-
PDF
- Split View
-
Views
-
Cite
Cite
Alice Pirlot, Carbon Border Adjustment Measures: A Straightforward Multi-Purpose Climate Change Instrument?, Journal of Environmental Law, Volume 34, Issue 1, March 2022, Pages 25–52, https://doi.org/10.1093/jel/eqab028
- Share Icon Share
Abstract
Carbon border adjustment measures (CBAMs) are instruments that can be used to mitigate climate change, but also have a positive impact on trade, climate leadership and even public finance. In this article, I challenge the view that they can serve as straightforward multi-purpose instruments. In a first step, I analyse each of the purposes that can be achieved through CBAMs and explain their underlying differences. In a second step, I discuss their legal design and explain how CBAMs’ design features affect the types of purposes that they can achieve. I apply this two-step analytical framework to the European Union context, where a proposal for a regulation establishing a CBAM has been published by the European Commission in July 2021. I demonstrate that the design of the EU CBAM is inconsistent with the Commission’s main objectives of promoting fair competition and climate mitigation in line with the Paris Agreement. The EU CBAM proposal is primarily an instrument of climate leadership.
1. INTRODUCTION
In the legal and policy discourse, multiple purposes have been attached to carbon border adjustment measures (CBAMs), including the prevention of carbon leakage, the promotion of compliance with the Paris Agreement, the development of climate leadership, the internalisation of emissions in the country of consumption and the generation of revenue.1 Whilst these different purposes might appear mutually supportive at first sight, I argue that they are not fully reconcilable. Presenting them as such gives the wrong impression that CBAMs are a ‘straightforward and uniform regulatory strategy’ to mitigate climate change.2 It also hides the difficult design choices that underlie the adoption of CBAMs and can compromise their effectiveness.3 Instead of being viewed as straightforward and uniform, I argue that the concept of CBAM should be understood as an umbrella term encompassing a wide range of measures, which can each achieve different types of purposes depending on their specific legal design. To make this point, I proceed in two steps, which together form a two-step analytical framework that I use to explore CBAMs’ role and legal design.
First, I discuss each of the different purposes that have been attached to CBAMs and highlight their underlying differences (Section 2). My goal is to illuminate CBAMs’ regulatory complexity by clarifying the story linked to each of their purposes. By story, I mean the combination of facts and events that policymakers and legal scholars—as storytellers4—put forward to explain the problems that CBAMs are supposed to solve. I start with the traditional objective that economists attach to CBAMs, namely their role in addressing carbon leakage risks and fostering fair competition, which I explain as part of what I call the ‘fair competition story’. Then, I analyse the other purposes that have been attached to CBAMs in the legal and policy discourse: the role of CBAMs in promoting compliance with the Paris Agreement (under the so-called ‘Paris Agreement story’), the role of CBAMs as an instrument of climate leadership for the implementing country (under the so-called ‘climate leadership story’), the role of CBAMs in internalising greenhouse gas emissions linked to consumption (under the so-called ‘consumption-based story’) and the budgetary objective of CBAMs (under the so-called ‘budgetary story’). I show that these stories, except for the latter, are hard to reconcile, if not irreconcilable, because they rely on different assumptions about the type of mitigation strategy that should guide countries’ climate action. This step of my analysis thus gives a first indication that CBAMs cannot serve as straightforward multi-purpose climate change instruments.
The second step of my analysis confirms this reasoning by exploring the links between CBAMs’ purposes and their legal design. I understand the term ‘legal design’ to be in reference to the role of lawyers as architects who translate political ideas into legal provisions. I am interested in CBAMs’ design features (Section 3): the types of products and emissions on which they will be imposed; their relationship to carbon taxes and emissions trading schemes; and the system used to allocate their revenue. In the literature, these design elements have often been discussed in the context of how they would influence the compatibility of CBAMs with the law of the World Trade Organisation (WTO).5 In this context, authors have proposed design options that they consider more likely to be compatible with the General Agreements on Tariffs and Trade and the Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures.6 For example, according to some authors, the use of CBAMs’ revenue to support environmental projects in developing countries could make them less prone to being found incompatible with WTO law.7 In this article, I proceed differently (Section 4). I examine how different design choices can be influenced by the purpose of a future CBAM (rather than by the legal constraints of international trade law). What would be the design features of a CBAM aimed at addressing carbon leakage risks? Would it be different if CBAMs’ primary purpose was to foster compliance with the Paris Agreement, promote the climate leadership of the implementing country or internalise greenhouse gas emissions linked to consumption? By answering these questions, I explain how the pursuit of each of the purposes attached to CBAMs will translate into different choices in terms of legal design. From this it follows that a lack of clarity on CBAM’s main purpose and expected effects prevents the making of the right design choices. Moreover, it implies that CBAMs’ legal design affects the types of purposes that they can achieve, and thus their effectiveness.
I apply this two-step reasoning to the development of CBAMs in the context of the European Union (EU). This context is relevant as the European Commission proposed the adoption of CBAMs in 2019 as part of its plan to become the first climate-neutral continent by 2050 (the so-called ‘European Green Deal’).8 The Commission published its CBAMs’ proposal in July 2021 along other proposals to achieve its climate-neutrality objective.9 If adopted, the EU CBAMs would require importers of certain energy-intensive products (such as cement, iron and steel, aluminium, fertilisers and electricity) to pay a carbon price equivalent to the price imposed in the EU through the EU Emissions Trading System (ETS) as of January 2026.10 In addition to the current policy relevance of the EU proposal, my choice to focus on the EU context lies in the need to contextualise this work. Unless CBAMs are assessed within a specific legal context, it is difficult—if not impossible—to discuss how their primary purpose will translate into specific legal provisions, which themselves will limit the other purposes that CBAMs can achieve. First, I use the EU context to provide concrete examples of each of the purposes attached to CBAMs in the policy discourse (Section 2). Where relevant, I explain how these examples relate to the policy discourse in other jurisdictions, including the USA. Secondly, I dissect the legal design of the Commission’s proposal (Section 3) and explain how it interacts with its regulatory purpose (Section 4). I show that the Commission’s proposal is characterised by a significant inconsistency between its stated goals and its legal design, which risks making the European CBAMs ineffective. The legal design proposed for the future European CBAMs suggests that its primary goal is to promote the EU’s climate leadership rather than—as stated by the Commission—fostering fair competition and supporting climate mitigation in line with the Paris Agreement (Section 5). The Commission’s proposal is thus likely to be less effective—if not, ineffective—at achieving these latter purposes.
This article is structured as follows: Section 2 provides an overview of the different purposes attached to CBAMs. Section 3 discusses the main building blocks of CBAM’s legal design. Section 4 examines the interaction between CBAMs’ purpose and their legal design. Section 5 argues that the EU’s proposal for a CBAM is primarily an instrument of climate leadership. Finally, Section 6 concludes.
2. THE LEGAL AND POLICY DISCOURSE ON CBAMS
This section corresponds to the first step of my two-step analytical framework for analysing CBAMs’ purpose and legal design. It explains how multiple purposes have been attached to CBAMs in the legal and policy discourse. Traditionally, CBAMs are described as a regulatory strategy to mitigate the risks of carbon leakage and loss of competitiveness associated with the unilateral adoption of carbon pricing policies. Moreover, other objectives have been attached to CBAMs, including the objectives of fostering compliance with the Paris Agreement, serving as a tool of climate leadership, internalising the greenhouse gas emissions linked to consumption and generating revenue. Except for the latter, all these different objectives directly relate to the ultimate objective of maintaining the increase of global average temperature below an acceptable level. This might explain why they all seem interconnected and mutually supportive. This section takes a close look at each of these purposes separately and highlights how they differ from each other.
2.1 The Fair Competition Story
Proposals in favour of CBAMs have always been part of the legal and policy debate on carbon pricing instruments.11 Carbon pricing instruments, including emissions trading schemes (such as the EU ETS) and tax instruments (such as carbon taxes), are often thought to lead to carbon leakage and a loss of competitiveness for domestic enterprises.12 Under the fair competition story, CBAMs are presented as an innovative solution to mitigate these risks, which are inherent to a world where jurisdictions have not (yet) agreed on the adoption of a global carbon price.13 The implicit assumption underlying the fair competition story is that carbon pricing should ideally be ‘universal’.14 The lack of a universal carbon price justifies the introduction of CBAMs.
Carbon leakage risks are associated with concerns that the reduction of greenhouse gas emissions in countries imposing a carbon price on their domestic firms will lead to an increase of greenhouse gas emissions abroad.15 For example, such a domestic carbon price could encourage domestic enterprises to relocate or outsource their carbon-intensive activities to jurisdictions with no carbon pricing scheme in place. Carbon leakage risks could also materialise when carbon pricing makes carbon-intensive domestic products less competitive, which can lead to a higher demand for foreign products with a high carbon value. The underlying assumption is that carbon-intensive products made in countries with no (or a relatively low) carbon price in place will become relatively cheaper. Carbon leakage will damage the integrity of domestic carbon pricing measures if it leads to the generation of more emissions at the worldwide level than would have been emitted in the absence of domestic climate action. In a 2019 World Group Report, this is described as a ‘lose-lose: a loss of competitiveness or economic activity without an environmental gain’.16 When carbon leakage is limited in scope, the reduction in the global emissions level achieved through the domestic carbon price will be less than anticipated but it will not lead to perverse environmental effects (increasing instead of decreasing the global level of emissions). In this hypothesis, the main negative effect of carbon leakage is on trade: Domestic enterprises will lose competitiveness on the global market.
So far, carbon leakage risks have been mitigated by softening carbon pricing rules and levelling down carbon costs.17 For example, in the context of the EU ETS, sectors considered at risk of carbon leakage have been granted free allowances.18 Similarly, countries with carbon tax measures often grant tax exemptions or tax reductions to energy-intensive sectors in order to limit the potentially negative effects of the carbon tax on their competitiveness.19 CBAMs are thought to pursue a similar objective but they proceed differently. Whereas free allowances and tax exemptions completely mute the carbon price signal, CBAMs level up carbon costs for foreign producers and maintain their application on domestic firms, except when they export their products abroad.20 By including imports into carbon pricing mechanisms and by excluding exports, CBAMs are supposed to level the playing field between domestic and foreign products. From an environmental point of view, these measures are justified if they lead to higher emissions reduction levels than could have been achieved otherwise.
Although the economic literature on the effects of CBAMs remains divided,21 it is fair to say that the legal scholarship often presents CBAMs as a regulatory strategy that allows countries to introduce a strong carbon price across sectors while avoiding the unfair trade effects linked to such ambitious carbon pricing policy.22 For example, Mehling and his co-authors describe CBAMs as a ‘promising response to leakage’.23 Under this narrative, CBAMs are part of a suite of instruments that countries use to promote what they would describe as ‘fair competition’. If countries subject their own enterprises to a carbon price, it is considered fair that they also subject imported products from foreign enterprises to an identical carbon price through border adjustments on imports. Similarly, border adjustments on exports, used to relieve exported products of the carbon price, are justified by the objective of permitting domestic enterprises to compete fairly on the world market.
Fair competition is also a key element of the policy discourse on CBAMs, including in the EU context. For example, in 2008–09, the EU Commission introduced the idea of a ‘carbon equalisation system’, which could be used to mitigate the risk of carbon leakage as part of its carbon pricing strategy.24 In 2017, during discussions on the EU ETS, the European Parliament underlined that, in case of a significant risk of carbon leakage, the ‘Commission shall, if appropriate, come forward with a legislative proposal introducing a carbon border adjustment (…)’.25 The European Green Deal pursues a similar approach. In its communication from December 2019, the Commission described the CBAM as ‘an alternative to the measures that address the risk of carbon leakage in the EU’s Emissions Trading System’, such as the free allocation of emission allowances.26 In her State of the Union Address, von der Leyen also emphasised the role of the CBAM in ensuring a level playing field between EU and foreign producers, referring to both ‘just globalisation’ and ‘fairness’.27 The Commission’s proposal for a regulation establishing a CBAM confirms this approach: Its main objective is ‘to prevent the risk of carbon leakage’.28 The same justification has been used by the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD), which describes CBAMs as ‘one of the policy options’ that countries could use for ‘minimising adverse carbon leakage, while ensuring their fairness by dampening any negative competitiveness effects’.29 Similarly, the administration of President Biden has been reported to consider a CBAM as part of the US trade agenda and the Canadian government has expressed its commitment to considering the use of border carbon adjustments as part of a ‘strategy to meet climate targets while ensuring a fair environment for businesses’.30
It is worth noting that some countries oppose the fair competition story, which they describe as ‘green protectionism’.31 They argue that CBAMs act as an obstacle to trade by allowing countries to protect their domestic enterprises from the negative economic consequences caused by their own ambitious climate policies. This explains the important legal debate on CBAMs’ compatibility with WTO law.32 Beyond this debate, it seems that the consideration that CBAMs lead to fair (or unfair) competition is linked to different views on the need for a global carbon price. CBAMs will be perceived as fair by those who accept the assumption that all economic activities—regardless of where they are located—should be subject to a uniform carbon price. In the absence of such a global carbon price, CBAMs are viewed as helping to preserve countries’ ability to adopt ambitious climate policies. In contrast, CBAMs will be considered unfair by those who reject this assumption, for example because they believe that countries, more specifically least developed and developing countries, should remain free to adopt a relatively lower carbon price, if they decide to adopt such a mechanism at all. CBAMs will be viewed as restricting these countries’ freedom by imposing an unwanted carbon price on the products that these countries export to jurisdictions with a CBAM in place.
2.2 The Paris Agreement Story
The fair competition story is not the only story involving CBAMs. One of the other stories in which CBAMs are thought to play an important role is the Paris Agreement story. Under this story, CBAMs are supposed to foster global compliance with the Paris Agreement, which is assumed to be the most suitable strategy to mitigate climate change.
Among other objectives, the Paris Agreement aims at ‘holding the increase in global average temperature to well below 2°C above pre-industrial levels and pursuing efforts to limit the temperature increase to 1.5°C above pre-industrial levels’.33 To achieve this temperature target,34 the Paris Agreement relies on the ‘principle of common but differentiated responsibilities and respective capabilities’ and requires its Parties to ‘pursue domestic mitigation measures’.35 The Paris Agreement does not oblige its Parties to adopt specific mitigation measures: Countries can choose which commitments contribute to their ‘highest possible ambition (…), in the light of [their] different national circumstances’.36 In this context, CBAMs are supposed to serve as a stick with which to beat ‘non-cooperative countries’, namely those countries whose commitments to mitigating climate change are not in line with the ‘normative expectations of “progression” and “highest possible ambition”’37 laid down in the Paris Agreement.38
This specific objective has been mentioned both in the EU (as part of the ‘ancillary effects’ of the Commission’s proposal39) and in the USA, as part of President Biden’s tax and trade strategy.40 Interestingly, the Commission and the European Parliament also refer to CBAMs’ essential role in allowing the EU to become climate-neutral by 2050 ‘in line with the Paris Agreement’.41 Such reference to the Paris Agreement is both confusing and problematic. It is confusing because it does not relate to the role of CBAMs in fostering global compliance with the Paris Agreement. Instead, it relates to the role of CBAMs in allowing the EU to address carbon leakage risks and, thus, increase its ambition in terms of carbon price. This objective corresponds to the fair competition story. In this context, the reference to the Paris Agreement is problematic because the use of CBAMs to promote fair competition—which enables the EU to meet its commitments in terms of climate neutrality42—is inconsistent with the approach of the Paris Agreement and irreconcilable with the Paris Agreement story.
Although the ultimate objective of both the fair competition and the Paris Agreement stories is to limit the increase in global average temperature, these two stories rely on radically different approaches to climate mitigation. Whereas the fair competition story is based on the idea that CBAMs are necessary due to the absence of a ‘harmonized, global carbon price’,43 the Paris Agreement story accommodates differences in carbon prices across jurisdictions.44 Under the Paris Agreement story, carbon leakage only becomes unacceptable when it takes place in favour of countries whose climate commitments are not deemed sufficiently ambitious in the light of their national circumstances. In other words, the relocation of some energy-intensive activities to third countries with relatively less ambitious carbon pricing policies remain acceptable under the condition that the carbon pricing policies in place in these countries correspond to ‘the highest possible ambition’ that can be expected from them under the Paris Agreement. The systematic and indiscriminate use of CBAMs to mitigate carbon leakage risks is not ‘in line’ with the principle of common but differentiated responsibility that underlies the Paris Agreement.
2.3 The Climate Leadership Story
In addition to their role in supporting fair competition and ensuring compliance with the Paris Agreement, CBAMs have been described as an instrument of climate leadership. Under this story, CBAMs are presented as a tool for influencing third countries’ climate action and making them follow the lead of the implementing country (eg the EU or the USA).45 The Commission does not explicitly include this objective among those that its proposal is to achieve. However, it is fully part of the policy context surrounding the Commission’s proposal for a regulation establishing a CBAM.46 The EU CBAM proposal has often been presented as a measure aimed at ‘encouraging industry outside the EU’ and the EU’s ‘international partners to take steps in the same direction’ as the EU.47 Similarly, the Climate Leadership Council, a US bipartisan non-profit organization that advocates for the adoption of carbon pricing policies, refers to CBAMs as a regulatory strategy that can promote both fair competition and the climate leadership of the USA:
This [a well-designed system of border carbon adjustments] will put America in the driver’s seat of global climate policy and encourage other large emitters – such as China and India – to follow America’s lead and adopt carbon pricing of their own.48
Under this ‘climate leadership story’, third countries—which are portrayed as ‘climate laggards’49—can be defined in a narrow or broad way. Under a narrow definition, ‘climate laggards’ would only refer to ‘non-cooperative countries’50 and CBAMs’ objective would be to pressure them to adopt sufficiently ambitious commitments in line with the Paris Agreement. In this hypothesis, CBAMs would have a similar purpose under the climate leadership and Paris Agreement stories. However, ‘climate laggards’ can also be defined broadly by reference to all countries with less ambitious carbon pricing policies as the ones in place in the EU (or the USA). In this case, CBAMs’ objective would be to encourage all third countries to adopt as ambitious carbon pricing policies as those that have been or will be adopted by the EU (or the USA).51 CBAMs would support the ‘territorial extension’ of European (or American) carbon pricing policies.52 Third countries following the lead of the EU (or the USA) would form a ‘climate club’ and CBAMs would be imposed on products from countries that have not (yet) become part of the club.53 Countries would thus be divided in two groups based on whether they have adopted a carbon price as high as in the EU (or the USA). This version of the climate leadership story differs from the Paris Agreement story, which distinguishes between countries based on a different criterion (ie based on whether they comply with the Paris Agreement).54 It also differs from the fair competition story and its implicit assumption that the best climate mitigation strategy is the adoption of a global harmonised carbon price. This version of the climate leadership story relies on the assumption that the mitigation of climate change requires the adoption of an international minimum carbon price equivalent to the carbon price in place in the EU (or the USA).55 This assumption is inconsistent with the differentiated approach of the Paris Agreement.56
As this article aims to explore the meaning of the multiple purposes attached to CBAMs, references to the climate leadership story in the rest of this article will focus on this second version of the climate leadership story given its differences with both the fair competition and the Paris Agreement stories. It is worth pointing, though, that this version of the climate leadership story could, in the long run, fulfil the objective of the fair competition story. Carbon leakage risks would disappear under the climate leadership story if, thanks to the CBAMs, all countries end up adopting the EU (or the US) carbon price.
2.4 The Consumption-based Story
Under a fourth story, CBAMs are described as a crucial instrument to make consumers pay for the carbon footprint of the services and products they consume, including imported products. This story has rarely been explicitly discussed in the policy discourse,57 but it has been advocated by some legal scholars and economists.58 It relies on an unusual assumption about how to best mitigate climate change, namely that emissions associated with production processes should be internalised, through a carbon price, in the country where services and products are consumed. This assumption has been discussed as part of the debate on how to divide responsibilities for emissions between countries, but it has not been adopted in international climate change law.59
If it were to prevail, this story would thus imply a complete paradigm shift in the climate mitigation approach that has guided national and international climate action so far. For practical reasons,60 greenhouse gas emissions are generally accounted for in the country where they are released, and embedded emissions linked to products ‘manufactured offshore but consumed in-country’ are rarely included in national greenhouse gas emissions targets.61 It implies that producers—rather than consumers—are generally held responsible for the greenhouse gas emissions generated through production processes. For example, in the EU, the EU ETS establishes a carbon price for heavy energy-using installations, which reflects a production-based approach. Although this carbon price can be passed on to the consumers of energy-intensive products, it is not directly imposed on consumers. A consumption-based approach would be based on the opposite logic. Embedded greenhouse gas emissions would be accounted for in the country of consumption and internalise there. Such a new logic could have significant consequences on the way responsibilities with respect to climate change are shared between countries. Moreover, if all countries were to follow this new logic, the traditional methods used to report greenhouse gas emissions would have to be fully reviewed.
Because they rely on two contradictory approaches to climate mitigation, the consumption-based story and the Paris Agreement story cannot be reconciled. These two stories differ in respect to the location that they deem appropriate to internalise greenhouse gas emissions linked to production processes: either in the consumption country (under the consumption-based story) or in the production country where the emissions are physically released (under the Paris Agreement story). This is not to say that the consumption-based story would not support the mitigation of climate change, but it would necessarily break with the rules that govern the reporting of greenhouse gas emissions under international climate change law.
For the same reason, the consumption-based story differs from the fair competition and climate leadership stories. Yet, the purposes underlying each of these three stories can nevertheless be reconciled. If the EU takes the lead in a move towards the worldwide adoption of a consumption-based approach, it could still be portrayed as a climate leader (though its climate leadership would no longer be in reference to the EU’s ability in encouraging third countries to adopt a carbon price as ambitious as the European carbon price). Moreover, although its primary objective is not to mitigate carbon leakage risks, the consumption-based story is likely to be robust to carbon leakage because carbon costs are borne by (relatively immobile) consumers rather than (relatively mobile) producers who might relocate their activities to jurisdictions with no (or relatively lower) carbon price.62 Carbon leakage risks would nevertheless remain in the absence of a mechanism to prevent domestic producers from maintaining a highly energy-intensive production line for products that they would export to countries with no (or a relatively lower) carbon price on ‘embedded’ emissions.63 If robust to carbon leakage, the consumption-based story could accommodate a new, consumption-based, version of the fair competition story.
2.5 The Budgetary Story
Finally, a fifth story relates to the role of CBAMs in generating revenue. This story has played a key role in the EU context.64 CBAMs’ revenue-driven objective can be understood as a direct consequence of the COVID-19 crisis.65 Given the huge economic implications of the pandemic, it is understandable that the EU is looking for new sources of financing, including through environmental tax and other market-based measures. This approach has been supported both by the fiscal affairs department of the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and the OECD.66 In May 2020, the European Parliament called on EU leaders to ‘reform the EU own resources system’ and consider a CBAM among ‘potential candidates for new own resources’.67 The same month, the European Commission released a document on the financing of the EU recovery plan that included both the EU ETS as well as the CBAM as ‘possible additional own resources’.68 The European Council confirmed this additional goal for CBAMs in July 2020.69
Despite the clear interest in the revenue generation dimension of CBAMs, the Commission seems to reject the idea that raising revenue is part of the purposes to be achieved through its proposal. The Commission’s impact assessment report states as follows: ‘While not introduced with revenue raising as its purpose and it not playing a role in the design of the measure, the CBAM will raise revenue on GHG emissions at the border’.70 This indicates that the budgetary objective is secondary, at least in the eyes of the Commission. From an environmental perspective, it certainly makes sense to prioritise CBAMs’ climate mitigation objective (be it by promoting fair competition, compliance with the Paris Agreement, the EU’s climate leadership or the imposition of a carbon price on consumers) over their budgetary objective.71 The budgetary story is reconcilable with all the other stories. Its objective does not relate to the mitigation of climate change and, thus, it does not rely on any assumption that can be inconsistent with the ones underlying the other stories analysed above.
3. FROM A GENERIC IDEA TO A CONCRETE PROPOSAL: THE BUILDING BLOCKS OF CBAMS
The previous section has explained the different stories linked to the multiple purposes that have been attached to CBAMs in the legal and policy discourse. These stories are not specific to the EU but the recent European Commission’s proposal for a regulation establishing a CBAM provides a good example of a policy context where these stories have been told concurrently. The Commission’s proposal includes references to all but one of the stories discussed above. The European CBAM is primarily justified by reference to its objective in addressing carbon leakage risks. Moreover, as part of the policy context of its proposal, the Commission refers to the role of the CBAM in supporting the EU’s climate leadership. Finally, the Commission considers that its proposal might have ‘ancillary positive effects’ on fostering compliance with the Paris Agreement and generating revenue for the EU.72 The Commission proposes a clear hierarchy between the purposes and effects that it expects from its CBAM proposal. This is the correct approach to the adoption of CBAMs. Each of the objectives that can be achieved through CBAMs are based on different assumptions about the most suitable climate mitigation strategy and are not (or not fully) reconcilable. It is thus key to first determine which of CBAMs’ objectives should be seen as primary and subsidiary. This defined hierarchy of objectives should then guide the design choices made by the Commission in the drafting process of its proposal to ensure its effectiveness.
In this section, I discuss the main building blocks that constitute the foundation of CBAMs’ legal design and, on that basis, I explain the choices made by the Commission for its proposal of a regulation establishing a CBAM. This discussion thus gives an overview of the content of the Commission’s proposal and lays the groundwork for explaining, in the next section, the reciprocal influence that exists between CBAMs’ legal design and their primary objective (Section 4). To show how the use of CBAMs for specific purposes requires specific design choices, one first needs to understand CBAMs’ main building blocks.
3.1 The Object of the Adjustment: A Tax or an Emissions Trading Scheme
The first design choice to be made with respect to the adoption of future CBAMs concerns the type of domestic carbon pricing instruments that they complement. Two main options exist: CBAMs can be adopted as a complementary measure either to a carbon tax or to an emissions trading scheme.
The Commission examined these two options as part of its impact assessment report and decided in favour of a CBAM linked to the EU ETS.73 The CBAM will subject imports to a ‘system that replicates the EU ETS regime applicable to domestic production’, mirroring the carbon price of the EU ETS allowances.74 Thus, in the same way as domestic producers are required to surrender emissions allowances, importers will be obliged to surrender ‘CBAM certificates’ to cover the emissions associated with the production of their imported products.75 These CBAM certificates will be phased in gradually, following the gradual phase out of the free allocations of emissions allowances.76 Their price will be calculated on a weekly basis as ‘the average price of the closing prices of EU ETS allowances’.77
3.2 The Type and Scope of the Adjustment
A second design choice for a future CBAM concerns the type and the scope of the adjustments. CBAMs can be used for both imported and exported products or they can be limited to adjustments on imports. On the import side, CBAMs impose a charge on imported products. On the export side, CBAMs exempt exported products from the carbon price that would otherwise apply to them or, alternatively, repay upon the export of the products the carbon price that has already been paid. On both sides, CBAMs can apply either to a small list of products (eg energy products and carbon intensive basic materials, such as steel, pulp paper, cement clinker and plastic) or be extended to a larger number of products, including semi-manufactured and manufactured products. The broader the scope of the CBAMs, the more complicated it will be to guarantee low compliance costs and administrability. Moreover, adjustments can be applied on products imported from (or exported to) a limited number of non-cooperative countries (namely those that do not comply with the Paris Agreement) or be applied to all imported and exported products, regardless of their country of origin and destination.
The Commission’s proposal is rather limited in scope: It only provides for adjustments on imports on a limited number of products (cement, electricity, fertilisers, iron and steel and aluminium).78 However, it is not limited to imports from non-cooperative countries but generally applies to all imports, except for imports from countries and territories with a trading system linked to the EU ETS.79
3.3 The Definition and Calculation of the Emissions Subject to the CBAMs
A third design choice for a future CBAM concerns the definition and calculation of the embedded greenhouse gas emissions on which the carbon price will be imposed. Embedded greenhouse gas emissions can be determined in a narrow or broad way and with more or less accuracy. Narrowly defined, embedded greenhouse gas emissions only refer to the emissions strictly associated with the production process of products.80 But the concept could also cover the entire carbon footprint throughout the life cycle of products, including the emissions linked to the production process defined broadly (such as the emissions linked to the mining and transport of materials) and those linked to the use of the product and its disposal.81
The method of calculation with the highest level of accuracy aims to determine the ‘actual’ greenhouse gas emissions embedded in the products subject to the CBAM. When the concept of embedded emissions is defined narrowly, this usually means that embedded greenhouse gas emissions of products are determined per installation: The embedded greenhouse gas emissions of a given product are determined by dividing the total amount of greenhouse gas emissions caused by the production of the goods by the total amount of goods produced over a given period.82 Such a method involves significant administrative costs to track how much greenhouse gas emissions have been emitted throughout the production processes of imported products. It could also lead to resource shuffling: Exporters could send their ‘carbon-efficient’ production to the EU but their overall production would remain carbon intensive.83 Another—less burdensome—method is to determine the carbon content of imported products based on default values.84 Different techniques can be used. One option is to rely on the amount of greenhouse gas emissions released when the ‘best (or worst) available technique’ (meaning the technique that is the least (or the most) carbon intensive) is used to produce the imported products subject to the CBAM. This would mean that the carbon content of imported products would be undervalued (or overvalued) in most cases. Another option is to use the average amount of greenhouse gas emissions released when the ‘predominant method of production’ or the ‘average method of production’ is used to produce the imported products. These methods could both undervalue and overvalue the amount of greenhouse gas emissions from imported products.
The Commission’s proposal provides that the European CBAM will be imposed on the same type of emissions as the ones covered by the EU ETS: carbon dioxide and, where relevant, nitrous oxide and perfluorocarbons.85 However, the scope of the embedded emissions covered by the Commission’s proposal will initially be narrower than the emissions covered by the EU ETS: It will only cover direct emissions (ie ‘emissions from the production processes on which producers have direct control’) and not indirect emissions (ie emissions from the production of electricity consumed in production processes).86 For the calculation of the embedded emissions, the Commission’s proposal combines a method based on the actual emissions released during the production of goods as well as a method based on default values.87 For goods other than electricity, the Commission gives preferences to the determination of their actual embedded emissions.88 If such determination is not possible, default values will be used based on the average emissions intensity of the exporting country, which will be increased by a mark-up.89 In the absence of reliable data for the exporting country, the default value will be based on the ‘average emission intensity of the 10 per cent worst performing EU installations for that type of goods’.90 For electricity, the approach is different: Default values are used, unless the importer chooses to determine the actual embedded emissions of electricity.91
3.4 The Interaction with Other Countries’ Carbon Pricing Policy
A fourth design choice concerns the interaction of the CBAMs with the carbon pricing imposed by third countries. The implementing country can either ignore or acknowledge the existence of carbon pricing policies in place in third countries.92 The recognition of third countries’ carbon pricing policies permits the application of different carbon prices on imported products based on their origin country. Under this method, products imported from countries with similar (or more ambitious) carbon pricing policies as those in place in the implementing country will not be subject to the CBAM.93 Products imported from other countries will be subject to the CBAM, the amount of which will depend on whether part of the carbon cost has already been internalised in the country of production.
The Commission’s proposal integrates this method by allowing importers to obtain a reduction in the number of CBAM certificates to be surrendered when they have already paid a ‘carbon price’ in their country of origin.94 However, it is not yet clear how this reduction will be calculated and implemented in practice.95 It worth pointing that this method is likely to be prone to manipulation.96 To avoid paying the higher carbon costs imposed on products from one specific country, importers could decide to artificially shift the origin of the products, pretending that they come from a ‘climate friendly’ country. Moreover, this method will require the assessment of the quality of the carbon pricing policies in place in third countries. This could raise complex questions as to which carbon policies are of ‘equal’ quality to the EU’s carbon price, which foreign partners could see as controversial, if not unacceptable. For goods originating from countries or territories with a carbon pricing system that has been linked to the EU ETS (eg Switzerland), the situation is nevertheless simple. The Commission’s proposal provides that the CBAM will not apply to those goods.97
3.5 The Revenue Allocation
A fifth design choice concerns the allocation of the revenues generated by the future CBAM when it is imposed on imports. Many options exist. First, the revenue could contribute to the general budget of the implementing country following the same allocation rules that apply to other import taxes. Secondly, given CBAMs’ overarching goal of limiting the increase in global average temperature, the revenue could be earmarked for climate mitigation projects. Earmarking could take place at the national, regional or global level. For example, the revenue could be allocated to a global environmental fund, such as the Green Climate Fund.98 Finally, the revenue could be redistributed to developing or less-developed countries in order to alleviate the potential negative effects that CBAMs might have on their economy.99 In the context of the EU’s proposal, the plan is to allocate most revenues to the EU budget.100 In its impact assessment report, the EU Commission recognises the ‘need for targeted ways to support LDCs [least developed countries]’, including through financial support.101 However, at this stage, there is no clear indication that part of the revenue will be redistributed to developing and least developed countries.
4. THE INTERACTION BETWEEN CBAMS’ PRIMARY PURPOSE AND THEIR LEGAL DESIGN
When CBAMs are thought of as concrete policy proposals, it becomes clear that many different options exist for transforming a generic CBAM proposal into a concrete measure. In this section, which corresponds to the second step of my analytical framework, I examine the links between CBAMs’ legal design and their objectives based on a though experiment. Assuming that the primary purpose of a future CBAM was ‘X’ [eg promoting fair competition], how would its legal design look like in practice? This section thus presents simplified models of CBAMs aimed at a specific purpose.102 As they all differ from each other, these simplified models can illuminate the complex regulatory nature of CBAMs. I use the EU legal framework as a basis for this analysis as a way of contextualisation: The interactions between CBAMs’ legal design and purpose appear more clearly when discussed in a specific legal context than when analysed in the abstract. The following questions guide my analysis: What do the design choices made by the Commission for its CBAM proposal tell us about its main objectives? Do the choices made by the Commission in terms of legal design correspond to the objectives on which the Commission has based and justified its proposal? By comparing the Commission’s proposal with each of the simplified CBAMs’ models, I show that the legal design of the Commission’s proposal is not fully in line with its stated objectives, and I am able to uncover the types of objectives that the future European CBAMs will (or not) effectively achieve.
4.1 CBAMs as Part of a Fair Competition Story
A simplified model of CBAM, which primary objective is to address carbon leakage risks, would include the following design elements. This simplified model of CBAM would complement the EU ETS and replace the system of free allowances. It would include adjustments on both imports and exports in order to fully remove differences in carbon prices between European and foreign products.103 On the import side, a charge on imported products would allow the EU to impose a similar carbon price on EU and non-EU products sold into the EU market. EU products would be indirectly subject to a carbon price through the EU ETS and the charge on imported products would directly subject them to a carbon price equal to the EU ETS. The charge on imported products should, if possible, be broad in scope. If the measure is limited to energy products and basic materials, manufacturing industries relying on basic products would be put at a disadvantage in comparison to competitors operating in jurisdictions with no carbon price. This trade disadvantage would mean that the CBAM does not fully meet its objective in terms of providing fair competition.104 To equalize the EU price, the charge on imported products would, if possible, be determined based on the actual level of ‘EU-ETS like emissions’ of imported products (ie the emissions of imported products that correspond to the emissions that would have been subject to the EU ETS if these products had been produced in the EU) and the charge would take into account the carbon price level imposed in third countries.105 On the export side, the EU ETS costs would be reimbursed to producers in proportion to their share of exported products to countries with no equivalent carbon price to the EU ETS. For countries with a lower carbon price than the EU ETS, the EU ETS costs could be reimbursed in part to ensure that EU products compete on an equal basis with foreign products when they are exported abroad. Alternatively, the costs of the EU ETS on exported products could be reimbursed in full. This solution might be considered ‘fairer’: EU products exported to a third country will not only compete with the products produced in this particular third country, but also with products from other third countries, which might not be subject to any carbon price. Regarding revenue allocation, the fair competition story does not require any specific use for the revenue generated by the CBAM. The purpose of achieving a level playing field between domestic and foreign producers is achieved through the mechanisms of the CBAM, irrespective of how the revenue is being used.
Although the Commission’s proposal primarily aims at preventing carbon leakage risks, it differs from this simplified model of CBAM in four main respects. First, the Commission’s proposal is limited in scope, which the Commission explained by reference to the high administrative costs linked to the inclusion semi-manufactured and manufactured products.106 Secondly, the scope of the embedded emissions covered by the Commission’s proposal differs from the ‘EU-ETS like emissions’: It is limited to direct emissions, excluding indirect emissions which are nevertheless covered by the EU ETS.107 This design choice seems to have been justified by reference to the lack of easily available data on indirect emissions.108 Thirdly, the Commission’s CBAM proposal will co-exist with the system of free allowances, which it will gradually replace. The Commission justified this design choice as a way to ‘ensure a prudent and predictable transition for businesses and authorities’.109 Fourthly, the Commission’s proposal does not include adjustments on exports. The option of including adjustments on exports was discarded by the Commission at an early stage of the legislative process for two main reasons.110 First, the Commission considered that it would have been contrary to the environmental objective of the mechanism. Secondly, the Commission thought that it would ‘undermine the global credibility of EU’s raised climate ambition’.111
None of these four design choices are consistent with the simplified model of a CBAM aimed at mitigating climate leakage risk but the Commission convincingly justified the first two by reference to practical reasons linked to the administrability of the measure.112 In contrast, the two other design elements raise questions as to whether the Commission’s proposal is effectively primarily aimed at addressing carbon leakage risks and creating a level playing field between EU and foreign producers. The gradual phase-in of the CBAMs suggests that the Commission does not consider its proposal ready to immediately replace the system of free allowances, which is the Union’s main tool to address carbon leakage risks. Moreover, adjustments on exports are a key feature of CBAMs aimed at mitigating carbon leakage risks and it is hard to understand why the EU discarded this option so quickly. In the absence of CBAMs on exports, EU products could become non-competitive in foreign markets. This could lead to higher demand for products from jurisdictions with no climate policies in place, which could translate to higher levels of greenhouse gas emissions at the global level. From this perspective, and maybe counterintuitively, adjustments on exports are not necessarily contrary to the environmental objective of CBAMs when this objective is defined by reference to the mitigation of climate leakage risks (as under the fair competition story). CBAMs on exports might be necessary to reduce greenhouse gas emissions globally by preventing that a decrease of emissions physically released in the EU leads to a relatively higher increase of emissions physically released in third countries.
4.2 CBAMs as Part of a Paris Agreement Story
Under the Paris Agreement story, the primary purpose of a CBAM is intrinsically tied to the success and implementation of the Paris Agreement. In this hypothesis, a simplified model of a EU CBAM would serve as an instrument to reduce the risk of carbon leakage in favour of ‘non-cooperative countries’113 and would entail the following design elements. The CBAM would complement the EU ETS as part of the EU’s carbon pricing policy but the design of the CBAM would not mirror the design of the EU ETS. It would only involve adjustments on the import side. There is no reason to include adjustments on exports: The objective, under the Paris Agreement story, is not to systematically prevent any form of carbon leakage. The adjustments on imports would be based on the actual embedded emissions of imported products and their level as high as needed to force non-cooperative countries to cooperate.114 Similarly, the scope of the CBAM could be as broad as needed to infer cooperation. The CBAM could first be imposed on a small list of basic materials and be latterly extended to more products if the non-cooperative country still refuses to join global efforts to mitigate climate change. The calculation of the adjustments would not need to take account of carbon pricing policies in place in non-cooperative third countries as the objective is not to match the EU’s carbon price but rather to foster compliance with the Paris Agreement. Finally, revenue generated through the CBAM should be used to ‘assist developing country Parties with respect to both mitigation and adaptation’, in line with Article 9 of the Paris Agreement.
The Commission’s proposal is not primarily aimed at fostering compliance with the Paris Agreement, which explains that its design differs from this model in two main respects. First, it does not target imported products from non-cooperative countries but generally applies to all imported products. Secondly, CBAM’s revenue will be allocated to the EU budget and not redistributed to developing countries. These differences, and more specifically the first one, imply that the Commission’s proposal is unlikely to achieve the objective of fostering compliance with the Paris Agreement. CBAMs imposed indiscriminately on all imported products cannot serve as a sanction against non-cooperative countries (given that their products will be subject to the same CBAM as the products from cooperative countries). Importantly, and as explained in Section 2.2, the indiscriminate application of CBAMs is inconsistent with the approach of the Paris Agreement.
4.3 CBAMs as Part of a Climate Leadership Story
If the main purpose of a simplified model of CBAM was to encourage third countries to adopt similar carbon pricing policies as in the EU, it would include the following design features. This model of CBAM would complement and mirror the EU ETS. It would be limited to adjustments on the import side: Relieving exported products of the costs of the EU ETS would undermine the EU’s objective of extending the territorial scope of the European carbon price. The adjustment on imports would be imposed on products from countries with no equivalent carbon price to the EU ETS. If possible, the level of the charge would be based on the actual ‘EU-ETS like’ emissions of imported products and be a function of the carbon price that has (or not) already been imposed in the country(ies) of production. The scope of the CBAM on imports would be as broad as possible, including basic materials as well as semi-manufactured and manufactured products. Under this version of the climate leadership story, the more products that are subject to a carbon price equivalent to the EU ETS, the better. Finally, the revenues could be used for any purpose. This version of the climate leadership is not about leading by example by funding projects related to climate change. Instead, it is about making all countries adopt a carbon price as ambitious as the EU carbon price. This latter objective does not require any specific use for CBAMs’ revenue.
The Commission’s proposal differs from this simplified model only in two respects. Its scope is limited; it does not include semi-manufactured and manufactured products. Moreover, embedded emissions will initially not cover all ‘EU-ETS like’ emissions but be limited to ‘direct emissions’.115 As explained before (Section 4.1), these design choices are justified by practical reasons, including the need to minimise compliance costs. The high correspondence between the Commission’s proposal and this simplified model of CBAM suggests that the Commission’s proposal has been primarily designed to achieve this objective, even though it has not been explicitly listed as part of the objectives to be achieved by the EU CBAM.
4.4 CBAMs as Part of a Consumption-based Story
In the context of the consumption-based story, a simplified model of CBAM would replace the EU ETS altogether in order to reverse the production-based approach to climate mitigation that has prevailed so far in the EU and globally. Such a simplified model of CBAM on imports would be used to make consumers pay for the carbon costs of all services and products they consume on the EU’s territory, including imports and excluding exports. This model, often referred to as ‘carbon added tax’, would follow the logic of the value added tax, which is imposed on all services and products consumed on the EU’s territory.116 However, instead of being based on products’ price, the charge would be based on the actual greenhouse gas emissions released at each stage of a product’s life cycle.117 Whether or not a carbon price has been levied in the country of production would be of no importance: Under a consumption-based approach, the country of consumption is responsible for establishing the carbon price that it deems sufficient to influence consumption behaviours on its territory. Finally, the consumption-based story does not require the revenue raised by the CBAM to be used for a specific purpose. The consumption-based approach is achieved through the carbon pricing mechanism itself.
The Commission’s proposal is not aimed at internalising greenhouse gas emissions in the consumption country, which explains why it fully differs from this model. The Commission discarded the option for a CBAM as part of a ‘carbon added tax’ at an early stage of the discussions on different CBAMs’ models, mainly due the practical difficulties linked to its implementation, including high administrative and compliance costs.118
4.5 CBAMs as Part of a Budgetary Story
A simplified model of EU CBAM primarily119 aimed at generating revenue would complement the EU ETS as part of the EU’s carbon pricing policy, but its design would not need to match the design of the EU ETS. In principle, it should be limited to imports. Adjustments in respect of exports would likely involve a loss of revenue as exported products would no longer be subject to a carbon price. The adjustments on imported products should have the broadest scope possible: Basic materials and also semi-manufactured and manufactured products should be included as it would generate more revenue. The carbon charge could be based either on the actual or on the average embedded greenhouse gas emissions of the products covered. The method that leads to higher levels of adjustments should be preferred. For the same reason, adjustments on imported products would be imposed regardless of the carbon price imposed in third countries. Finally, the revenue generated would be allocated to the EU budget.
The Commission’s proposal differs from this model in two main respects: It has a limited scope, and it does not disregard the carbon price imposed in third countries. These differences can be explained by the hierarchy of objectives defined by the Commission for its proposal. The generation of revenue is not the priority.
5. THE EU CBAM AS AN INSTRUMENT OF CLIMATE LEADERSHIP
The analysis of different simplified models of CBAMs illustrates how CBAMs’ legal design is heavily influenced by their primary purpose. Conversely, CBAMs’ legal design illuminates the type of purposes that they can achieve. The table below gives an overview of the different purposes attached to CBAMs, their underlying assumption and their matching design. In this table, the boxes coloured light grey include all the design choices that correspond to the design of the Commission’s proposal. From this, it appears clearly that the European CBAM is closer to the climate leadership model than to the fair competition model.
Due to the absence of adjustments on exports, the Commission’s proposal is likely to be more effective at fostering the EU’s climate leadership than at mitigating carbon leakage. This is not to say that the European CBAM will have no effect on carbon leakage. Adjustments on imports will reduce carbon leakage risks but not fully eliminate them.120 Regarding its effects in relation to the Paris Agreement, the European CBAM will allow the EU to meet its commitments in terms of climate neutrality and might encourage some non-cooperative countries to increase their commitments in line with the Paris Agreement. However, as explained in Sections 2.2 and 4.2, the systematic and indiscriminate use of CBAMs is inconsistent with the approach of the Paris Agreement. The European CBAM will not only impose a carbon price on products from non-cooperative countries but also on products from cooperative countries, namely countries whose climate policy meet the requirements of the Paris Agreement. For these countries, the CBAM will impose a higher carbon price on part of their greenhouse gas emissions (namely the emissions embedded in products from cooperative countries imported into the EU) than what would have been necessary in the light of their national circumstances. Due to the CBAM, these cooperative countries will no longer be able to fully decide upon their domestic climate policy.121 From this perspective, the European CBAM should not be considered as an appropriate tool to foster compliance with the Paris Agreement. Regarding the budgetary objective, the design of the European CBAM seems suitable: The plan is to allocate most of the revenues to the EU budget.122
The design of the EU CBAM proposal as first and foremost an instrument of climate leadership is surprising in some respects and unsurprising in others. On the one hand, it is surprising because the Commission has primarily justified its proposal by reference to the objective of addressing carbon leakage risks not by reference to the promotion of its climate leadership. It suggests that the Commission has either misrepresented the goals that it sought to achieve through the European CBAM or not (or insufficiently) thought about the relationship between the design of its proposal and its main purpose and thus made the wrong design choices. On the other hand, it is unsurprising as it confirms the EU’s leadership role in climate change matters. The EU has long been portrayed as a ‘global environmental leader’ because it has encouraged the adoption of international environmental agreements, including climate change agreements.123 Moreover, the EU has been described as a ‘directional leader’ who leads by example through the adoption of ambitious domestic climate policies.124
The EU CBAM proposal could be seen as putting an end to the EU’s global climate leadership because it is inconsistent with the approach of the Paris Agreement. Yet, the Commission’s proposal could also be viewed as an attempt by the EU to support a new and more ambitious international climate agreement that would impose a minimum carbon price equivalent to the price applied under the EU ETS. The EU CBAM proposal implements and goes beyond directional leadership. It does not only set an example that others might decide to follow but it also allows the EU to enforce its carbon price on foreign products. A similar strategy was used in 2008 when the EU adopted a directive extending the scope of the EU ETS to the aviation sector, including for flights which do not fully take place over the EU’s territory but merely arrive at or depart from an aerodrome situated in the EU.125 Third countries strongly opposed this new EU approach126 and the Commission decided to defer enforcement of the EU ETS obligations on aircraft operators in respect of activities to and from aerodromes in countries outside the Union.127 Given that it extends, in a similar way, the scope of the EU ETS, the Commission’s proposal for a CBAM might attract the same kind of opposition.
. | Fair competition . | Paris Agreement . | Climate leadershipa . | Consumption-based approach . | Budget . |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Overarching objective | Limiting the increase in global average temperatureb | ||||
Specific problem to be solved by CBAMs | Carbon leakage risks preventing the EU to meet its commitments in terms of climate-neutrality | Non-compliance of some countries (ie ‘non-cooperative countries’) with the Paris Agreement | Lack of sufficiently ambitious carbon prices in third countries | Lack of internalisation of embedded GHG emissions in consumption patters | Need for new EU own resources |
Underlying assumption | Ideally, a global carbon price—to be imposed on GHG emissions where they are released—should apply worldwide | Ideally, all countries should comply with the normative expectations of the Paris Agreement. There is no ‘right’ or ‘wrong’ carbon price as it will depend on the national circumstances of each country | Ideally, all countries should impose a minimum carbon price (equivalent to the EU carbon price) on GHG emissions where they are released | Ideally, a carbon price should be imposed on the emissions embedded in products. The amount of this carbon price should be determined by each ‘consumption’ country | The ‘ideal’ carbon price is the carbon price that generates the most revenue to the EU budget |
Nature | Complementing the EU ETS | Complementing the EU ETS | Complementing the EU ETS | Independent mechanism replacing the EU ETS | Complementing the EU ETS |
Type | All imports and exports (regardless of country of origin/destination) | Imports of non-cooperative countries only | All imports (regardless of country of origin) | All imports and exports (regardless of country of origin/destination) | All imports |
(regardless of country of origin) | |||||
Basis for the adjustment on imports | Actual emissions, and a function of the carbon price in third countries | Actual emissions, and adjustment ‘as high as needed’ | Actual emissions, and a function of the carbon price in third countries | Actual emissions, regardless of the carbon price in third countries | Actual or average emissions, regardless of the carbon price in third countries |
Scope | Broad scope | Limited or broad scope | Broad scope | Broad scope | Broad scope |
Revenue allocation | Irrelevant (EU budget or other) | In line with Article 9 of the Paris Agreement | Irrelevant (EU budget or other) | Irrelevant (EU budget or other) | EU budget |
. | Fair competition . | Paris Agreement . | Climate leadershipa . | Consumption-based approach . | Budget . |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Overarching objective | Limiting the increase in global average temperatureb | ||||
Specific problem to be solved by CBAMs | Carbon leakage risks preventing the EU to meet its commitments in terms of climate-neutrality | Non-compliance of some countries (ie ‘non-cooperative countries’) with the Paris Agreement | Lack of sufficiently ambitious carbon prices in third countries | Lack of internalisation of embedded GHG emissions in consumption patters | Need for new EU own resources |
Underlying assumption | Ideally, a global carbon price—to be imposed on GHG emissions where they are released—should apply worldwide | Ideally, all countries should comply with the normative expectations of the Paris Agreement. There is no ‘right’ or ‘wrong’ carbon price as it will depend on the national circumstances of each country | Ideally, all countries should impose a minimum carbon price (equivalent to the EU carbon price) on GHG emissions where they are released | Ideally, a carbon price should be imposed on the emissions embedded in products. The amount of this carbon price should be determined by each ‘consumption’ country | The ‘ideal’ carbon price is the carbon price that generates the most revenue to the EU budget |
Nature | Complementing the EU ETS | Complementing the EU ETS | Complementing the EU ETS | Independent mechanism replacing the EU ETS | Complementing the EU ETS |
Type | All imports and exports (regardless of country of origin/destination) | Imports of non-cooperative countries only | All imports (regardless of country of origin) | All imports and exports (regardless of country of origin/destination) | All imports |
(regardless of country of origin) | |||||
Basis for the adjustment on imports | Actual emissions, and a function of the carbon price in third countries | Actual emissions, and adjustment ‘as high as needed’ | Actual emissions, and a function of the carbon price in third countries | Actual emissions, regardless of the carbon price in third countries | Actual or average emissions, regardless of the carbon price in third countries |
Scope | Broad scope | Limited or broad scope | Broad scope | Broad scope | Broad scope |
Revenue allocation | Irrelevant (EU budget or other) | In line with Article 9 of the Paris Agreement | Irrelevant (EU budget or other) | Irrelevant (EU budget or other) | EU budget |
Understood by reference to the role of CBAMs in encouraging third countries to adopt as ambitious carbon pricing policies as those that have been adopted in the EU (ss 2.3 and 4.3).
bThe budgetary story does not explicitly refer to this overarching objective. However, for the reasons mentioned above (s 2.5), this objective should prevail over a budgetary objective.
. | Fair competition . | Paris Agreement . | Climate leadershipa . | Consumption-based approach . | Budget . |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Overarching objective | Limiting the increase in global average temperatureb | ||||
Specific problem to be solved by CBAMs | Carbon leakage risks preventing the EU to meet its commitments in terms of climate-neutrality | Non-compliance of some countries (ie ‘non-cooperative countries’) with the Paris Agreement | Lack of sufficiently ambitious carbon prices in third countries | Lack of internalisation of embedded GHG emissions in consumption patters | Need for new EU own resources |
Underlying assumption | Ideally, a global carbon price—to be imposed on GHG emissions where they are released—should apply worldwide | Ideally, all countries should comply with the normative expectations of the Paris Agreement. There is no ‘right’ or ‘wrong’ carbon price as it will depend on the national circumstances of each country | Ideally, all countries should impose a minimum carbon price (equivalent to the EU carbon price) on GHG emissions where they are released | Ideally, a carbon price should be imposed on the emissions embedded in products. The amount of this carbon price should be determined by each ‘consumption’ country | The ‘ideal’ carbon price is the carbon price that generates the most revenue to the EU budget |
Nature | Complementing the EU ETS | Complementing the EU ETS | Complementing the EU ETS | Independent mechanism replacing the EU ETS | Complementing the EU ETS |
Type | All imports and exports (regardless of country of origin/destination) | Imports of non-cooperative countries only | All imports (regardless of country of origin) | All imports and exports (regardless of country of origin/destination) | All imports |
(regardless of country of origin) | |||||
Basis for the adjustment on imports | Actual emissions, and a function of the carbon price in third countries | Actual emissions, and adjustment ‘as high as needed’ | Actual emissions, and a function of the carbon price in third countries | Actual emissions, regardless of the carbon price in third countries | Actual or average emissions, regardless of the carbon price in third countries |
Scope | Broad scope | Limited or broad scope | Broad scope | Broad scope | Broad scope |
Revenue allocation | Irrelevant (EU budget or other) | In line with Article 9 of the Paris Agreement | Irrelevant (EU budget or other) | Irrelevant (EU budget or other) | EU budget |
. | Fair competition . | Paris Agreement . | Climate leadershipa . | Consumption-based approach . | Budget . |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Overarching objective | Limiting the increase in global average temperatureb | ||||
Specific problem to be solved by CBAMs | Carbon leakage risks preventing the EU to meet its commitments in terms of climate-neutrality | Non-compliance of some countries (ie ‘non-cooperative countries’) with the Paris Agreement | Lack of sufficiently ambitious carbon prices in third countries | Lack of internalisation of embedded GHG emissions in consumption patters | Need for new EU own resources |
Underlying assumption | Ideally, a global carbon price—to be imposed on GHG emissions where they are released—should apply worldwide | Ideally, all countries should comply with the normative expectations of the Paris Agreement. There is no ‘right’ or ‘wrong’ carbon price as it will depend on the national circumstances of each country | Ideally, all countries should impose a minimum carbon price (equivalent to the EU carbon price) on GHG emissions where they are released | Ideally, a carbon price should be imposed on the emissions embedded in products. The amount of this carbon price should be determined by each ‘consumption’ country | The ‘ideal’ carbon price is the carbon price that generates the most revenue to the EU budget |
Nature | Complementing the EU ETS | Complementing the EU ETS | Complementing the EU ETS | Independent mechanism replacing the EU ETS | Complementing the EU ETS |
Type | All imports and exports (regardless of country of origin/destination) | Imports of non-cooperative countries only | All imports (regardless of country of origin) | All imports and exports (regardless of country of origin/destination) | All imports |
(regardless of country of origin) | |||||
Basis for the adjustment on imports | Actual emissions, and a function of the carbon price in third countries | Actual emissions, and adjustment ‘as high as needed’ | Actual emissions, and a function of the carbon price in third countries | Actual emissions, regardless of the carbon price in third countries | Actual or average emissions, regardless of the carbon price in third countries |
Scope | Broad scope | Limited or broad scope | Broad scope | Broad scope | Broad scope |
Revenue allocation | Irrelevant (EU budget or other) | In line with Article 9 of the Paris Agreement | Irrelevant (EU budget or other) | Irrelevant (EU budget or other) | EU budget |
Understood by reference to the role of CBAMs in encouraging third countries to adopt as ambitious carbon pricing policies as those that have been adopted in the EU (ss 2.3 and 4.3).
bThe budgetary story does not explicitly refer to this overarching objective. However, for the reasons mentioned above (s 2.5), this objective should prevail over a budgetary objective.
6. CONCLUSION
In this article, my objective has been to illuminate the complex regulatory nature of CBAMs as climate mitigation measures, and, on this basis, to offer a critical analysis of the purpose and legal design of the latest Commission’s proposal for a regulation establishing a CBAM. In a first step, I have explained the underlying differences between each of the purposes that have been attached to CBAMs in the legal and policy discourse. In a second step, I have examined how CBAMs’ specific purpose and legal design affect each other.
This two-step analytical framework contributes to the understanding of CBAMs and their deep consequences for the climate change debate. Importantly, the different ‘stories’ surrounding CBAMs that I have analysed are not just stories about CBAMs. They are stories about countries’ preferences in terms of climate mitigation strategy and how they view the Paris Agreement. Under the Paris Agreement story, CBAMs are used to strengthen the Paris Agreement that lacks an enforcement mechanism. In contrast, neither the fair competition nor the climate leadership and consumption-based stories are consistent with the approach of the Paris Agreement. This suggests that countries that propose CBAMs to address carbon leakage risks, promote their climate leadership (defined in reference to their ability in imposing their carbon price on third countries) or internalise greenhouse gas emissions embedded in consumption patterns, do not view the Paris Agreement as an appropriate solution to maintain the increase of global average temperature below an acceptable level. Countries using CBAMs to promote fair competition seem to consider that climate mitigation should be based on the adoption of a global carbon price to be imposed on greenhouse gas emissions where they are physically released. Countries using CBAMs as part of the climate leadership story consider that the carbon price in place in third countries should be at least equal to their domestic carbon price. Finally, countries following the consumption-based approach reject the idea that greenhouse gas emissions from production processes should be internalised in the country where they are physically released. Instead, they favour a new approach aimed at internalising greenhouse gas emissions embedded in consumption patterns.
These contrasting views on climate mitigation explain why CBAMs are hard to discuss in the abstract: There is no generic and uniform concept of CBAMs. The more countries will introduce concrete proposals in favour of CBAMs, the easier it will become to understand the full breath of their regulatory complexity.
ACKNOWLEDGEMENT
I would like to thank all the colleagues with whom I discussed this topic over the past months. This work also benefitted from the comments I received during several conferences and events, including the webinar organised by the Cambridge Tax Discussion Group in May 2021, the XVIII Seminar on Advanced Issues of EU Law organised by the University of Zagreb Jean Monnet Centre of Excellence in May 2021, the Colloquium Series of the Institute for Austrian and International Tax Law in May 2021, the CBS Tax Colloquium Series organised by Yvette Lind in March 2021, the webinar organised by the Catolica Lisbon School of Business & Economics in June 2020, the Lund environmental tax seminar organised by Cécile Brokelind in January 2020, the Brussels conference on the ‘Future of EU Tax Harmonization’ organised by Edoardo Traversa in December 2019, the event on ‘Carbon Taxation: Challenges & Opportunities’ organised by the Belgian Representation to the EU in Brussels in October 2019 and the two Nuremberg environmental tax seminars organised by Roland Ismer in 2018 and 2019. Special thanks go to Manuel Haussner and Timo Gerres as well as the students who I had the opportunity to lecture on environmental tax law and who, through their questions, also contributed to this work. Finally, I would like to thank Liz Fisher and the two anonymous referees for their constructive and stimulating comments. The usual disclaimers apply.
Footnotes
By way of illustration, see European Parliament, Committee on the Environment, Public Health and Food Safety, ‘Report Towards a WTO-compatible EU Carbon Border Adjustment Mechanism’ (A9-0019/2021), explanatory statement.
The expression ‘straightforward and uniform regulatory strategy’ is borrowed from Bogojević who uses it in a different context (Sanja Bogojević, Emissions Trading Schemes: Market, States and Law (Hart Publishing 2013) 20).
The concept of ‘effectiveness’ has various meanings in law, including environmental law (Sandrine Maljean-Dubois (ed), The Effectiveness of Environmental Law (Intersentia 2017)). In this article, I define it by reference to the ‘production by legal rules of consequences compatible with the finalities of this production’ (Yann Leroy, ‘La notion d’effectivité du droit’ (2011) 73 Droit et Société 715). See also Maria Mousmouti, ‘Making Legislative Effectiveness an Operational Concept: Unfolding the Effectiveness Test as a Conceptual Tool for Lawmaking’ (2018) 9 E J Risk Regul 445.
On storytelling in law, see James Boyd White, Heracles’ Bow. Essays on the Rhetoric and Poetics of the Law (The University of Wisconsin Press 1985) 168–75.
See, among others, Joost Pauwelyn, ‘Carbon Leakage Measures and Border Tax Adjustments under WTO Law’ in Geert Van Calster and Denise Prévost (eds), Research Handbook on Environment, Health and the WTO (Edward Elgar Publishing 2013); Kateryna Holzer, Carbon-related Border Adjustment and WTO Law (Edward Elgar Publishing 2014); Ross Astoria, ‘Design of an International Trade Law Compliant Carbon Border Tax Adjustment’ (2015) 6 Ariz J Envtl L & Pol’y 491; Joel P Trachtman, ‘WTO Law Constraints on Border Tax Adjustment and Tax Credit Mechanisms to Reduce the Competitive effect of Carbon Taxes’ (2016) 16 Resources for the Future Discussion Paper; Alice Pirlot, Environmental Border Tax Adjustments and International Trade Law. Fostering Environmental Protection (Edward Elgar Publishing 2017); Michael A Mehling and others, ‘Designing Border Carbon Adjustments for Enhanced Climate Action’ (2019) 113 AJIL 433.
Holzer ibid 241–92; Mehling ibid 456–71.
Jennifer Hillman, ‘Changing Climate for Carbon Taxes. Who’s Afraid of the WTO?’ (2013) Climate Energy Paper Series 14 <https://scholarship.law.georgetown.edu/facpub/2030/> accessed 24 September 2021; Holzer (n 5) 237; Pirlot (n 5) 158–61; Mehling and others (n 5) 478–79.
Commission, ‘The European Green Deal’ COM (2019) 640 final, 5.
Commission, ‘Proposal for a Regulation of the European Parliament and of the Council Establishing a Carbon Border Adjustment Mechanism (EU CBAM proposal)’ COM (2021) 564 final. See also Commission, ‘Delivering the European Green Deal’ (14 July 2020) <https://ec.europa.eu/info/strategy/priorities-2019-2024/european-green-deal/delivering-european-green-deal_en> accessed 21 August 2021.
EU CBAM proposal ibid arts 2.1; 6; 22; 36.3(d); Annex I.
OECD, Environmental Policy Committee and Committee on Fiscal Affairs, ‘Environmental Taxes and Border Tax Adjustments’ (COM/ENV/EPOC/DAFFE/CFA(94)31); Paul Demaret and Richard Stewardson, ‘Border Tax Adjustments under GATT and EC Law and General Implications for Environmental Taxes’ (1994) 28 J World Trade 5; Marco Düerkop, ‘Trade and Environment: International Trade Law Aspects of the Proposed EC Directive Introducing a Tax on Carbon Dioxide Emissions and Energy’ (1994) 31 CML Rev 807; Roland Ismer and Karsten Neuhoff, ‘Border Tax Adjustment: A Feasible Way to Support Stringent Emission Trading’ (2007) 24 Eur J Law Econ 137. For a US perspective, see Warren H Maruyama, ‘Climate Change and the WTO: Cap and Trade versus Carbon Tax?’ (2011) 45 J World Trade 679. For a recent overview, see Mehling and others (n 5).
Susanne Dröge and Simonne Cooper, ‘Tackling Leakage in a World of Unequal Carbon Prices’ (Study commissioned for the Greens/EFA Group 2010) <https://climatestrategies.org/wp-content/uploads/2014/11/cs-greens-group-final-160610.pdf> accessed 17 August 2021.
In the EU context, see Commission, ‘The European Green Deal’ (n 8) s 2.1.1; EU CBAM proposal (n 9) Explanatory memorandum and recital 9.
See Olivier Blanchard and Jean Tirole (chairs), ‘French Report on Major Future Economic Challenges’ (June 2021) 37.
OECD, ‘Climate Policy Leadership in an Interconnected World: What Role for Border Carbon Adjustments?’ (2020) 7–11.
International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/the World Bank, Report of the High-Level Commission on Carbon Pricing and Competitiveness (2019) 8.
Dröge and Cooper (n 12).
Consolidated Version of Directive 2003/87/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 13 October 2003 establishing a scheme for greenhouse gas emission allowance trading within the Community and amending Council Directive 96/61/EC [2003] OJ L275/32, art 10a; Directive 2009/29/EC of the European parliament and of the Council of 23 April 2009 amending Directive 2003/87/EC so as to improve and extend the greenhouse gas emission allowance trading scheme of the Community [2009] OJ L140/63, recital 25.
See Partnership for Market Readiness (PMR), Carbon Tax Guide. A Handbook for Policy Makers (World Bank Group 2017) 107ff.
Roland Ismer, Karsten Neuhoff and Alice Pirlot, ‘Border Carbon Adjustments and Alternative Measures for the EU ETS. An Evaluation’ (2020) DIW Discussion Papers 1855.
See Frederic Branger and Philippe Quirion, ‘Would Border Carbon Adjustments Prevent Carbon Leakage and Heavy Industry Competitiveness Losses? Insight from a Meta-analysis of Recent Economic Studies’ (2014) 99 Ecol Econ 29. See also Madison Condon and Ada Ignaciuk, ‘Border Carbon Adjustment and International Trade’ (2013) OECD Trade and Environment Working Papers 6; Aaron Cosbey and others, ‘Developing Guidance for Implementing Border Carbon Adjustments: Lessons, Cautions and Research Needs from the Literature’ (2019) 13 Rev Environ Econ Pol 3, 6–7.
Eg, Yassen Spassov, ‘EU ETS: Upholding the Carbon Price Without Incidence of Carbon Leakage’ (2012) 24 JEL 311; Trachtman (n 5) 2; Pauwelyn (n 5) 450–55; Holzer (n 5) 2.
Mehling and others (n 5) 433.
Directive 2009/29/EC (n 18), recital 25. See also Commission, ‘20 20 by 2020. Europe’s Climate Change Opportunity’ COM (2008) 30 final, 11.
European Parliament, Amendments adopted on 15 February 2017 on the proposal for a directive of the European Parliament and of the Council amending Directive 2003/87/EC to enhance cost-effective emission reductions and low-carbon investments [2018] OJ C252/352, amendment 85. See also European Parliament, ‘Resolution of 10 March 2021 towards a WTO-compatible EU carbon border adjustment mechanism (CBAM Resolution)’ (P9_TA(2021)0071).
Commission, ‘The European Green Deal’ (n 8).
State of the Union Address by President von der Leyen at the European Parliament Plenary, 16 September 2020.
EU CBAM proposal (n 9) art 1.1.
OECD (n 15) 4. The same wording was used in IMF/OECD, ‘Report for the G20 Finance Ministers and Central Bank Governors: Tax Policy and Climate Change’ (April 2021) 22.
See US Trade Representative, ‘2021 Trade Policy Agenda and 2020 Annual report of the President of the United States on the Trade Agreements Program’ (March 2021) 3; Canada, ‘Supporting Canadians and Fighting COVID-19, Fall Economic Statement 2020’, s 3.3.2.8.
IMF/OECD (n 29) 22; Joint Statement issued at the conclusion of the 30th BASIC Ministerial Meeting on Climate Change hosted by India on 8 April 2021, para 19. See also Arvind P Ravikumar, ‘Carbon Border Taxes are Unjust’ (2020) MIT Technology Review <www.technologyreview.com/2020/07/27/1005641/carbon-border-taxes-eu-climate-change-opinion/> accessed 17 August 2021.
Joost Pauwelyn and David Kleimann, ‘Trade Related Aspects of a Carbon Border Adjustment Mechanism. A Legal Assessment’, Briefing requested by the European Parliament’s Committee on International Trade (April 2020).
United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change ‘Adoption of the Paris Agreement’ (12 December 2015) FCCC/CP/2015/L.9/Rev.1, art 2.
On the concept of temperature target, see Chris Hilson, ‘Hitting the Target? Analysing the Use of Targets in Climate Law’ (2020) 32 JEL 195, 199.
Paris Agreement arts 2.2. and 4.
ibid art 4.
Lavanya Rajamani, ‘Understanding the 2015 Paris Agreement’, in Navroz K. Dubash (ed), India in a Warming World: Integrating Climate Change and Development (OUP 2019) 215.
Mehling and others (n 5) 441.
Commission, ‘Impact Assessment Report Accompanying the Proposal for a Regulation of the European Parliament and of the Council Establishing a Carbon Border Adjustment Mechanism (CBAM Impact assessment report)’ SWD (2021) 643 final, 15.
The Biden Plan to Ensure the Future is ‘Made in All of America’ by All of America’s Workers (7 July 2020) <https://joebiden.com/made-in-america/> accessed 17 August 2021.
European Parliament, ‘CBAM Resolution’ (n 25) paras 7 and 14; EU CBAM proposal (n 9) recital 9.
Commission, ‘CBAM Impact Assessment Report’ (n 39) 8 and 10; Ramboll and others, ‘Study on the Possibility to Set Up a Carbon Border Adjustment Mechanism on Selected Sectors’ TAXUD/2020/AO-14 (14 July 2021) 39ff.
Samuel Kortum and David Weisbach, ‘The Design of Border Adjustments for Carbon Prices’ (2017) 70 Natl Tax J 421, 422; Trachtman (n 5) 2. See also s 2.1.
Commission, ‘CBAM Impact Assessment Report’ (n 39) 4. See Carbon Pricing Leadership Coalition, Report of the High-Level Commission on Carbon Prices, 29 May 2017, 4, stating that in a context where ‘domestic and international compensatory transfers are limited’, ‘(…) the appropriate carbon-price levels will vary across countries’.
The term ‘global leader’ has been used in Commission, ‘The European Green Deal’ (n 8) s 3. See also Dieter Helm, Cameron Hepburn and Giovanni Ruta, ‘Trade, Climate Change, and the Political Game Theory of Border Carbon Adjustments’ 28 (2012) Oxf Rev Econ Policy 368; Matthias Weitzel, Michael Hübler and Sonja Peterson, ‘Fair, Optimal or Detrimental? Environmental vs. Strategic Use of Border Carbon Adjustment’ (2012) 34 Energy Econ 198; Holzer (n 5) 3.
EU CBAM proposal (n 9) Explanatory memorandum 0, 3. See also the references to the EU’s international climate leadership in Commission, ‘CBAM Impact Assessment Report’ (n 39) 1, 11.
See Commission, ‘European Green Deal: Commission proposes Transformation of EU Economy and Society to Meet Climate Ambitions’ (IP/21/3541). See also European Parliament, Committee on the Environment, Public Health and Food Safety, ‘Report towards a WTO-compatible EU carbon border adjustment mechanism’ (A9-0019/2021), explanatory statement.
Climate Leadership Council, ‘The Four Pillars of Our Carbon Dividends Plan’ (September 2019) <https://clcouncil.org/our-plan/> accessed 17 August 2021.
Mehling and others (n 5) 441.
As defined above under s 2.2: ‘countries whose commitments to mitigating climate change are not in line with the “normative expectations” of the Paris Agreement’.
Peter R Orszag, ‘Europe is Poised to Set Climate Standards for the World’ Bloomberg Opinion (16 March 2021) <www.bloomberg.com/opinion/articles/2021-03-16/europe-is-poised-to-set-climate-standards-for-the-world> accessed 17 August 2021.
See Joanne Scott, ‘Extraterritoriality and Territorial Extension in EU Law’ (2014) 62 Am J Comp L 87.
The idea of ‘climate club’ has been introduced by William Nordhaus, ‘Climate Clubs: Overcoming Free-riding in International Climate Policy’ (2015) 105 Am Econ Rev 1339.
In fact, Nordhaus himself considered that ‘The attractiveness of a Climate Club must be judged relative to the current approaches, where international climate treaties are essentially voluntary and have little prospect of slowing climate change’ (Norhdhaus ibid 1368).
On the idea of an international minimum carbon price, see Ian Parry, Simon Black and James Roaf, ‘Proposal for an International Carbon Price Floor among Large Emitters’ (2021) IMF Staff Climate Notes 001.
For the same reason as the one explaining the inconsistency between the fair competition and Paris Agreement stories (above s 2.2).
It was, however, discussed as part of DG Taxud’s Terms of reference for its study on the possibility to set up a Carbon Border Adjustment Mechanism on selected sectors (TAXUD/2020/AO-14) 4. See also the reference to the objective of ‘ensur[ing] that the price of imports reflects more accurately their carbon content’ in Commission, ‘The European Green Deal’ (n 8) 5.
See Thomas J Courchene and John R Allan, ‘Climate Change: The Case for a Carbon Tariff/Tax’ (2008) 29 Policy Options 59, 62–4; Stephen Sewalk, ‘A Carbon Tax with Reinvestment is WTO Compatible’ (2013–2014) 25 Fordham Envtl L Rev 338, 379–80; Carol McAusland and Nouri Najjar, ‘Carbon Footprint Taxes’ (2014) 61 Environ Resour Econ 37; Ronald Ismer and Manuel W Haussner, ‘Inclusion of Consumption into the EU ETS: The Legal Basis under European Union Law’ (2016) 25 Rev Eur Comp Int Environ Law 69; Manuel W Haussner, Including Consumption in Emissions Trading. Economic and Legal Considerations (Edward Elgar Publishing 2021).
Eg Jiahua Pan, Jonathan Phillips and Ying Chen, ‘China’s Balance of Emissions Embodied in Trade: Approaches to Measurement and Allocating International Responsibility’ (2008) 24 Oxf Rev Econ Policy 354.
Greenhouse gas emissions reporting is more easily done in the country where emissions are released due to the availability of information on production processes.
Hilson (n 34) 207–08.
On the robustness of destination-based taxes, see Michael P Devereux and others, Taxing Profit in a Global Economy (OUP 2020) 290–4.
See Michael Jakob, Jan Christoph Steckel and Ottmar Edenhofer, ‘Consumption- Versus Production-Based Emission Policies’ (2014) 6 Ann Rev Resour Econ 297, 305–06.
Susanne Dröge,‘The EU’s CO2 Border Adjustment: Climate or Fiscal Policy’ (2020) Point of View, Stiftung Wissenschaft und Politik <www.swp-berlin.org/en/publication/the-eus-co2-border-adjustment-climate-or-fiscal-policy/> accessed 17 August 2021.
Richard Collier, Alice Pirlot and John Vella, ‘Tax Policy and the COVID-19 Crisis’ (2020) 48 Intertax 794.
IMF, Fiscal Affairs Department, Greening the Recovery (2020), <www.imf.org/en/Topics/climate-change/green-recovery> accessed 17 August 2021; OECD, ‘Policy Responses to Coronavirus (COVID-19): Green Budgeting and Tax Policy Tools to Support a Green Recovery’ (2020).
European Parliament, ‘Resolution of 15 May 2020 On the New Multiannual Financial Framework, Own Resources and the Recovery Plan’ (P9_TA(2020)0124). See also European Parliament, ‘Interim Report of 14 November 2018 on the Multiannual Financial Framework 2021–2027’ (P8_TA (2018)0449).
Commission, ‘Financing the Recovery Plan for Europe’ (27 May 2020) <https://ec.europa.eu/info/sites/info/files/factsheet_3_04.06.pdf> accessed 17 August 2021
European Council, ‘Special meeting of the European Council (17, 18, 19, 20 and 21 July 2020)’ (EUCO 10/20, CO EUR 8, CONCL 4) para A29.
Commission, ‘CBAM Impact Assessment Report’ (n 39) 15.
Christian Gollier and Mar Reguant, ‘Climate Change’, in Olivier Blanchard and Jean Tirole (chairs), French Report on Major Future Economic Challenges (June 2021) 101, 158–59 <https://www.strategie.gouv.fr/sites/strategie.gouv.fr/files/atoms/files/fs-2021-rapport-anglais-les_grands_defis_economiques-juin_1.pdf> accessed 24 September 2021.
Commission, ‘CBAM Impact assessment report’ (n 39) 15.
EU CBAM proposal (n 9) Explanatory memorandum 7–8.
ibid.
ibid arts 3.18–3.19; 20–22.
ibid art 21.
ibid.
EU CBAM proposal (n 9) art 2.1; Annex I.
ibid arts 2.3 and 2.5; Annex IIA. For electricity, see arts 2.7–2.9.
Ramboll and others (n 42) 104–06.
ibid 104–05.
Eg, EU CBAM proposal (n 9) Annex III, pts 2–3.
Commission, ‘CBAM Impact Assessment Report’ (n 39) 29–30.
Condon and Ignaciuk (n 21) 13.
EU CBAM proposal (n 9) Annex I; Commission, ‘CBAM Impact Assessment Report’ (n 39) 17.
EU CBAM proposal (n 9) recital 17; arts 3.15–3.16; 3.28; 6.2(c); 22.1; 30.1; Annexes I and III. See also Commission, ‘CBAM Impact Assessment Report’ (n 39) 17–18.
EU CBAM proposal (n 9) arts 3.21–3.22; 7 and Annex III.
ibid art 7.2; Annexes I and III.
ibid, Annex III, pt 4.1.
ibid.
EU CBAM proposal (n 9) art 7.3; Annexes I and III.
Pirlot (n 5) 149–51.
Unless these countries exempt exported products from the carbon price.
EU CBAM proposal (n 9) arts 3.23; 9.
ibid art 9.4 (empowering the Commission to adopt implementing acts).
Note that the Commission ‘shall take action (…) to address practices of circumvention’ of its the EU CBAM (EU CBAM proposal (n 9) art 27).
EU CBAM proposal (n 9) arts 2.3; 2.5; Annex IIA. For electricity, see arts 2.7–2.9.
United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change, Decision 1/CP.16, FCCC/CP/2010/7/Add.1, 102.
Mehling and others (n 5) 478.
EU CBAM proposal (n 9) Explanatory memorandum 10–11, referring to Council Decision (EU, Euratom) 2020/2053 of 14 December 2020 on the system of own resources of the European Union and repealing Decision 2014/335/EU Euratom [2020] OJ L 424/1.
Commission, ‘CBAM Impact Assessment Report’ (n 39) 30.
My goal is not to present a range of ‘ready-to-implement’ CBAMs, which is why I largely disregard the technical difficulties linked to some of the design features of the models presented below in terms of implementation. Some of these technical issues have already been discussed in s 3.
See Stuart Evans and others, ‘Border Carbon Adjustments and Industrial Competitiveness in a European Green Deal’ (2021) 21 Climate Policy 307.
As explained in s 3.2, this economic justification would need to be balanced against practical considerations. See Kortum and Weisbach (n 43) 429–32.
OECD (n 15) 23–24: ‘A BCA regime could credit foreign producers for the carbon pricing they have already been subject to domestically, which is sensible from a leakage-prevention perspective’.
Commission, ‘CBAM Impact Assessment Report’ (n 39) 21, 75 and 84; EU CBAM proposal (n 9) recitals 28–29.
EU CBAM proposal (n 9) recital 17; arts 3.15; 3.16; 3.28; 6.2(c); 22.1; 30.1; Annexes I and III. See also Commission, ‘CBAM Impact Assessment Report’ (n 39) 17–18.
Commission, ‘CBAM Impact Assessment Report’ (n 39) 18.
EU CBAM proposal (n 9) explanatory memorandum 10–11.
Commission, ‘CBAM Impact Assessment Report’ (n 39) 42.
ibid.
Commission, ‘CBAM Impact Assessment Report’ (n 39) 17–18, 21.
As defined under s 2.2.
The application of the adjustments on the actual embedded emissions of imported products would allow the EU not to impose an adjustment on products from producers using climate-neutral production methods but located in non-cooperative countries.
EU CBAM proposal (n 9) recital 17; arts 3.16; 3.28; 30.1; Annexes I and III. See also Commission, ‘CBAM Impact Assessment Report’ (n 39) 17–18.
CE Delft, ‘Carbon Added Tax as an Alternative Climate Policy Instrument’ (2015) <https://cedelft.eu/wp-content/uploads/sites/2/2021/04/CE_Delft_7A48_Carbon_Added_Tax_FINAL.pdf> accessed 17 August 2021; Ramboll and others (n 42) 34. This model is the closest to the traditional concept of ‘border tax adjustments’. See Alice Pirlot, ‘Environmental Border Tax Adjustments (BTAs): a Forgotten History’, in Larry Kreiser and others (eds), Environmental Pricing. Studies in Policy Choices and Interactions (Edward Elgar Publishing 2015) 147–60.
CE Delft ibid; Courchene and Allan (n 58) 62–4; McAusland and Najjar (n 58). On the definition of ‘embedded emissions’ under this model, see Ramboll and others (n 42) 104–10.
Commission, ‘CBAM Impact Assessment Report’ (n 39) 42.
Note that, ideally and as explained in s 2.5, CBAMs’ primary objective should not be the generation of revenue.
See Ramboll and others (n 42) 50.
They will have to impose a carbon price equivalent to the EU carbon price to avoid that their products are subject to the European CBAM. Otherwise, part of their greenhouse gas emissions will be priced through the EU CBAM.
EU CBAM proposal (n 9) Explanatory memorandum 10.
R Daniel Kelemen and David Vogel, ‘Trading Places: The Role of the United States and the European Union in International Environmental Politics’ (2010) 43 Comp Political Stud 427.
Sebastien Oberthür and Claire Roche Kelly, ‘EU Leadership in International Climate Policy: Achievements and Challenges’ (2008) 43 Int Spect 35, 36–37.
Directive 2008/101/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 19 November 2008 amending Directive 2003/87/EC so as to include aviation activities in the scheme for greenhouse gas emission allowance trading within the Community [2009] OJ L8/3.
Alan Thomas and others, Joined letter to the EU regarding unilateral aircraft emissions control (6 April 2007).
Decision 377/2013/EU of the European Parliament and of the Council of 24 April 2013 derogating temporarily from Directive 2003/87/EC establishing a scheme for greenhouse gas emission allowance trading within the Community [2013] OJ L 113/1. See also Regulation (EU) 421/2014 of the European Parliament and of the Council of 16 April 2014 amending Directive 2003/87/EC establishing a scheme for greenhouse gas emission allowance trading within the Community, in view of the implementation by 2020 of an international agreement applying a single global market-based measure to international aviation emissions [2014] OJ L129/1; Regulation (EU) 2917/2392 of the European Parliament and of the Council of 13 December 2017 amending Directive 2003/87/EC to continue current limitations of scope for aviation activities and to prepare to implement a global market-based measure from 2021 [2017] OJ L350/7.