advantages also absorb the mean level of dyadic trade frictions in such statistical decomposition (the mean of |$\ln \lambda _{ij}^k(d_{ij}^k)^{-\theta ^k}$| across destinations within a product and origin country). For this reason, there is a mechanical negative correlation between the estimated fixed effect and the zero-match probability that plays against the correlation recovered in Figure 6.27 The positive correlation is consistent with search frictions faced by French firms in Europe being distortive because they penalize more those sectors in which French firms have a comparative advantage.

Correlation of search frictions with comparative advantages. The graph is a binned scatter plot of the log of revealed comparative advantages measured for each hs6 product, using equation (11) against the mean value of the no-match probability (averaged across destinations within a product).
Figure 6.

Correlation of search frictions with comparative advantages. The graph is a binned scatter plot of the log of revealed comparative advantages measured for each hs6 product, using equation (11) against the mean value of the no-match probability (averaged across destinations within a product).

5.2. Search Frictions, Productivity, and Export Performances

A consequence of the distortive impact of frictions, discussed in Section 3.2.2, is that search frictions also affect selection mechanisms across sellers within an origin country. In the frictionless benchmark, only the most efficient firms can expect to serve foreign markets. In the frictional model instead, low-productivity firms have a strictly positive probability of serving at least one buyer in each destination, and the probability is all the higher since frictions are severe. The mapping between the productivity and the export performances of French firms in export markets is suggestive of the size of competitive distortions induced by search frictions.

To test this prediction of the model, we leverage on external balance-sheet data on French firms to measure the relative productivity of exporters. We use two measures of productivity, the size of domestic sales and the firm’s apparent labor productivity. We then estimate heterogeneity in export performances across firms within a product and destination and how it varies depending on the strength of estimated search frictions. According to our model, we shall see the relative export performance of high-productivity firms being dampened in more frictional markets.

Results are summarized in Table 5. Columns (1)–(3) use domestic sales to characterize firms’ heterogeneity, while columns (4)–(6) use the firm’s apparent labor productivity. Our measure of a firm’s export performance is based on the value of annual exports, but we have reproduced the same analysis using the number of buyers instead, and results are qualitatively unchanged. All regressions control for destination |$\times$| product fixed effects so that identification is across firms within the same market. We first confirm that, on average, in our data, larger and more productive firms display better performances than smaller and less productive firms engaged in the same market (columns (1) and (4)). In the context of our model, the correlation comes from high productivity firms displaying a cost advantage that increases their probability of serving any foreign partner, in comparison with lower-productivity domestic competitors.28

Table 5.

Impact of search frictions on the relative export performances of heterogeneously productive firms.

Dependent variable: |$\ln$| firm-level bilateral exports
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
|$\ln$| domestic sales0.211***0.218***
(0.011)(0.011)
|$-$||$\times$| probability no match−0.047***
(0.011)
|${\mathbb {1}}$| top quartile sectoral sales0.400***
(0.032)
|$-$||$\times$| probability no match−0.121**
(0.056)
|$\ln$| L productivity0.279***0.285***
(0.022)(0.023)
|$-$||$\times$| probability no match−0.044*
(0.026)
|${\mathbb {1}}$| top quartile sectoral L productivity0.299***
(0.038)
|$-$||$\times$| probability no match−0.119***
(0.042)
Observations470,807470,807470,807470,807470,807470,807
R-squared0.2300.2310.2130.2160.2160.213
Fixed effectsProductProductProductProductProductProduct
−Country−Country−Country−Country−Country−Country
Dependent variable: |$\ln$| firm-level bilateral exports
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
|$\ln$| domestic sales0.211***0.218***
(0.011)(0.011)
|$-$||$\times$| probability no match−0.047***
(0.011)
|${\mathbb {1}}$| top quartile sectoral sales0.400***
(0.032)
|$-$||$\times$| probability no match−0.121**
(0.056)
|$\ln$| L productivity0.279***0.285***
(0.022)(0.023)
|$-$||$\times$| probability no match−0.044*
(0.026)
|${\mathbb {1}}$| top quartile sectoral L productivity0.299***
(0.038)
|$-$||$\times$| probability no match−0.119***
(0.042)
Observations470,807470,807470,807470,807470,807470,807
R-squared0.2300.2310.2130.2160.2160.213
Fixed effectsProductProductProductProductProductProduct
−Country−Country−Country−Country−Country−Country

Notes: Standard errors, clustered in the firm dimension, are in parentheses, with |$^{***}$|⁠, |$^{**}$|⁠, and |$^{*}$|⁠, respectively, denoting significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels. The dependent variable is the log of the firm’s exports to the destination country. The right-hand side variables include a proxy for the firm’s productivity and its interaction with the level of frictions (“Proba No Match”). We use four alternative proxies for the firm’s productivity: the value of its domestic sales (“ln Domestic Sales”), a dummy variable equal to 1 if the firm’s domestic sales fall in the top quartile of the firm’s sector-specific distribution (“|${\mathbb {1}}$| Top Quartile Sectoral Sales”), the firm’s apparent labor productivity computed as the ratio of value added over the number of employees (“ln L productivity”), and a dummy equal to 1 if the firm falls into the top quartile of the sector-specific distribution of labor productivities (“|${\mathbb {1}}$| Top Quartile Sectoral L Prod.”).

Table 5.

Impact of search frictions on the relative export performances of heterogeneously productive firms.

Dependent variable: |$\ln$| firm-level bilateral exports
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
|$\ln$| domestic sales0.211***0.218***
(0.011)(0.011)
|$-$||$\times$| probability no match−0.047***
(0.011)
|${\mathbb {1}}$| top quartile sectoral sales0.400***
(0.032)
|$-$||$\times$| probability no match−0.121**
(0.056)
|$\ln$| L productivity0.279***0.285***
(0.022)(0.023)
|$-$||$\times$| probability no match−0.044*
(0.026)
|${\mathbb {1}}$| top quartile sectoral L productivity0.299***
(0.038)
|$-$||$\times$| probability no match−0.119***
(0.042)
Observations470,807470,807470,807470,807470,807470,807
R-squared0.2300.2310.2130.2160.2160.213
Fixed effectsProductProductProductProductProductProduct
−Country−Country−Country−Country−Country−Country
Dependent variable: |$\ln$| firm-level bilateral exports
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
|$\ln$| domestic sales0.211***0.218***
(0.011)(0.011)
|$-$||$\times$| probability no match−0.047***
(0.011)
|${\mathbb {1}}$| top quartile sectoral sales0.400***
(0.032)
|$-$||$\times$| probability no match−0.121**
(0.056)
|$\ln$| L productivity0.279***0.285***
(0.022)(0.023)
|$-$||$\times$| probability no match−0.044*
(0.026)
|${\mathbb {1}}$| top quartile sectoral L productivity0.299***
(0.038)
|$-$||$\times$| probability no match−0.119***
(0.042)
Observations470,807470,807470,807470,807470,807470,807
R-squared0.2300.2310.2130.2160.2160.213
Fixed effectsProductProductProductProductProductProduct
−Country−Country−Country−Country−Country−Country

Notes: Standard errors, clustered in the firm dimension, are in parentheses, with |$^{***}$|⁠, |$^{**}$|⁠, and |$^{*}$|⁠, respectively, denoting significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels. The dependent variable is the log of the firm’s exports to the destination country. The right-hand side variables include a proxy for the firm’s productivity and its interaction with the level of frictions (“Proba No Match”). We use four alternative proxies for the firm’s productivity: the value of its domestic sales (“ln Domestic Sales”), a dummy variable equal to 1 if the firm’s domestic sales fall in the top quartile of the firm’s sector-specific distribution (“|${\mathbb {1}}$| Top Quartile Sectoral Sales”), the firm’s apparent labor productivity computed as the ratio of value added over the number of employees (“ln L productivity”), and a dummy equal to 1 if the firm falls into the top quartile of the sector-specific distribution of labor productivities (“|${\mathbb {1}}$| Top Quartile Sectoral L Prod.”).

The remaining columns test a distinctive property of our model, namely, that the export premium of large firms is reduced in more frictional markets. As expected, the coefficient on the interaction between the firm’s productivity and the estimated no-match probability is always negative and significant. In quantitative terms, the export premium of firms in the top quartile of the distribution of sectoral domestic sales (resp. sectoral labor productivity) increases from 32.2% to 40.0% (resp. 22.3%–30.0%) when moving from the first to the ninth decile of the distribution of estimated no-match probabilities.

This empirical exercise thus provides additional weight to our interpretation of the estimated parameters in terms of search frictions. Whereas the empirical moment used to identify search frictions may capture other deep parameters in the context of alternative models of the matching between sellers and buyers in international markets (Section 3.3), the dampening impact of frictions on large firms’ export premium is difficult to rationalize in such alternative models.29

5.3. Quantifying the Efficiency Loss Induced by Search Frictions

Having confirmed in the data that our estimated search frictions correlate with the export premium of high-productivity firms, we now proceed with a counterfactual exercise to quantify the magnitude of the distortion induced by such trade barriers. We simulate a drop in the level of search frictions faced by French firms in foreign markets, keeping parameters governing competition from the rest of the world unchanged. The heterogeneous impact of the counterfactual reduction in search frictions along the distribution of productivities has distributional consequences that pertain to the allocative efficiency.

In practice, our simulations exploit the prediction of the model summarized in equation (6). Given estimated and counterfactual frictions |$\lambda _{i}^k$|⁠, observed and counterfactual market shares |$\pi _{i}^k$| and a calibrated mass of potential exporters |$T_j^k \underline{z}^{-\theta }$|⁠, the equation can be used to compute the consequences of reducing search frictions at different percentiles of the (Pareto) distribution. We simulate a homogenous upward shift in the value of meeting probabilities, that is scaled by the observed heterogeneity in estimated parameters. Namely, we multiply all parameters by 4.2, which is the ratio of estimated coefficients at the first and second quartiles of the distribution.30

Results are summarized in Figure 7, which shows the probability of export (left panel) and the average number of buyers conditional on exporting (right panel), at various percentiles of the productivity distribution, in the data and the counterfactual world. Increasing meeting probabilities has a non-monotonic impact along the distribution of firms’ productivities, with low-productivity firms seeing their export probability reduced and high-productivity firms gaining in terms of both export probability and their expected number of buyers, conditional on export. On average across product markets, the probability of exports is reduced for firms below the 70th productivity percentile, whereas the increase in the expected number of buyers is above one after the 58th percentile and above five in the top 15% of the distribution. Together, these results imply that the mean productivity of exporting firms increases following the drop in search frictions, by 5%–10%.31 Combining the results in both panels of Figure 7 gives expected exports along the productivity distribution. In the baseline calibration that matches the export premium of large exporters market by market, firms at the 75th percentile export 4.06 more than firms at the 25th percentile, on average. In the counterfactual, the ratio reaches 4.78, a 17% increase. Reducing search frictions thus affects the allocative efficiency, by redistributing (foreign) market shares from low- to high-productivity firms.

Probability of exporting and expected number of buyers conditional on exports along the productivity distribution: actual vs. counterfactual. The figure shows the probability of serving at least one buyer (left panel) and the expected number of buyers conditional on exporting (right panel), in the average market of French firms, along the (product-specific) productivity distribution. The solid lines correspond to the actual equilibrium. The dashed lines are the counterfactual with reduced search frictions. The counterfactual is computed assuming that all meeting probabilities are shifted up, by a factor that corresponds to the ratio of estimated frictions at the median and first quartile of the distribution of estimated parameters. Results are then aggregated across products and countries using information on the relative number of firms in each product market.
Figure 7.

Probability of exporting and expected number of buyers conditional on exports along the productivity distribution: actual vs. counterfactual. The figure shows the probability of serving at least one buyer (left panel) and the expected number of buyers conditional on exporting (right panel), in the average market of French firms, along the (product-specific) productivity distribution. The solid lines correspond to the actual equilibrium. The dashed lines are the counterfactual with reduced search frictions. The counterfactual is computed assuming that all meeting probabilities are shifted up, by a factor that corresponds to the ratio of estimated frictions at the median and first quartile of the distribution of estimated parameters. Results are then aggregated across products and countries using information on the relative number of firms in each product market.

These numbers, however, hide a strong degree of heterogeneity across products and destinations, which we summarize in Figure 8. The ratio of high- to low-productivity firms’ exports is now calculated market-by-market. We then compare the actual value of the export premium with its counterfactual value in a world with lower search frictions. As expected, the export premium always increases in this simulation. The magnitude of the reallocation from low to high productivity firms, however, across markets. In our setting, a homogenous increase in meeting probabilities has more impact in product markets in which the initial market share of French firms is the largest such as the markets for live fish, fertilizers, or iron and steel, most notably in Belgium and Luxembourg or in Estonia.

Impact of the drop in search frictions on product-level export premia. The figure shows the log of the actual and counterfactual export premium of firms at the 75th percentile relative to firms at the 25th percentile of the product-specific distribution of productivity, by product and destination. In the counterfactual exercise, the value of the meeting probability is multiplied by the ratio of estimated probabilities at the second and the first quartiles of the distribution. The solid line corresponds to the 45-degree line.
Figure 8.

Impact of the drop in search frictions on product-level export premia. The figure shows the log of the actual and counterfactual export premium of firms at the 75th percentile relative to firms at the 25th percentile of the product-specific distribution of productivity, by product and destination. In the counterfactual exercise, the value of the meeting probability is multiplied by the ratio of estimated probabilities at the second and the first quartiles of the distribution. The solid line corresponds to the 45-degree line.

For comparison purposes, we ran another counterfactual exercise in which iceberg costs, instead of search frictions, are reduced product-by-product, keeping everything else unchanged. Because both parameters are not directly comparable, the counterfactual is calibrated such that the change in product-level trade shares is the same as in the counterfactual experiment just described. Moving from the actual to this counterfactual equilibrium induces a substantial increase in export probabilities for French firms, from 40% to 70% on average. However, this increase in export probabilities does not induce an efficiency gain as in the case of a reduction in search frictions. The drop in iceberg costs actually benefits low-productivity firms, in relative terms. The reason is that decreased iceberg costs push down the relative price offered by French firm relative to other countries’ firms, thus increasing the likelihood of being the lowest-cost supplier conditional on a match. This competitiveness gain over non-French exporters benefits more firms suffering from a lack of competitiveness. As a result, the average productivity of exporters decreases in this counterfactual experiment, with a drop of between 9% and 14%.

All in all, these results confirm the quantitatively important role of frictions. In comparison with standard barriers to international trade, they distort competition among potential exporters. Such frictions thus benefit low-productivity firms, whereas they reduce the export probability and expected exports at the top of the distribution.

6. Conclusion

This paper shows how search frictions in international goods markets can distort competition between firms of heterogeneous productivity. We develop a Ricardian model of trade in which buyers in each market meet with a random number of potential suppliers of a perfectly substitutable good. The model combines two barriers to international trade. Physical (iceberg) trade costs reduce the competitiveness of all exporters in foreign markets. Instead, bilateral search frictions reduce the likelihood that any exporter will meet with a foreign consumer but also decrease competitive pressures, conditional on having met with a potential buyer. The relative strength of these two forces varies along the distribution of firms’ productivity. Although high-productivity firms always suffer from a lack of visibility in foreign markets, low-productivity firms can sometimes benefit from high search frictions because, conditional on having met with a buyer, these frictions reduce the strength of competition, thus increasing the chances that the firm will be chosen to serve the buyer. This heterogeneous impact of frictions along the productivity distribution is a distinctive feature of our model. In highly frictional markets, the export premium of high-productivity firms is lowered and the export probability of small and medium firms increased.

We provide direct evidence of such distortion in our data. Bilateral search frictions are first estimated structurally using firm-to-firm trade data at the product and destination level. For each French firm and each product it sells, we can measure the size of its customer base in a particular destination. In the model, heterogeneity across firms in this number is explained by firms’ heterogeneous productivity and the magnitude of search frictions in the destination. Intuitively, more frictional markets induce more distortions, which reduces the export premium of high-productivity firms. We use this property of the model to structurally recover a measure of search frictions, for each product and destination. Estimated frictions are found to correlate with country and product attributes in a theoretically consistent way.

The estimated frictions are especially large in product markets where French firms have a comparative advantage, on average. Moreover, we provide evidence that the export premium of high-productivity firms is systematically reduced in markets that we estimate are more frictional. Using a counterfactual experiment, we show that reducing search frictions can generate sizeable gains in terms of the efficiency of selection mechanisms into export. Shifting meeting probabilities up by an amount that corresponds to the ratio of these probabilities at the second and first quartiles of the distribution reduces export probabilities up to the 68th percentile of the distribution of productivities while increasing export probabilities and the customer base of high-productivity exporters. The average productivity of exporters rises as a result, with an increase ranging from 5% to 10%. A comparable drop in iceberg costs would instead reduce the mean productivity of exporters, by about 10%.

The distortive impact of search frictions can rationalize a number of active policies used by export-promoting agencies. In a frictional world, any policy instrument that can help high-productivity firms that suffer from a lack of visibility abroad meet with foreign buyers induces aggregate productivity gains. Such policies may, however, hurt low-productivity exporters.

Appendix A: Additional Results

Number of sellers per buyer, within and across products. This figure compares the number of sellers per buyer, computed within a product and across products.
Figure A.1.

Number of sellers per buyer, within and across products. This figure compares the number of sellers per buyer, computed within a product and across products.

Table A.1.

Product- and firm-level gravity equations: robustness to the proxy for information frictions.

Dependent variable (all in log)
Product-levelFirm-level
Value of## buyersMean exportValue of# buyersExports
exportssellersper sellerper buyer–sellerexportsper buyer
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)(7)
log distance−0.482***−0.258***−0.142***−0.0819*−0.0867*−0.118***0.0310
(0.0644)(0.0293)(0.0230)(0.0443)(0.0476)(0.0255)(0.0416)
log import demand0.862***0.259***0.156***0.446***0.464***0.199***0.265***
(0.0150)(0.00583)(0.00506)(0.0103)(0.0103)(0.00766)(0.00915)
log GDP per capita−0.185***−0.0842***−0.0215*−0.0790***−0.158***−0.108***−0.0500***
(0.0347)(0.0163)(0.0119)(0.0254)(0.0270)(0.0163)(0.0186)
log French migrants0.352***0.212***0.0970***0.0430***0.211***0.115***0.0964***
(0.0203)(0.00890)(0.00717)(0.0123)(0.0143)(0.00758)(0.0115)
Observations63,09663,09663,09663,096621,816621,816621,816
R-squared0.6450.7940.4290.5830.6890.4350.718
Fixed effectsProductProductProductProductFirmFirmFirm
log distance−0.762***−0.373***−0.190***−0.199***−0.188***−0.138***−0.0497
(0.0604)(0.0285)(0.0214)(0.0408)(0.0446)(0.0239)(0.0392)
log import demand0.875***0.275***0.164***0.436***0.480***0.214***0.266***
(0.0150)(0.00636)(0.00516)(0.00958)(0.0111)(0.00772)(0.00963)
log GDP per capita0.0840***0.0720***0.0493***−0.0373−0.0395*−0.0450***0.00546
(0.0319)(0.0153)(0.0104)(0.0233)(0.0235)(0.0142)(0.0170)
log social connectedness0.312***0.230***0.109***−0.0275*0.226***0.145***0.0806***
(0.0258)(0.0122)(0.00893)(0.0156)(0.0158)(0.00998)(0.0123)
Observations63,09663,09663,09663,096621,816621,816621,816
R-squared0.6380.7860.4240.5830.6870.4340.718
Fixed effectsProductProductProductProductFirmFirmFirm
Dependent variable (all in log)
Product-levelFirm-level
Value of## buyersMean exportValue of# buyersExports
exportssellersper sellerper buyer–sellerexportsper buyer
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)(7)
log distance−0.482***−0.258***−0.142***−0.0819*−0.0867*−0.118***0.0310
(0.0644)(0.0293)(0.0230)(0.0443)(0.0476)(0.0255)(0.0416)
log import demand0.862***0.259***0.156***0.446***0.464***0.199***0.265***
(0.0150)(0.00583)(0.00506)(0.0103)(0.0103)(0.00766)(0.00915)
log GDP per capita−0.185***−0.0842***−0.0215*−0.0790***−0.158***−0.108***−0.0500***
(0.0347)(0.0163)(0.0119)(0.0254)(0.0270)(0.0163)(0.0186)
log French migrants0.352***0.212***0.0970***0.0430***0.211***0.115***0.0964***
(0.0203)(0.00890)(0.00717)(0.0123)(0.0143)(0.00758)(0.0115)
Observations63,09663,09663,09663,096621,816621,816621,816
R-squared0.6450.7940.4290.5830.6890.4350.718
Fixed effectsProductProductProductProductFirmFirmFirm
log distance−0.762***−0.373***−0.190***−0.199***−0.188***−0.138***−0.0497
(0.0604)(0.0285)(0.0214)(0.0408)(0.0446)(0.0239)(0.0392)
log import demand0.875***0.275***0.164***0.436***0.480***0.214***0.266***
(0.0150)(0.00636)(0.00516)(0.00958)(0.0111)(0.00772)(0.00963)
log GDP per capita0.0840***0.0720***0.0493***−0.0373−0.0395*−0.0450***0.00546
(0.0319)(0.0153)(0.0104)(0.0233)(0.0235)(0.0142)(0.0170)
log social connectedness0.312***0.230***0.109***−0.0275*0.226***0.145***0.0806***
(0.0258)(0.0122)(0.00893)(0.0156)(0.0158)(0.00998)(0.0123)
Observations63,09663,09663,09663,096621,816621,816621,816
R-squared0.6380.7860.4240.5830.6870.4340.718
Fixed effectsProductProductProductProductFirmFirmFirm

Notes: Standard errors, clustered in the country |$\times$| HS2 chapter dimension, are in parentheses, with |$^{***}$| and |$^{*}$|⁠, respectively, denoting significance at the 1% and 10% levels. “log Distance” is the log of the weighted distance between France and the destination. “log Import demand” is the log of the value of the destination’s demand of imports for the hs6–product, less the demand addressed to France. “log GDP per capita” is the log-GDP per capita in the destination. “log French migrants” is the log of the number of French migrants per 1,000 of inhabitants in the destination country. log social connectedness is the log of the social connectedness between France the destination as measured by Bailey et al. (2021) using anonymized Facebook data. The dependent variable is either the log of product-level French exports in the destination (column (1)) or one of its components, namely, the number of sellers involved in the trade flow (column (2)), the mean number of buyers they serve (column (3)), and the mean value of a seller–buyer transaction (column (4)). Column (5) uses the log of firm-level bilateral exports as left-hand side variable, whereas columns (6) and (7) use one of its components, the number of buyers served (column (6)), or the value of exports per buyer (column (7)).

Table A.1.

Product- and firm-level gravity equations: robustness to the proxy for information frictions.

Dependent variable (all in log)
Product-levelFirm-level
Value of## buyersMean exportValue of# buyersExports
exportssellersper sellerper buyer–sellerexportsper buyer
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)(7)
log distance−0.482***−0.258***−0.142***−0.0819*−0.0867*−0.118***0.0310
(0.0644)(0.0293)(0.0230)(0.0443)(0.0476)(0.0255)(0.0416)
log import demand0.862***0.259***0.156***0.446***0.464***0.199***0.265***
(0.0150)(0.00583)(0.00506)(0.0103)(0.0103)(0.00766)(0.00915)
log GDP per capita−0.185***−0.0842***−0.0215*−0.0790***−0.158***−0.108***−0.0500***
(0.0347)(0.0163)(0.0119)(0.0254)(0.0270)(0.0163)(0.0186)
log French migrants0.352***0.212***0.0970***0.0430***0.211***0.115***0.0964***
(0.0203)(0.00890)(0.00717)(0.0123)(0.0143)(0.00758)(0.0115)
Observations63,09663,09663,09663,096621,816621,816621,816
R-squared0.6450.7940.4290.5830.6890.4350.718
Fixed effectsProductProductProductProductFirmFirmFirm
log distance−0.762***−0.373***−0.190***−0.199***−0.188***−0.138***−0.0497
(0.0604)(0.0285)(0.0214)(0.0408)(0.0446)(0.0239)(0.0392)
log import demand0.875***0.275***0.164***0.436***0.480***0.214***0.266***
(0.0150)(0.00636)(0.00516)(0.00958)(0.0111)(0.00772)(0.00963)
log GDP per capita0.0840***0.0720***0.0493***−0.0373−0.0395*−0.0450***0.00546
(0.0319)(0.0153)(0.0104)(0.0233)(0.0235)(0.0142)(0.0170)
log social connectedness0.312***0.230***0.109***−0.0275*0.226***0.145***0.0806***
(0.0258)(0.0122)(0.00893)(0.0156)(0.0158)(0.00998)(0.0123)
Observations63,09663,09663,09663,096621,816621,816621,816
R-squared0.6380.7860.4240.5830.6870.4340.718
Fixed effectsProductProductProductProductFirmFirmFirm
Dependent variable (all in log)
Product-levelFirm-level
Value of## buyersMean exportValue of# buyersExports
exportssellersper sellerper buyer–sellerexportsper buyer
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)(7)
log distance−0.482***−0.258***−0.142***−0.0819*−0.0867*−0.118***0.0310
(0.0644)(0.0293)(0.0230)(0.0443)(0.0476)(0.0255)(0.0416)
log import demand0.862***0.259***0.156***0.446***0.464***0.199***0.265***
(0.0150)(0.00583)(0.00506)(0.0103)(0.0103)(0.00766)(0.00915)
log GDP per capita−0.185***−0.0842***−0.0215*−0.0790***−0.158***−0.108***−0.0500***
(0.0347)(0.0163)(0.0119)(0.0254)(0.0270)(0.0163)(0.0186)
log French migrants0.352***0.212***0.0970***0.0430***0.211***0.115***0.0964***
(0.0203)(0.00890)(0.00717)(0.0123)(0.0143)(0.00758)(0.0115)
Observations63,09663,09663,09663,096621,816621,816621,816
R-squared0.6450.7940.4290.5830.6890.4350.718
Fixed effectsProductProductProductProductFirmFirmFirm
log distance−0.762***−0.373***−0.190***−0.199***−0.188***−0.138***−0.0497
(0.0604)(0.0285)(0.0214)(0.0408)(0.0446)(0.0239)(0.0392)
log import demand0.875***0.275***0.164***0.436***0.480***0.214***0.266***
(0.0150)(0.00636)(0.00516)(0.00958)(0.0111)(0.00772)(0.00963)
log GDP per capita0.0840***0.0720***0.0493***−0.0373−0.0395*−0.0450***0.00546
(0.0319)(0.0153)(0.0104)(0.0233)(0.0235)(0.0142)(0.0170)
log social connectedness0.312***0.230***0.109***−0.0275*0.226***0.145***0.0806***
(0.0258)(0.0122)(0.00893)(0.0156)(0.0158)(0.00998)(0.0123)
Observations63,09663,09663,09663,096621,816621,816621,816
R-squared0.6380.7860.4240.5830.6870.4340.718
Fixed effectsProductProductProductProductFirmFirmFirm

Notes: Standard errors, clustered in the country |$\times$| HS2 chapter dimension, are in parentheses, with |$^{***}$| and |$^{*}$|⁠, respectively, denoting significance at the 1% and 10% levels. “log Distance” is the log of the weighted distance between France and the destination. “log Import demand” is the log of the value of the destination’s demand of imports for the hs6–product, less the demand addressed to France. “log GDP per capita” is the log-GDP per capita in the destination. “log French migrants” is the log of the number of French migrants per 1,000 of inhabitants in the destination country. log social connectedness is the log of the social connectedness between France the destination as measured by Bailey et al. (2021) using anonymized Facebook data. The dependent variable is either the log of product-level French exports in the destination (column (1)) or one of its components, namely, the number of sellers involved in the trade flow (column (2)), the mean number of buyers they serve (column (3)), and the mean value of a seller–buyer transaction (column (4)). Column (5) uses the log of firm-level bilateral exports as left-hand side variable, whereas columns (6) and (7) use one of its components, the number of buyers served (column (6)), or the value of exports per buyer (column (7)).

Acknowledgments

The paper has benefited from insightful comments by participants at the seminars at the Graduate Institute in Geneva, Bocconi University, Warwick University, LSE, the University of Cergy-Pontoise, Paris School of Economics, CREST, Yale-PhD Seminar, GSIE, RIEF, and ETSG. We are particularly indebted to Andrew Bernard, Tibor Besedes, Adrien Bilal, Johannes Boehm, Thomas Chaney, Edouard Chretien, Arnaud Costinot, Gregory Corcos, Jonathan Eaton, François Fontaine, Etienne Lalé, Sam Kortum, Francis Kramarz, Kalina Manova, Thierry Mayer, Andreas Moxnes, Mathieu Parenti, Gianmarco Ottaviano, Sophie Osotimehin, Frédéric Robert-Nicoud, and Esteban Rossi-Hansberg, who provided feedbacks at various stages of the project. This project has received funding from the European Research Council (ERC) under the European Union’s Horizon 2020 research and innovation programme (grant agreement No 714597). Martin is a Research Affiliate at CREST and CEPR. Mejean is a Research Fellow at CEPR.

Notes

The editor in charge of this paper was Giovanni Peri.

Footnotes

1.

Luttmer (2006) discusses the role of the customer base as a determinant of firms’ size. Arkolakis (2010) focuses on the impact of penetration costs associated with acquiring additional consumers on trade patterns. The impact of frictions is studied in various recent contributions, in the trade and macroeconomic literature. Perla (2019) shows how information frictions can impede customer acquisition and thus firms’ growth. Drozd and Nosal (2012) discuss how frictions affecting the building of market shares can explain the dynamics of international prices. Gourio and Rudanko (2014) use statistics on the size of marketing expenditures at the firm level as evidence of search frictions in product markets and study their consequences for the dynamics of firms. In a business-to-business trade context, asymmetric information on market conditions (Allen 2014) or the seller’s reliability (Macchiavello and Morjaria 2015) has been argued to affect firms’ pricing and quantity decisions.

2.

See Hopenhayn (2014) for a review of the related literature. Among the distortions that are extensively discussed in the empirical and theoretical literature, one can cite regulations (Garicano, Lelarge, and Reenen 2016), financial constraints (Midrigan and Xu 2014), or—closer to our paper—information frictions (David, Hopenhayn, and Venkateswaran 2016).

3.

Unlike Antràs, Fort, and Tintelnot (2017), our model abstracts from (ex-ante) buyers heterogeneity, and we assume there is no fixed cost of outsourcing. The selection of importers into different importing strategies is explained by the heterogeneity in the set of suppliers met by each buyer.

4.

This result is consistent with evidence in the gravity literature, which uses dyadic proxies for information frictions and finds their impact on the geography of bilateral trade is significant. See, among others, Head and Mayer (2014), Rauch (1999), and Rauch (2001).

5.

We show in Online Appendix that this prediction survives an extension of the model in which high-productivity firms display relatively high matching probabilities provided the extension preserves the log-supermodularity of export probabilities with respect to search frictions and the firm’s productivity. It is the case under realistic parametric assumptions.

6.

This statement may seem to contradict Melitz’s (2003)) result that a decrease in trade barriers improves the allocative efficiency by shifting resources from low- to high-productivity firms. The discrepancy comes from the fact that Melitz (2003) focuses on multilateral trade liberalization, whereas our thought experiment considers a unilateral decrease in trade barriers. Reducing the cost of serving foreign markets without easing the entry of foreign exporters into the domestic economy increases the competitiveness of all domestic firms abroad, which benefits infra-marginal firms that can pass the threshold for profitable exports.

7.

In our framework, the effect of friction is ambiguous at the individual level but not at the aggregate level. See Petropoulou (2011) for a model where search frictions may have a non-monotonic impact on aggregate trade flows.

8.

Our analysis, however, displays a notable difference in comparison with the previous literature. Once we condition on a particular product being traded, we indeed show that 90% of importers in our data source a given product from a single French exporter. Instead, the overall number of French sellers they are connected to is often above one as importers tend to source several products from several French firms.

9.

Our paper also displays important differences in the modeling of the matching of sellers and buyers, in comparison with Eaton, Kortum, and Kramarz (2022). To our knowledge, our paper is the first to extend the Ricardian analysis in Eaton and Kortum (2002) to a discrete setting. In doing so, we follow the logic introduced in Eaton, Kortum, and Sotelo (2012) to study how a discrete number of sellers affect predictions of the Melitz (2003) model. Working with a discrete number of firms allows the model to have Eaton and Kortum (2002) as a limit case when search frictions become infinitely small.

10.

Online Appendix Figure D.1 suggests that the restriction is unlikely to affect our results. The distribution of sellers’ degrees, whose product-specific equivalent is used to compute the empirical moments in the estimation, is indeed almost identical in the whole sample and in the sample restricted to the 70% of exporters that declare a product category.

11.

These facts are robust to alternatively defining the customer base as the number of buyers a seller interacts with over a 3-year window or the number of buyers interacting more than once with the seller over a 3-year window.

12.

This stands in contrast with respect to the previous literature exploiting similar data (Bernard, Moxnes, and Ulltveit-Moe 2018b), which points to the two-sided heterogeneity in the connectedness of firms involved in international markets. As shown by the comparison of the two lines in Figure A.1, the heterogeneity on the side of foreign importers is more pronounced when importers’ purchases are pooled across products. As our objective is to estimate search frictions at the product-level, both our model and empirical strategy are going to condition the structure of the matching on a particular product and will thus exploit the many-to-one structure of the matching. As discussed in Fontaine, Martin, and Mejean (2021), it is straightforward to account for multi-product importers using the same setting by assuming buyers combine individual products within their production function.

13.

Note the contribution of the buyer margin is artificially low in the decomposition of product-level trade in columns (1)–(4) because of the multicolinearity between the “seller” and “buyer” extensive margins. If we instead work with this decomposition, then

which treats sellers and buyers symmetrically, the distance elasticity is found to be larger on the buyer than the seller margin (i.e. |$|d\ln \#^B_{pd}/d\ln {{Dist}}_d|>|d\ln \#^S_{pd}/d\ln {{Dist}}_d|$|⁠).

14.

In the trade literature, equation (2) is used to estimate the elasticity of trade to iceberg costs (⁠|$\theta$|⁠). Equation (2) shows unbiased estimates of trade elasticities can be recovered if and only if instruments for iceberg costs are uncorrelated with search frictions.

15.

Proposition 1 shares some similarity with results in Dasgupta and Mondria (2018), who also establish a correlation between the distribution of trade and search frictions. The objects of interest and nature of trade frictions are, however, quite different in ours and their models. The non-monotonicity discussed in Proposition 1 also has a similar flavor than Lemma 1 in Ornelas, Turner, and Bickwit (2021), where contract incompleteness affects disproportionally the most productive suppliers.

16.

This intuition is confirmed by estimates in Eaton, Kortum, and Kramarz (2022), who use a more flexible matching technology and estimate low-cost firms to be more visible in international markets, on average.

17.

Quantifying the general equilibrium impact of search frictions would notably require to estimate product-level bilateral search frictions faced by producers from the rest of the world, which is not possible based on our empirical strategy.

18.

The same is true of a slightly modified version of the frictionless Eaton and Kortum (2002) model in which productivity would be drawn from a Fréchet distribution displaying a bilateral scale parameter as in |$F_{ij}(z)=Pr[Z_{ij}\le z]=e^{-T_{ij}z^{-\theta }}$|⁠, where |$Z_{ij}$| denotes the random productivity drawn by sellers in j to serve market i. In such model, the distribution of prices in country i becomes |$G_i(p)=1-e^{-p^\theta \sum _j T_{ij} (w_j d_{ij})^{-\theta }}$|⁠, which is the same expression as in our baseline model for |$T_{ij}=\lambda _{ij}T_j$|⁠. In this variant of the Eaton and Kortum (2002) model, the ex-post distribution of active exporters within each country is still degenerated though, whereas our model exploits predictions for export probabilities along the distribution of firms’ productivity.

19.

Integrating over the expected distribution of productivities amounts to neglecting additional distortions induced by the assumption of a discrete number of French suppliers. With a discrete and finite number of French suppliers, the ex-ante Pareto distribution of productivities does not exactly coincide with the ex-post distribution of productivities. We neglect this discrepancy and derive a distribution of the number of buyers per firm, whose shape solely depends on search frictions. This assumption is innocuous as long as the number of potential suppliers of the product is large enough, which is the case in practice in the data.

20.

More details on the set of convergent moments that could be used to identify search frictions and the reasoning beyond our choice of this particular moment are provided in Online Appendix C. Our approach favored (i) moments that vary monotonously with the structural parameter of interest, and (ii) moments that are empirically correlated with our proxy for search frictions while being uncorrelated with distance from France to avoid any confounding factor coming from iceberg costs.

21.

As shown in Figure 1 (left panel), most of the variance in the number of buyers served by French exporters is indeed found at values for |$B_{ij}(z_{s_j})$| below 10. Using all the individual moments regarding the number of firms with |$B_{ij}(z_{s_j})>10$| clients would thus be inefficient and would artificially reduce the dispersion in the data, in a way that is not independent from |$B_i$|⁠.

22.

|$\Omega _{i}^k=\triangledown g(\lambda _{i}^k) \Sigma _{i}^k \triangledown ^{\prime } g(\lambda _{ij})$|⁠, where g is the variance function and |$\Sigma _{i}^k$| is the variance–covariance matrix of the random variables |$\mathbb {1}\lbrace B_i^k(z)=M\rbrace$| for |$M=m_1,m_2,m_3$|⁠.

23.

We use bilateral trade flows from the CEPII-BACI database (Gaulier and Zignago 2010) and production data from the World Input–Output Database. |$\pi _{i}^k$| is defined as the ratio of bilateral trade from France to country i over absorption in country i.

24.

In sectors and countries in which the market share of French firms is very low, our empirical strategy implies very high values for |$B_{i}^k$|⁠, above a million firms. Such high values might artificially bias our estimation of |$\lambda _{i}^k$| down. To avoid this issue, we winsorized the number of potential buyers at the 95th percentile of each country-specific distribution. The winsorizing is relatively homogenous across sectors, except for three exceptions. The share of winsorized product |$\times$| country pairs is slightly larger in chapters 49 (printed books), 69 (ceramic products), and 71 (precious and semi-precious stones), for which we measure a relatively low share of foreign products in absorption despite the number of French exporters being significant.

25.

The correlation with country size may also emerge if firms are constrained in their capacity to serve a large number of buyers.

26.

More precisely, we use the estimated |$\lambda _{i}^k$| coefficients to predict the share of exporters serving a given number of buyers, in each destination and product. These shares are then aggregated across products and countries using information on the relative number of suppliers of each product in France.

27.

The negative correlation would be reinforced if meeting probabilities were endogenous. If firms could invest in decreasing frictions, then they should invest in markets in which they have a comparative advantage. The positive correlation recovered from the data suggests that this force, if it exists, is not strong enough to counteract the unconditional relationship between search frictions and comparative advantages.

28.

The correlation is also consistent with alternative models related to Melitz (2003) that feature heterogeneous firms’ export performances along the productivity distribution. Closer to this paper, the model of two-sided heterogeneity in Bernard, Moxnes, and Ulltveit-Moe (2018b) also predicts a positive relationship between a firm’s productivity and the number of its foreign partners.

29.

One may be concerned that the correlation is somewhat built-in as both the regressions in Table 5, and the estimation of search frictions exploit the dispersion in export performances across firms in a particular market. Whereas it is true that there is a link between both objects, the relationship between estimated frictions and the size of large firms’ export premium is never used in the structural estimation, thus offering a non-targeted moment that can be exploited to test this prediction of our model.

30.

Because both estimated frictions and comparative advantages are heterogeneous, the homogenous shift has heterogeneous consequences across product and country pairs. We thus run the counterfactual for all markets separately, before aggregating across markets based on the number of potential exporters.

31.

By definition, the mean productivity of exporters writes

where |$f(z)={\theta \underline{z}^\theta }/{z^{\theta +1}}$| is the density of z and |$\mathbb {P}({{Export}}|z)=1-(1-\rho _i^k(z))^{B_i^k}$| is the probability of exporting conditional on z. After some simplifications, the change in the productivity of exporters in the counterfactual state of the economy, in relative terms with the benchmark, becomes
(12)
where the |$^c$| superscript refers to the counterfactual state. After discretizing the productivity space in percentiles, this formula can be used, together with a calibrated value for |$\theta$|⁠, to recover the change in the mean productivity of exporters. For |$\theta =3$|⁠, the overall productivity improvement is found to be 9.34%, a value that is reduced to 5.43% for |$\theta =5$|⁠.

References

Akerman
Anders
,
Leuven
Edwin
,
Mogstad
Magne
(
2022
).
“Information Frictions, Internet and the Relationship between Distance and Trade.”
American Economic Journal: Applied Economics
,
14
(1),
133
163
.

Allen
Treb
(
2014
).
“Information Frictions in Trade
.”
Econometrica
,
82
,
2041
2083
.

Antràs
Pol
,
Chor
Davin
,
Fally
Thibault
,
Hillberry
Russell
(
2012
).
“Measuring the Upstreamness of Production and Trade Flows
.”
American Economic Review
,
102
(
3
),
412
416
.

Antràs
Pol
,
Fort
Teresa C.
,
Tintelnot
Felix
(
2017
).
“The Margins of Global Sourcing: Theory and Evidence from US Firms
.”
American Economic Review
,
107
(
9
),
2514
2564
.

Arkolakis
Costas
(
2010
).
“Market Penetration Costs and the New Consumers Margin in International Trade
.”
Journal of Political Economy
,
118
,
1151
1199
.

Arkolakis
Costas
,
Costinot
Arnaud
,
Rodrìguez-Clare
Andrés
(
2012
).
“New Trade Models, Same Old Gains?”
American Economic Review
,
102
(
1
),
94
130
.

Atalay
Enghin
,
Hortacsu
Ali
,
Syverson
Chad
(
2014
).
“Vertical Integration and Input Flows
.”
American Economic Review
,
104
(
4
),
1120
1148
.

Atkeson
Andrew
,
Burstein
Ariel
(
2008
).
“Pricing-to-Market, Trade Costs, and International Relative Prices
.”
American Economic Review
,
98
(
5
),
1998
2031
.

Bailey
Michael
,
Gupta
Abhinav
,
Hillenbrand
Sebastian
,
Kuchler
Theresa
,
Richmond
Robert J.
,
Stroebel
Johannes
(
2021
).
“International Trade and Social Connectedness.”
Journal of International Economics
,
129
(
C
).

Bergounhon
Flora
,
Lenoir
Clémence
,
Mejean
Isabelle
(
2018
).
“A Guideline to French Firm-Level Trade Data.”
mimeo
. https://isabellemejean.com/BergounhonLenoirMejean_2018.pdf.

Bernard
Andrew B.
,
Eaton
Jonathan
,
Bradford Jensen
J.
,
Kortum
Samuel
(
2003
).
“Plants and Productivity in International Trade
.”
American Economic Review
,
93
(
4
),
1268
1290
.

Bernard
Andrew B.
,
Moxnes
Andreas
,
Saito
Yukiko U.
(
2018a
).
“Production Networks, Geography and Firm Performance.”
Journal of Political Economy
,
130
(
7
),
1765
1804
.

Bernard
Andrew B.
,
Moxnes
Andreas
,
Helene Ulltveit-Moe
Karen
(
2018b
).
“Two-Sided Heterogeneity and Trade
.”
Review of Economics and Statistics
,
100
,
424
439
.

Carballo
Jernimo
,
Ottaviano
Gianmarco
,
Volpe Martincus
Christian
(
2018
).
“The Buyer Margins of Firms’ Exports
.”
Journal of International Economics
,
112
,
33
49
.

Chaney
Thomas
(
2014
).
“The Network Structure of International Trade
.”
American Economic Review
,
104
(
11
),
3600
3634
.

Chen
Maggie X.
,
Wu
Min
(
2021
).
“The Value of Reputation in Trade: Evidence from Alibaba
.”
The Review of Economics and Statistics
,
103
,
857
873
.

Costinot
Arnaud
,
Donaldson
Dave
,
Komunjer
Ivana
(
2012
).
“What Goods Do Countries Trade? A Quantitative Exploration of Ricardo’s Ideas
.”
Review of Economic Studies
,
79
,
581
608
.

Dasgupta
Kunal
,
Mondria
Jordi
(
2018
).
“Inattentive Importers
.”
Journal of International Economics
,
112
,
150
165
.

David
Joel M.
,
Hopenhayn
Hugo A.
,
Venkateswaran
Venky
(
2016
).
“Information, Misallocation, and Aggregate Productivity
.”
Quarterly Journal of Economics
,
131
,
943
1005
.

Drazanova
Lenka
(
2020
).
“Introducing the Historical Index of Ethnic Fractionalization (HIEF) Dataset: Accounting for Longitudinal Changes in Ethnic Diversity
.”
Journal of Open Humanities Data
,
6
,
6
.

Drozd
Lukasz A.
,
Nosal
Jaromir B.
(
2012
).
“Understanding International Prices: Customers as Capital
.”
American Economic Review
,
102
(
1
),
364
395
.

Eaton
Jonathan
,
Kortum
Samuel
(
2002
).
“Technology, Geography, and Trade
.”
Econometrica
,
70
,
1741
1779
.

Eaton
Jonathan
,
Kortum
Samuel
,
Kramarz
Francis
(
2022
).
“Firm-to-Firm Trade: Imports, Exports, and the Labor Market.”
NBER Working Paper No. 29685
.

Eaton
Jonathan
,
Kortum
Samuel S.
,
Sotelo
Sebastian
(
2012
).
International Trade: Linking Micro and Macro
,
Advances in Economics and Econometrics: Tenth World Congress, Vol. II. Applied Economics
.
Cambridge University Press

Fontaine
Francois
,
Martin
Julien
,
Mejean
Isabelle
(
2021
).
“Frictions and Adjustments in Firm-to-Firm Trade.”
mimeo
. https://isabellemejean.com/FMM2.pdf.

Garicano
Luis
,
Lelarge
Claire
,
Van Reenen
John
(
2016
).
“Firm Size Distortions and the Productivity Distribution: Evidence from France
.”
American Economic Review
,
106
(
11
),
3439
3479
.

Gaubert
Cecile
,
Itskhoki
Oleg
(
2021
).
“Granular Comparative Advantage.”
Journal of Political Economy
,
129
(
3
),
871
939
.

Gaulier
Guillaume
,
Zignago
Soledad
(
2010
).
“BACI: International Trade Database at the Product-Level. The 1994-2007 Version.”
CEPII Working Paper No. 2010-23
.

Gourio
Franois
,
Rudanko
Leena
(
2014
).
“Customer Capital
.”
Review of Economic Studies
,
81
,
1102
1136
.

Head
Keith
,
Mayer
Thierry
(
2014
).
Gravity Equations: Workhorse,Toolkit, and Cookbook
,
Handbook of International Economics
, Vol.
4
,
Chap. 0
,
Elsevier
, pp.
131
195
.

Hopenhayn
Hugo A.
(
2014
).
“Firms, Misallocation, and Aggregate Productivity: A Review
.”
Annual Review of Economics
,
6
,
735
770
.

Imbs
Jean
,
Mejean
Isabelle
(
2015
).
“Elasticity Optimism
.”
American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics
,
7
,
43
83
.

Khandelwal
Amit
(
2010
).
“The Long and Short (of) Quality Ladders
.”
Review of Economic Studies
,
77
,
1450
1476
.

Krolikowski
Pawel
,
McCallum
Andrew
(
2021
).
“Goods-Market Frictions and International Trade.”
Journal of International Economics
,
129(C)
.

Lendle
Andreas
,
Olarreaga
Marcelo
,
Schropp
Simon
,
Vézina
Pierre-Louis
(
2016
).
“There Goes Gravity: How eBay Reduces Trade Costs
.”
The Economic Journal
,
126
,
406
441
.

Luttmer
Erzo G. J.
(
2006
).
“Consumer Search and Firm Growth.”
Working Paper No. 645
,
Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis
.

Macchiavello
Rocco
,
Morjaria
Ameet
(
2015
).
“The Value of Relationships: Evidence from a Supply Shock to Kenyan Rose Exports
.”
American Economic Review
,
105
(
9
),
2911
2945
.

Mayer
Thierry
,
Zignago
Soledad
(
2011
).
“Notes on CEPII’s Distances Measures : the GeoDist Database.”
CEPII Working Paper No. 2011-25
.

Melitz
Marc J.
(
2003
).
“The Impact of Trade on Intra-Industry Reallocations and Aggregate Industry Productivity
.”
Econometrica
,
71
,
1695
1725
.

Melitz
Jacques
,
Toubal
Farid
(
2014
).
“Native Language, Spoken Language, Translation and Trade
.”
Journal of International Economics
,
93
,
351
363
.

Midrigan
Virgiliu
,
Yi Xu
Daniel
(
2014
).
“Finance and Misallocation: Evidence from Plant-Level Data
.”
American Economic Review
,
104
(
2
),
422
458
.

Nunn
Nathan
(
2007
).
“Relationship-Specificity, Incomplete Contracts, and the Pattern of Trade
.”
Quarterly Journal of Economics
,
122
,
569
600
.

Ornelas
Emanuel
,
Turner
John L.
,
Bickwit
Grant
(
2021
).
“Preferential Trade Agreements and Global Sourcing
.”
Journal of International Economics
,
128
,
103395
.

Perla
Jesse
(
2019
).
“A Model of Product Awareness and Industry Life Cycles.”
Working paper
,
R R (2nd Round) at Econometrica
.

Petropoulou
Dimitra
(
2011
).
“Information Costs, Networks and Intermediation in International Trade.”
Globalization Institute Working Paper No. 76
,
Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas
.

Rauch
James E.
(
1999
).
“Networks Versus Markets in International Trade
.”
Journal of International Economics
,
48
,
7
35
.

Rauch
James E.
(
2001
).
“Business and Social Networks in International Trade
.”
Journal of Economic Literature
,
39
,
1177
1203
.

Steinwender
Claudia
(
2018
).
“Information Frictions and the Law of One Price: When the States and the Kingdom became United
.”
American Economic Review
,
108
(
3
),
657
696
.

This is an Open Access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial License (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc/4.0/), which permits non-commercial re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited. For commercial re-use, please contact [email protected]