-
PDF
- Split View
-
Views
-
Cite
Cite
David Atkin, Azam Chaudhry, Shamyla Chaudry, Amit K. Khandelwal, Eric Verhoogen, Organizational Barriers to Technology Adoption: Evidence from Soccer-Ball Producers in Pakistan, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Volume 132, Issue 3, August 2017, Pages 1101–1164, https://doi.org/10.1093/qje/qjx010
- Share Icon Share
Abstract
This article studies technology adoption in a cluster of soccer-ball producers in Sialkot, Pakistan. We invented a new cutting technology that reduces waste of the primary raw material and gave the technology to a random subset of producers. Despite the clear net benefits for nearly all firms, after 15 months take-up remained puzzlingly low. We hypothesize that an important reason for the lack of adoption is a misalignment of incentives within firms: the key employees (cutters and printers) are typically paid piece rates, with no incentive to reduce waste, and the new technology slows them down, at least initially. Fearing reductions in their effective wage, employees resist adoption in various ways, including by misinforming owners about the value of the technology. To investigate this hypothesis, we implemented a second experiment among the firms that originally received the technology: we offered one cutter and one printer per firm a lump-sum payment, approximately a month’s earnings, conditional on demonstrating competence in using the technology in the presence of the owner. This incentive payment, small from the point of view of the firm, had a significant positive effect on adoption. The results suggest that misalignment of incentives within firms is an important barrier to technology adoption in our setting.
I. Introduction
Observers of the process of technological diffusion have been struck by how slow it is for many technologies.1 A number of the best-known studies have focused on agriculture or medicine,2 but diffusion has also been observed to be slow among large firms in manufacturing. In a classic study of major industrial technologies, Mansfield (1961) found that it took more than 10 years for half of major U.S. iron and steel firms to adopt by-product coke ovens or continuous annealing lines, technologies that were eventually adopted by all major firms. More recently, Bloom et al. (2013) found that many Indian textile firms are not using standard (and apparently cheap to implement) management practices that have diffused widely elsewhere. The surveys by Hall and Khan (2003) and Hall (2005) contain many more examples.
Why is adoption so slow for so many technologies? The question is key to understanding the process of economic development and growth. It is also a difficult one to study empirically, especially among manufacturing firms. It is rare to be able to observe firms’ technology use directly, and rarer still to have direct measures of the costs and benefits of adoption, or of what information firms have about a given technology. As a consequence, it is difficult to distinguish between various possible explanations for low adoption rates.
In this article, we present evidence from a cluster of soccer-ball producers in Sialkot, Pakistan, that a conflict of interest between employees and owners within firms is an important barrier to adoption. The cluster is economically significant, producing 30 million soccer balls a year, including for the largest global brands (and the 2014 World Cup). The setting has two main advantages for understanding the adoption process. The first is that the industry is populated by a substantial number of firms—135 by our initial count—producing a relatively standardized product, using largely the same, simple production process. The technology we focus on is applicable at a large enough number of firms to conduct statistical inference. The second, and perhaps more important, advantage is that our research team, through a series of fortuitous events, discovered a useful innovation: we invented a new technology that represents, we argue, a clear increase in technical efficiency for nearly all firms in the sector. The most common soccer-ball design combines 20 hexagonal and 12 pentagonal panels. The panels are cut from rectangular sheets of an artificial leather called rexine, typically by bringing a hydraulic press down on a hand-held metal die. Our new technology, described in more detail below, is a die that increases the number of pentagons that can be cut from a rectangular sheet by implementing the densest packing of pentagons in a plane known to mathematicians. A conservative estimate is that the new die reduces rexine cost per pentagon by 6.76% and total costs by approximately 1%—a modest reduction but a nontrivial one in an industry where mean profit margins are 8%. The new die requires minimal adjustments to other aspects of the production process. Importantly, we observe adoption of the new die very accurately, in contrast to studies that must infer technology adoption from changes in residual-based measures of productivity such as those reviewed in Syverson (2011).
We randomly allocated the new technology to a subset of 35 firms (which we refer to as the “tech-drop” group) in May 2012. To a second group of 18 firms (the “cash-drop” group) we gave cash equal to the value of the new die (US|${\$}$|300), and to a third group of 79 firms (the “no-drop” group) we gave nothing. We expected the technology to be adopted quickly by the tech-drop firms, and we planned to focus on spillovers to the cash-drop and no-drop firms; we are pursuing this line of inquiry in a companion project. In the first 15 months of the experiment, however, the most striking fact was how few firms adopted, even among the tech-drop group. As of August 2013, five firms from the tech-drop group and one from the no-drop group had used the new die to produce more than 1,000 balls, our preferred measure of adoption.3 The experiences of the adopters indicated that the technology was working as expected; we were reassured, for instance, by the fact that the one no-drop adopter was one of the largest firms in the cluster and had purchased a total of 40 dies on 15 separate occasions. Overall, however, adoption remained puzzlingly low.
In our March–April 2013 survey round, we asked nonadopters in the tech-drop group why they had not adopted. Of a large number of possible responses, the leading answer was resistance from employees. Anecdotal evidence from a number of firms also suggested that workers were resisting the new die, in part by misinforming owners about its productivity benefits. Moreover, we noticed that the pay scheme of the large adopter (purchaser of the 40 dies) differed from the local norm: while more than 90% of firms pay a pure piece rate, it pays a fixed monthly salary plus a performance bonus.
The qualitative evidence led us to hypothesize that a misalignment of incentives within the firm is an important reason for the lack of adoption. The new die slows cutters down, certainly in the initial period when they are learning how to use it, and possibly in the longer run.4 If the piece rate is not adjusted, the cutters’ effective wage falls. Unless owners modify the payment scheme, the benefits of using the new technology accrue to owners and the costs are borne by the cutters. Realizing this, the workers resist adoption, including by misinforming owners about the value of the technology. We formalize this intuition in a simple model of strategic communication between an imperfectly informed principal (the owner) and a perfectly informed agent (the cutter). When principals are limited to standard piece-rate contracts that must be set ex ante, there is an equilibrium in which the agent seeks to discourage the principal from adopting a technology like ours and influences the principal not to adopt.5 A simple modification to the labor contract, conditioning the wage contract on marginal cost, an ex post–revealed characteristic of the technology, induces the agent to encourage adoption of the technology and the principal to adopt it.
To investigate the misalignment-of-incentives hypothesis, we implemented a second experiment. In September 2013, we randomly divided the set of 31 tech-drop firms that were still in business into two subgroups, a treatment subgroup (which we call Group A) and a control subgroup (Group B). To Group B, we simply gave a reminder about the benefits of the die and an offer of another demonstration of the cutting pattern. To Group A, we gave the reminder and explained the issue of misaligned incentives to the owner and offered an incentive payment treatment: we offered to pay one cutter and one printer a lump-sum bonus roughly equivalent to a month’s earnings (US|${\$}$|150 and US|${\$}$|120, respectively), conditional on demonstrating competence with the new technology in the presence of the owner. This bonus was designed to mimic (as closely as possible, given firms’ reluctance to participate) the “conditional” wage contracts we model in the theory. (We also paid printers a bonus because the new die requires a slight modification to the printing process, and printers face a similar but weaker disincentive to adopt.) The one-time bonus payments were small relative both to revenues from soccer-ball sales for the firms, approximately US|${\$}$|57,000 a month at the median, and to the variable-cost reductions from adopting our technology, approximately US|${\$}$|413 a month at the median.
Fifteen firms were assigned to Group A and 16 to Group B. Of the 13 Group A firms that had not already adopted the new die, 8 accepted the incentive payment intervention, and 5 adopted the new die within six months of the second experiment. Of the 13 Group B firms that had not already adopted the new die, none adopted within six months of the experiment and one adopted in the next six-month period. Although the sample size is small, we find a positive, statistically significant effect of the incentive intervention on adoption, with the probability of adoption increasing by 0.27–0.32 from a baseline adoption rate of 0.16 in our intent-to-treat specifications. Our results remain significant when using permutation tests that are robust to small sample sizes. The fact that such small payments had a significant effect on adoption suggests that the misalignment of incentives is indeed an important barrier to adoption in this setting.
After the second experiment, we asked owners and their employees a number of survey questions about wage setting and communication within the firm, and the results are supportive of the hypotheses that piece-rate contracts are sticky and that cutters have misinformed owners about the technology. We argue that the results do not support a leading alternative hypothesis, that our second experiment mechanically induced adoption by subsidizing the fixed costs of adoption, because it cannot quantitatively explain both low initial adoption rates and an increase in adoption of the magnitude we find in response to the second experiment. We also argue against the hypothesis that the second experiment merely increased the salience of the technology to owners, and that this alone led to increased adoption.
A natural question is why the firms themselves did not adjust their payment schemes to incentivize their employees to adopt the technology. Our model suggests two possible explanations. The first is that owners simply did not realize that such an alternative payment scheme was possible or desirable, just as the technical innovation had not occurred to them. The second is that there was a transaction cost involved in changing payment schemes that exceeded the expected benefits in this case. In the end, the two hypotheses have similar observable implications and are difficult to distinguish empirically. The important point is that many firms did not in fact adjust the payment scheme and as a consequence there was scope for our modest payment intervention to have an effect on adoption.
To our knowledge, this is the first study to randomly allocate a new technology to manufacturing firms to examine the adoption process.6 But the article is related to several different literatures. There is a long literature, largely descriptive, on how conflicts of interest in the workplace may affect productivity. One strand, dating back at least to the work of Taylor (1896, 1911) on scientific management, and including classic studies by Mathewson (1931), Roy (1952), Edwards (1979), and Clawson (1980), has focused on how employees in piece-rate systems may conceal information about how quickly they are capable of working or about productivity improvements they have discovered.7 A distinctive aspect of our study, relative to this strand, is the focus on workers dissuading owners from using a technology from outside the firm. Another strand of literature, much of it focusing on historical cases, has emphasized worker resistance to the adoption of such externally developed technologies (Lazonick 1979, 1990; Mokyr 1990). But the most commonly cited cases are of resistance to labor-saving technologies by groups of skilled artisans whose skills were in danger of being rendered obsolete. By contrast, our technology is labor-using: the new die simply slows cutters down while they are learning to use it and possibly in the longer run; we would expect demand for skilled cutters to increase marginally. There appears to have been little previous empirical research on worker resistance to such technologies.
A number of other explanations for slow technology adoption by manufacturing firms have been advanced. Bloom and Van Reenen (2007, 2010) and Bloom et al. (2013) suggest that a lack of product market competition may be responsible for the failure to adopt beneficial management practices. Rosenberg (1982), David (1990), Bresnahan and Trajtenberg (1995), and others have emphasized that new technologies often require changes in complementary technologies, which take time to implement. In our setting, firms sell almost all output on international export markets that appear to be quite competitive, and our technology requires extremely modest changes to other aspects of production, so these common explanations do not appear to be directly applicable.
There is an active literature in development economics on technology adoption in agriculture, where measures of technology use are more readily available than in manufacturing (e.g., Foster and Rosenzweig 1995; Munshi 2004; Bandiera and Rasul 2006; Conley and Udry 2010; Duflo, Kremer, and Robinson 2011; Suri 2011; Hanna, Mullainathan, and Schwartzstein 2014; BenYishay and Mobarak 2014; Beaman et al. 2015; Emerick et al. 2016). In addition to being important for development in their own right, manufacturing firms raise issues of organizational conflict that do not arise when the decision makers are individual smallholder farmers. Also, risk arguably plays a less important role among manufacturing firms, both because there is a lower degree of production risk (making inference about the benefits of a technology more straightforward) and because factory owners are typically richer and presumably less risk-averse than smallholder farmers.8
Our article is also related to a small but growing literature on field experiments in firms, including the experiments with fruit pickers by Bandiera, Barankay, and Rasul (2005, 2007, 2009) and with microenterprises by de Mel, McKenzie, and Woodruff (2008). The Bloom et al. (2013) study randomly allocated consulting services among Indian textile plants and argues that this generated exogenous variation in management practices (arguably a form of technology) which can be used to estimate the effect of those practices on plant outcomes. The authors suggest that “informational constraints” are an important factor leading firms not to adopt simple, apparently beneficial practices that are widespread elsewhere. Our study investigates how conflicts of interest within firms can impede the flow of information to managers and provides a possible micro-foundation for such informational constraints.9
The theoretical model we develop combines ideas from the literature on strategic communication following Crawford and Sobel (1982) and the voluminous literature on principal-agent models of the employment relationship (reviewed, for instance, by Lazear and Oyer 2013, and Gibbons and Roberts 2013). Gibbons (1987) formalizes the argument that (assuming employers cannot commit to future contracts) workers paid piece rates may hide information about labor-saving productivity improvements from their employers to prevent employers from reducing rates.10Carmichael and MacLeod (2000) explore the contexts in which firms will commit to fixing piece rates to alleviate these “ratchet” effects. Holmstrom and Milgrom (1991) show that high-powered incentives such as piece rates may induce employees to focus too much on the incentivized task to the detriment of other tasks, which could include reporting accurately on the value of a technology. Our study supports the argument of Milgrom and Roberts (1995) that piece rates may need to be combined with other incentives (in our case, higher pay conditional on adopting the new technology) to achieve high performance. Perhaps the closest theoretical antecedent is Dow and Perotti (2013), in which losers within the firm may block the adoption of a new technology because it reduces their share of quasi-rents (but do not communicate strategically).11Garicano and Rayo (2016) review a number of models of “organizational failures” that may lead firms not to adopt surplus-enhancing innovations. We view our model primarily as an application of insights from the organizational-economics literature to our setting, although we are not aware of a previous theoretical treatment of the specific idea that workers on piece-rate contracts may dissuade owners from adopting surplus-enhancing technologies from outside the firm. Our main contribution is empirical: while the organizational-economics literature has had to rely almost entirely on case studies for supporting evidence on organizational failures, we are able to document—and explore the reasons for—such a failure in an experimental setting.12
The article is organized as follows. Section II provides background on the Sialkot cluster and describes the new cutting technology. Section III describes our surveys and presents summary statistics. Section IV details the roll-out of the new technology and documents rates of early adoption. Section V discusses qualitative evidence on organizational barriers and summarizes our model of strategic communication in a principal-agent context, the full exposition of which has been relegated to Online Appendix B. Section VI describes the incentive payment experiment and evaluates the results. Section VII presents additional evidence on the hypothesized theoretical mechanisms. Section VIII considers the leading alternative interpretations of our findings, and Section IX concludes.
II. Background and Description of the New Technology
II.A. The Industry
Sialkot is a city of 1.6 million people in the province of Punjab, Pakistan. The soccer-ball cluster dates to British colonial rule. In 1889, a British sergeant asked a Sialkoti saddlemaker to repair a damaged ball, and then to make a new ball from scratch. The industry expanded through spinoffs and new entrants. (The history of the industry is reviewed in more detail in Atkin et al. 2017.) By the 1970s, the city had become a center of offshore production for many European soccer-ball companies. In 1982, a firm in Sialkot manufactured the FIFA World Cup ball for the first time. Virtually all of Pakistan’s soccer ball production is concentrated in Sialkot and exported to foreign markets. While in recent years the industry has faced increasing competition from East Asian (especially Chinese) suppliers,13 Sialkot remains the major source for the world’s hand-stitched soccer balls. It provided, for example, the hand-stitched balls used in the 2012 Olympic Games.14
To the best of our knowledge, there were 135 manufacturing firms producing soccer balls in Sialkot as of November 2011. The firms employ approximately 12,000 workers, and outsourced employment of stitchers in stitching centers and households is estimated to be more than twice that number (Khan, Munir, and Willmott 2007). The largest firms have hundreds of employees and produce for international brands such as Nike and Adidas. These firms manufacture both high-quality “match” and medium-quality “training” balls, often with a brand or team logo, as well as lower quality “promotional” balls, often with an advertiser’s logo. The remaining producers are small- and medium-size firms (the median firm size is 25 employees), which typically produce promotional balls either for clients they meet through industry fairs and online markets or under subcontract to larger firms.
II.B. The Production Process
Before presenting our new technology, we briefly explain the standard production process. As mentioned most soccer balls (approximately 90% in our sample) are of a standard design combining 20 hexagons and 12 pentagons (see Online Appendix Figure A.2). There are four stages of production. In the first stage, shown in Online Appendix Figure A.3, layers of cloth (cotton and/or polyester) are glued to an artificial leather called rexine using a latex-based adhesive, to form what is called a laminated rexine sheet (henceforth “laminated rexine”). The rexine, cloth, and latex are the most expensive inputs to production, together accounting for approximately 46% of the total cost of each soccer ball (or more if higher-quality rexine, which tends to be imported, is used). In the second stage, shown in Online Appendix Figure A.4, a skilled cutter uses a metal die and a hydraulic press to cut the hexagonal and pentagonal panels from the laminated rexine. The cutter positions the die by hand before activating the press with a foot pedal. He then slides the rexine along and places the die again to make the next cut.15 In the third stage, shown in Online Appendix Figure A.5, logos or other insignia are printed on the panels. This requires a “screen,” held in a wooden frame, that allows ink to pass through to create the desired design. Typically the dies cut pairs of hexagons or pentagons, making an indentation between them but leaving them attached to be printed as a pair, using one swipe of ink. In the fourth stage, shown in Online Appendix Figure A.6, the panels are stitched together around an inflatable bladder. Unlike the previous three stages, this stage is often outsourced to specialized stitching centers or stitchers’ homes. This stage is the most labor-intensive part of the production process, accounting for approximately 71% of total labor costs.
The production process is remarkably similar across the range of firms in Sialkot. A few larger firms have automated the cutting process, cutting half or full laminated rexine sheets at once, or attaching a die to a press that moves on its own, but even these firms typically continue to do hand cutting for a substantial share of their production. A few firms in the cluster have implemented machine stitching, but this has no implications for the first three stages of production.
Prior to our study, the most commonly used dies cut two panels at a time with the panels sharing an entire edge (Figure I). Hexagons tessellate (i.e., completely cover a plane), and experienced cutters are able to cut with a small amount of waste—approximately 8% of a laminated rexine sheet, mostly around the edges. (See the laminated rexine “net” remaining after cutting hexagons in Figure II.) By contrast, pentagons do not tessellate, and using the traditional two-pentagon die even experienced cutters typically waste 20–24% of the laminated rexine sheet (Figure III). The leftover laminated rexine has little value; typically it is sold to brickmakers who burn it to fire their kilns.


Laminated Rexine Wastage, Hexagons
Figure displays laminated rexine wastage from cutting hexagons with the traditional two-hexagon die.

Laminated Rexine Wastage, Pentagons, Traditional Die
Figure displays laminated rexine wastage from cutting pentagons with the traditional two-pentagon die.
II.C. The Innovation
In June 2011, as we were first exploring the possibility of studying the soccer-ball sector, we sought out a consultant who could recommend a beneficial new technique or practice that had not yet diffused in the industry. We found a Pakistan-based consultant who appears to have been responsible for introducing the existing two-hexagon and two-pentagon dies many years ago. (Previously, firms had used single-panel dies.) We offered the consultant US|${\$}$|4,125 to develop a cost-saving innovation for us. The consultant spent several days in Sialkot but was unable to improve on the existing technology. After this setback, Eric Verhoogen (a coauthor on this project) happened to watch a YouTube video of a Chinese firm producing the Adidas “Jabulani” thermo-molded soccer ball used in the 2010 FIFA World Cup. The video showed an automated press cutting pentagons for an interior lining of the Jabulani ball, using a pattern different from the one we knew was being used in Sialkot (Online Appendix Figure A.7). Based on the pattern in the video, Verhoogen and Annalisa Guzzini, an architect, developed a blueprint for a four-pentagon die (Figure IV).16 Through an intermediary, we contracted with a diemaker in Sialkot to produce the die (Online Appendix Figure A.8). It was only after we had received the first die and piloted it with a firm in Sialkot that we discovered that the cutting pattern is well known to mathematicians. The pattern appeared in a 1990 paper in Discrete & Computational Geometry (Kuperberg and Kuperberg 1990).17 It also appears, conveniently enough, in the Wikipedia “Pentagon” entry (Online Appendix Figure A.9).

Cutting Pattern and Blueprint for Offset Four-Pentagon Die
Left figure displays the cutting pattern for the four-panel offset die. Right figure displays blueprint of the four-panel offset die that was provided to tech-drop firms. The blueprint contained instructions for modifying the size of the die.
The pentagons in the new die are offset, with the two leftmost pentagons sharing half an edge, rather than a full edge. For this reason, we refer to the new die as the “offset” die, and treat other dies with pentagons sharing half an edge as variations on our technology. A two-pentagon variant of our design can be made using the specifications in the blueprint (with the two leftmost and two rightmost pentagons in the blueprint on the right side of Figure IV cut separately). This version is easier to maneuver with one hand and can be used with the same cutting rhythm as the traditional two-pentagon die. This version has proven more popular with firms.
II.D. Benefits and Costs
To quantify the various components of benefits and costs of using the offset die, we draw on several rounds of survey data that we describe in more detail in Section III. We start by comparing the typical number of pentagons per sheet using the traditional die with the number using the offset die. The dimensions of pentagons and hexagons vary slightly across orders, even for balls of a given official size (e.g., size 5, the standard size for adults), depending on the thickness and quality of the laminated rexine sheet used. The most commonly used pentagons have edge length 43.5 mm, 43.75 mm, 44 mm, or 44.25 mm after stitching. The first two columns of Table I report the means and standard deviations of the numbers of pentagons per sheet for each size, using a standard (39 in by 54 in) sheet of laminated rexine. Column (1) uses information from owner self-reports; we elicited the information in more than one round, and here we pool observations across rounds. Column (2) reports direct observations by our survey team, during the implementation of our first experiment. In the fifth row, we have multiplied the raw measures by the ratio of means for size 44 mm and the corresponding size; the rescaled measure provides an estimate of the number of pentagons per sheet the firm would obtain using a 44 mm die. The owner reports and direct observations correspond reasonably closely, with owners slightly overestimating pentagons per sheet relative to our direct observations. Both measures suggest that cutters obtain approximately 250 pentagons per sheet using the traditional die.
. | Traditional die . | . | Offset die . | ||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | Owner report . | Direct obs. . | . | Owner report . | Direct obs. . |
. | (1) . | (2) . | . | (3) . | (4) . |
Size 43.5 | 257.3 | 257.7 | 273.5 | 277.5 | |
(10.6) | (6.7) | (4.4) | (5.3) | ||
Size 43.75 | 256.3 | 254.4 | 269.0 | 272.0 | |
(6.7) | (9.4) | (1.4) | (0.0) | ||
Size 44 | 254.3 | 248.4 | 280.0 | 272.5 | |
(9.1) | (18.7) | (0.7) | |||
Size 44.25 | 246.1 | 262.0 | 272.0 | ||
(8.3) | |||||
Rescaled (to size 44) | 254.2 | 248.3 | 280.0 | 275.4 | |
(8.9) | (11.0) | (3.0) | (4.8) | ||
N (all sizes) | 320 | 39 | 8 | 10 |
. | Traditional die . | . | Offset die . | ||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | Owner report . | Direct obs. . | . | Owner report . | Direct obs. . |
. | (1) . | (2) . | . | (3) . | (4) . |
Size 43.5 | 257.3 | 257.7 | 273.5 | 277.5 | |
(10.6) | (6.7) | (4.4) | (5.3) | ||
Size 43.75 | 256.3 | 254.4 | 269.0 | 272.0 | |
(6.7) | (9.4) | (1.4) | (0.0) | ||
Size 44 | 254.3 | 248.4 | 280.0 | 272.5 | |
(9.1) | (18.7) | (0.7) | |||
Size 44.25 | 246.1 | 262.0 | 272.0 | ||
(8.3) | |||||
Rescaled (to size 44) | 254.2 | 248.3 | 280.0 | 275.4 | |
(8.9) | (11.0) | (3.0) | (4.8) | ||
N (all sizes) | 320 | 39 | 8 | 10 |
Notes. Table reports average (nondefective) pentagons per sheet by die size. Column (1) indicates self-reported numbers from the owner, several rounds per firm in some cases. Column (2) indicates pentagons per sheet directly observed by the survey team for tech-drop firms (during the initial cutting demonstration) and for cash-drop firms (at the time of the cash drop). Columns (3) and (4) report numbers for the offset die and were only collected from tech-drop firms. In the fifth row, pentagons per sheet are rescaled using means for each size in each column. The final row reports the pooled number of observations for all die sizes. Standard deviations (when more than one observation available) in parentheses.
. | Traditional die . | . | Offset die . | ||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | Owner report . | Direct obs. . | . | Owner report . | Direct obs. . |
. | (1) . | (2) . | . | (3) . | (4) . |
Size 43.5 | 257.3 | 257.7 | 273.5 | 277.5 | |
(10.6) | (6.7) | (4.4) | (5.3) | ||
Size 43.75 | 256.3 | 254.4 | 269.0 | 272.0 | |
(6.7) | (9.4) | (1.4) | (0.0) | ||
Size 44 | 254.3 | 248.4 | 280.0 | 272.5 | |
(9.1) | (18.7) | (0.7) | |||
Size 44.25 | 246.1 | 262.0 | 272.0 | ||
(8.3) | |||||
Rescaled (to size 44) | 254.2 | 248.3 | 280.0 | 275.4 | |
(8.9) | (11.0) | (3.0) | (4.8) | ||
N (all sizes) | 320 | 39 | 8 | 10 |
. | Traditional die . | . | Offset die . | ||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | Owner report . | Direct obs. . | . | Owner report . | Direct obs. . |
. | (1) . | (2) . | . | (3) . | (4) . |
Size 43.5 | 257.3 | 257.7 | 273.5 | 277.5 | |
(10.6) | (6.7) | (4.4) | (5.3) | ||
Size 43.75 | 256.3 | 254.4 | 269.0 | 272.0 | |
(6.7) | (9.4) | (1.4) | (0.0) | ||
Size 44 | 254.3 | 248.4 | 280.0 | 272.5 | |
(9.1) | (18.7) | (0.7) | |||
Size 44.25 | 246.1 | 262.0 | 272.0 | ||
(8.3) | |||||
Rescaled (to size 44) | 254.2 | 248.3 | 280.0 | 275.4 | |
(8.9) | (11.0) | (3.0) | (4.8) | ||
N (all sizes) | 320 | 39 | 8 | 10 |
Notes. Table reports average (nondefective) pentagons per sheet by die size. Column (1) indicates self-reported numbers from the owner, several rounds per firm in some cases. Column (2) indicates pentagons per sheet directly observed by the survey team for tech-drop firms (during the initial cutting demonstration) and for cash-drop firms (at the time of the cash drop). Columns (3) and (4) report numbers for the offset die and were only collected from tech-drop firms. In the fifth row, pentagons per sheet are rescaled using means for each size in each column. The final row reports the pooled number of observations for all die sizes. Standard deviations (when more than one observation available) in parentheses.
Using the offset die and cutting 44 mm pentagons, it is possible to achieve 272 pentagons per sheet, as illustrated in Figure IV.18 For 43.5 mm pentagons, it is possible to achieve 280 pentagons. Columns (3) and (4) of Table I report the means and standard deviations of pentagons per sheet using the offset die. As discussed in more detail below, relatively few firms have adopted the offset die, and therefore we have few observations. But even with this caveat, we can say with a high level of confidence that more pentagons can be obtained per sheet using the offset die. The directly observed (rescaled) mean is 275.4, and the standard errors indicate that the difference from the mean for the traditional die (either owner reports or direct observations) is significant at greater than the 99% level.
To convert these figures into cost savings, we need to know the proportion of costs that materials and cutting labor account for. Online Appendix Table A.1 provides a cost breakdown for a promotional ball obtained from our baseline survey.19 The table shows that the laminated rexine (rexine plus cotton/polyester plus latex) accounts for roughly half of the unit cost of production: 46% on average. The inflatable bladder is the second most important material input, accounting for 21% of the unit cost. Labor of all types accounts for 28%, but labor for cutting makes up less than 1% of the unit cost. In the second column, we report the input cost in rupees; the mean cost of a two-layer promotional ball is Rs 211 (US|${\$}$|2.11).20
The cost savings from the offset die vary across firms, depending in part on the type of rexine used and the number of layers of cloth glued to it, which themselves depend on a firm’s mix of promotional, training and match balls. In Table II, we present estimates of the distributions of the benefits and costs of adopting the offset die for firms. Not all firms were willing to provide a cost breakdown by input in the baseline survey, and only a subset of firms have adopted the offset die. To compute the distributions, we adopt a hot-deck imputation procedure that replaces a firm’s missing value for a particular cost component with a draw from the empirical distribution (i.e., nonmissing values) within the firm’s size stratum.21 Following Andridge and Little (2010), we bootstrap this entire procedure 1,000 times and calculate the quantiles and mean of each variable in each iteration, with the table reporting the mean and standard deviation for each statistic over the 1,000 iterations.
. | 10th . | 25th . | 50th . | 75th . | 90th . | Mean . |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Panel A: Variable cost reduction from reduced waste of material | ||||||
Reduction in pentagon | 4.24 | 5.56 | 6.76 | 8.02 | 10.15 | 6.93 |
laminated rexine cost (%) | (0.99) | (0.85) | (0.59) | (1.59) | (2.10) | (0.70) |
Laminated rexine as | 34.51 | 39.80 | 44.83 | 51.30 | 56.09 | 45.82 |
share of total cost (%) | (3.06) | (1.86) | (1.94) | (1.72) | (3.84) | (1.58) |
Variable cost reduction (%) | 0.59 | 0.77 | 0.98 | 1.24 | 1.62 | 1.05 |
(0.11) | (0.10) | (0.09) | (0.19) | (0.27) | (0.11) | |
Panel B: Variable cost increase from increased labor time | ||||||
Cutter wage as share | 0.30 | 0.36 | 0.45 | 0.59 | 0.71 | 0.48 |
of cost (%) | (0.03) | (0.01) | (0.02) | (0.03) | (0.04) | (0.02) |
Variable cost increase (%) | 0.10 | 0.12 | 0.15 | 0.19 | 0.23 | 0.16 |
(0.01) | (0.00) | (0.01) | (0.01) | (0.01) | (0.01) | |
Panel C: Net benefits | ||||||
Net variable cost | 0.42 | 0.61 | 0.82 | 1.09 | 1.47 | 0.89 |
reduction (%) | (0.11) | (0.10) | (0.09) | (0.19) | (0.27) | (0.11) |
% net variable cost | 4.55 | 6.82 | 10.63 | 16.56 | 24.42 | 13.07 |
red./avg % profit rate | (1.05) | (1.13) | (1.60) | (2.35) | (4.15) | (1.79) |
Total cost savings | 3.66 | 9.82 | 41.35 | 135.92 | 397.95 | 137.77 |
per month (Rs 000s) | (0.99) | (2.33) | (9.43) | (36.39) | (130.62) | (31.68) |
Total cost savings per | 2.75 | 6.47 | 14.91 | 33.83 | 63.61 | 27.31 |
cutter per month(Rs 000s) | (0.83) | (1.33) | (2.43) | (6.28) | (14.02) | (5.04) |
Days to recover fixed costs | 10.28 | 19.11 | 43.03 | 100.86 | 247.53 | 168.80 |
(2.23) | (3.66) | (7.37) | (21.74) | (76.42) | (84.72) | |
Days to recover fixed | 5.34 | 9.92 | 22.34 | 52.37 | 128.53 | 87.64 |
costs (no die) | (1.16) | (1.90) | (3.83) | (11.29) | (39.68) | (43.99) |
. | 10th . | 25th . | 50th . | 75th . | 90th . | Mean . |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Panel A: Variable cost reduction from reduced waste of material | ||||||
Reduction in pentagon | 4.24 | 5.56 | 6.76 | 8.02 | 10.15 | 6.93 |
laminated rexine cost (%) | (0.99) | (0.85) | (0.59) | (1.59) | (2.10) | (0.70) |
Laminated rexine as | 34.51 | 39.80 | 44.83 | 51.30 | 56.09 | 45.82 |
share of total cost (%) | (3.06) | (1.86) | (1.94) | (1.72) | (3.84) | (1.58) |
Variable cost reduction (%) | 0.59 | 0.77 | 0.98 | 1.24 | 1.62 | 1.05 |
(0.11) | (0.10) | (0.09) | (0.19) | (0.27) | (0.11) | |
Panel B: Variable cost increase from increased labor time | ||||||
Cutter wage as share | 0.30 | 0.36 | 0.45 | 0.59 | 0.71 | 0.48 |
of cost (%) | (0.03) | (0.01) | (0.02) | (0.03) | (0.04) | (0.02) |
Variable cost increase (%) | 0.10 | 0.12 | 0.15 | 0.19 | 0.23 | 0.16 |
(0.01) | (0.00) | (0.01) | (0.01) | (0.01) | (0.01) | |
Panel C: Net benefits | ||||||
Net variable cost | 0.42 | 0.61 | 0.82 | 1.09 | 1.47 | 0.89 |
reduction (%) | (0.11) | (0.10) | (0.09) | (0.19) | (0.27) | (0.11) |
% net variable cost | 4.55 | 6.82 | 10.63 | 16.56 | 24.42 | 13.07 |
red./avg % profit rate | (1.05) | (1.13) | (1.60) | (2.35) | (4.15) | (1.79) |
Total cost savings | 3.66 | 9.82 | 41.35 | 135.92 | 397.95 | 137.77 |
per month (Rs 000s) | (0.99) | (2.33) | (9.43) | (36.39) | (130.62) | (31.68) |
Total cost savings per | 2.75 | 6.47 | 14.91 | 33.83 | 63.61 | 27.31 |
cutter per month(Rs 000s) | (0.83) | (1.33) | (2.43) | (6.28) | (14.02) | (5.04) |
Days to recover fixed costs | 10.28 | 19.11 | 43.03 | 100.86 | 247.53 | 168.80 |
(2.23) | (3.66) | (7.37) | (21.74) | (76.42) | (84.72) | |
Days to recover fixed | 5.34 | 9.92 | 22.34 | 52.37 | 128.53 | 87.64 |
costs (no die) | (1.16) | (1.90) | (3.83) | (11.29) | (39.68) | (43.99) |
Notes. Each row reports the distribution across firms of indicated variable. First row: percentage reduction in per pentagon laminated rexine cost from adopting the offset die. Second row: laminated rexine cost as a percentage of total unit costs. Third row: variable cost reduction due to reduced waste of material, computed as product of reduction in per pentagon laminated rexine cost times 33% (share of pentagons relative to hexagons in total laminated rexine costs) times laminated rexine’s share of total cost. Fourth row: cutter’s wage as a share of unit costs. Fifth row: variable cost increase due to increased labor time, calculated as cutter wage share of cost times 33% (pentagon share of total laminated rexine cost) times 100% (conservative assumption of increase in cutting time). Sixth row: net variable cost reduction, that is, difference between variable cost reduction due to reduced wages and variable cost increase due to increased labor time. Seventh row: ratio of the net variable cost reduction to firm’s average profit margin. (The firm’s profit margin is a weighted average of its reported profit margin on promotional, training and match balls where the weights are the share of each ball type in total production.) Eighth row: total cost savings per month in rupees (exchange rate Rs 100 = US|${\$}$|1). Ninth row: cost savings per month per cutter in rupees. Tenth row: days needed to recover all fixed costs of adoption. Eleventh row: days needed to recover fixed costs of adoption, excluding purchase of the die (relevant for tech-drop firms which received the die for free). Table uses hot-deck imputation procedure to replace missing values with draws from distribution of nonmissing values for firm’s stratum. Entire procedure bootstrapped 1,000 times; quantiles and mean of each variable calculated for each iteration. Table reports mean and standard deviation for each statistic and variable.
. | 10th . | 25th . | 50th . | 75th . | 90th . | Mean . |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Panel A: Variable cost reduction from reduced waste of material | ||||||
Reduction in pentagon | 4.24 | 5.56 | 6.76 | 8.02 | 10.15 | 6.93 |
laminated rexine cost (%) | (0.99) | (0.85) | (0.59) | (1.59) | (2.10) | (0.70) |
Laminated rexine as | 34.51 | 39.80 | 44.83 | 51.30 | 56.09 | 45.82 |
share of total cost (%) | (3.06) | (1.86) | (1.94) | (1.72) | (3.84) | (1.58) |
Variable cost reduction (%) | 0.59 | 0.77 | 0.98 | 1.24 | 1.62 | 1.05 |
(0.11) | (0.10) | (0.09) | (0.19) | (0.27) | (0.11) | |
Panel B: Variable cost increase from increased labor time | ||||||
Cutter wage as share | 0.30 | 0.36 | 0.45 | 0.59 | 0.71 | 0.48 |
of cost (%) | (0.03) | (0.01) | (0.02) | (0.03) | (0.04) | (0.02) |
Variable cost increase (%) | 0.10 | 0.12 | 0.15 | 0.19 | 0.23 | 0.16 |
(0.01) | (0.00) | (0.01) | (0.01) | (0.01) | (0.01) | |
Panel C: Net benefits | ||||||
Net variable cost | 0.42 | 0.61 | 0.82 | 1.09 | 1.47 | 0.89 |
reduction (%) | (0.11) | (0.10) | (0.09) | (0.19) | (0.27) | (0.11) |
% net variable cost | 4.55 | 6.82 | 10.63 | 16.56 | 24.42 | 13.07 |
red./avg % profit rate | (1.05) | (1.13) | (1.60) | (2.35) | (4.15) | (1.79) |
Total cost savings | 3.66 | 9.82 | 41.35 | 135.92 | 397.95 | 137.77 |
per month (Rs 000s) | (0.99) | (2.33) | (9.43) | (36.39) | (130.62) | (31.68) |
Total cost savings per | 2.75 | 6.47 | 14.91 | 33.83 | 63.61 | 27.31 |
cutter per month(Rs 000s) | (0.83) | (1.33) | (2.43) | (6.28) | (14.02) | (5.04) |
Days to recover fixed costs | 10.28 | 19.11 | 43.03 | 100.86 | 247.53 | 168.80 |
(2.23) | (3.66) | (7.37) | (21.74) | (76.42) | (84.72) | |
Days to recover fixed | 5.34 | 9.92 | 22.34 | 52.37 | 128.53 | 87.64 |
costs (no die) | (1.16) | (1.90) | (3.83) | (11.29) | (39.68) | (43.99) |
. | 10th . | 25th . | 50th . | 75th . | 90th . | Mean . |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Panel A: Variable cost reduction from reduced waste of material | ||||||
Reduction in pentagon | 4.24 | 5.56 | 6.76 | 8.02 | 10.15 | 6.93 |
laminated rexine cost (%) | (0.99) | (0.85) | (0.59) | (1.59) | (2.10) | (0.70) |
Laminated rexine as | 34.51 | 39.80 | 44.83 | 51.30 | 56.09 | 45.82 |
share of total cost (%) | (3.06) | (1.86) | (1.94) | (1.72) | (3.84) | (1.58) |
Variable cost reduction (%) | 0.59 | 0.77 | 0.98 | 1.24 | 1.62 | 1.05 |
(0.11) | (0.10) | (0.09) | (0.19) | (0.27) | (0.11) | |
Panel B: Variable cost increase from increased labor time | ||||||
Cutter wage as share | 0.30 | 0.36 | 0.45 | 0.59 | 0.71 | 0.48 |
of cost (%) | (0.03) | (0.01) | (0.02) | (0.03) | (0.04) | (0.02) |
Variable cost increase (%) | 0.10 | 0.12 | 0.15 | 0.19 | 0.23 | 0.16 |
(0.01) | (0.00) | (0.01) | (0.01) | (0.01) | (0.01) | |
Panel C: Net benefits | ||||||
Net variable cost | 0.42 | 0.61 | 0.82 | 1.09 | 1.47 | 0.89 |
reduction (%) | (0.11) | (0.10) | (0.09) | (0.19) | (0.27) | (0.11) |
% net variable cost | 4.55 | 6.82 | 10.63 | 16.56 | 24.42 | 13.07 |
red./avg % profit rate | (1.05) | (1.13) | (1.60) | (2.35) | (4.15) | (1.79) |
Total cost savings | 3.66 | 9.82 | 41.35 | 135.92 | 397.95 | 137.77 |
per month (Rs 000s) | (0.99) | (2.33) | (9.43) | (36.39) | (130.62) | (31.68) |
Total cost savings per | 2.75 | 6.47 | 14.91 | 33.83 | 63.61 | 27.31 |
cutter per month(Rs 000s) | (0.83) | (1.33) | (2.43) | (6.28) | (14.02) | (5.04) |
Days to recover fixed costs | 10.28 | 19.11 | 43.03 | 100.86 | 247.53 | 168.80 |
(2.23) | (3.66) | (7.37) | (21.74) | (76.42) | (84.72) | |
Days to recover fixed | 5.34 | 9.92 | 22.34 | 52.37 | 128.53 | 87.64 |
costs (no die) | (1.16) | (1.90) | (3.83) | (11.29) | (39.68) | (43.99) |
Notes. Each row reports the distribution across firms of indicated variable. First row: percentage reduction in per pentagon laminated rexine cost from adopting the offset die. Second row: laminated rexine cost as a percentage of total unit costs. Third row: variable cost reduction due to reduced waste of material, computed as product of reduction in per pentagon laminated rexine cost times 33% (share of pentagons relative to hexagons in total laminated rexine costs) times laminated rexine’s share of total cost. Fourth row: cutter’s wage as a share of unit costs. Fifth row: variable cost increase due to increased labor time, calculated as cutter wage share of cost times 33% (pentagon share of total laminated rexine cost) times 100% (conservative assumption of increase in cutting time). Sixth row: net variable cost reduction, that is, difference between variable cost reduction due to reduced wages and variable cost increase due to increased labor time. Seventh row: ratio of the net variable cost reduction to firm’s average profit margin. (The firm’s profit margin is a weighted average of its reported profit margin on promotional, training and match balls where the weights are the share of each ball type in total production.) Eighth row: total cost savings per month in rupees (exchange rate Rs 100 = US|${\$}$|1). Ninth row: cost savings per month per cutter in rupees. Tenth row: days needed to recover all fixed costs of adoption. Eleventh row: days needed to recover fixed costs of adoption, excluding purchase of the die (relevant for tech-drop firms which received the die for free). Table uses hot-deck imputation procedure to replace missing values with draws from distribution of nonmissing values for firm’s stratum. Entire procedure bootstrapped 1,000 times; quantiles and mean of each variable calculated for each iteration. Table reports mean and standard deviation for each statistic and variable.
In the first row of Table II, we report the distribution of the percentage reduction in the cost of laminated rexine used to cut pentagons when moving to the offset die. The pentagon cost reduction is 6.76% at the median and ranges from 4.24% at the 10th percentile to 10.15% at the 90th percentile. Combining these figures with the laminated rexine share of total unit costs (which has the distribution reported in the second row) and multiplying by 33% (the share of pentagons in total laminated rexine costs, since a standard ball uses more hexagons than pentagons and the hexagons are bigger) yields the percentage reduction in variable material costs reported in the third row. The reduction in variable material costs is 0.98% at the median and ranges from 0.59% at the 10th percentile to 1.62% at the 90th percentile.22
The offset die requires cutters to be more careful in the placement of the die when cutting, at least while they are learning how to use it. A conservative estimate of the increase in labor time for cutters (for the preferred two-pentagon variant) is 100%.23 (In Section VI.B we discuss why the 100% number is very conservative.) If firms compensate workers for this extra labor time, labor costs will increase. The fourth row of Table II reports the distribution of the cutter’s wage as a share of unit costs across firms. As noted earlier, the cutter’s share of cost is quite low.24 Multiplying the cutter share by 33% (assuming that pentagons take up one third of cutting time, equivalent to their share of laminated rexine cost) and then by 100% (our conservative estimate of the increase in labor time) yields the percentage increase in variable labor costs from adopting the offset die if the firms were to compensate workers (fifth row). Although the offset die is slower and requires more care to use, our surveys suggest that firms were not concerned that adoption would lead them to miss more deadlines or increase defect rates.25
Although the proportional increase in cutting time is potentially large, the cutter’s share of costs is sufficiently low that the variable labor cost increase is very small. The sixth row reports the net variable cost reduction, the difference between the variable materials cost reduction and the variable labor cost increase. The net variable cost reduction is 0.82% at the median, and ranges from 0.42% at the 10th percentile to 1.47% at the 90th percentile. Although these numbers are small in absolute terms, the cost reductions are not trivial given the low profit margins in the industry: 8.39% at the median and 8.42% at the mean. The seventh row shows the ratio of the net variable cost reductions to average profits; the mean and median ratios are 13.07% and 10.63%, respectively. If we multiply the net variable cost reduction by total monthly output, we obtain the total monthly savings, in rupees, from adopting the offset die (eighth row). The large variation in output across firms induces a high degree of heterogeneity in total monthly cost savings. The mean and median monthly cost savings are Rs 137,770 (US|${\$}$|273) and Rs 41,350 (US|${\$}$|413), respectively, and savings range from Rs 3,660 (US|${\$}$|37) at the 10th percentile to Rs 397,950 (US|${\$}$|3,980) at the 90th percentile.
These reductions in variable cost must be compared with the fixed costs of adopting the offset die. There are a number of such costs, but they are modest in monetary terms. The market price for a two-pentagon offset die is approximately Rs 10,000 (|${\$}$|100). As we explain below, we paid this fixed cost for the firms in the tech-drop group. The offset die requires few changes to other aspects of the production process, since the pentagons it cuts are identical to the pentagons cut by the traditional die, but there are two adjustments that many firms make, related to the fact that pairs of pentagons cut by the offset die remain attached in a different way (i.e., sharing half an edge) than those cut by the traditional die. First, for balls with printed pentagons the printing screens must be redesigned and remade to match the offset pattern. Designers typically charge Rs 600 (US|${\$}$|6) for a new design; for the minority of firms that do not have in-house screenmaking capabilities, a new screen costs Rs 200 (US|${\$}$|2) from an outside screenmaker. (In any case, new screens must be made for any new order, but we include them to be conservative.) Second, some firms use a “combing” machine, a device to enlarge the holes at the edges of panels made by the cutting die to further facilitate sewing. These machines also use dies. A two-pentagon combing die that works with pentagons cut by the two-pentagon offset die costs approximately Rs 10,000 (US|${\$}$|100). For both printing and combing, it is always possible to cut and work with separate pentagons, but there is a speed benefit to keeping the pairs of pentagons attached. Adding together the cost of the die, the cost of a new screen design and screen, and a new combing die (that not all firms use), a conservative estimate of total fixed costs of adoption is Rs 20,800 (US|${\$}$|208).
A common way for firms to make calculations about the desirability of adoption is to use a rule of thumb (or “hurdle”) for the length of time required to recoup the fixed costs of adoption (the “payback period”). Reviewing a variety of studies from the United States and United Kingdom, Lefley (1996) reports that the “hurdles” vary from two to four years, whereas Anderson and Newell (2004) infer from energy-efficiency audits in the United States that firms are using hurdles of one to two years. The final two rows of Table II report the distribution of the number of days needed to recover the fixed costs of adoption detailed above. For this calculation, we calculate output per cutter per month and hence the cost savings per cutter per month (ninth row). Dividing our conservative estimate of per cutter fixed costs (assuming that each cutter needs his own offset die and combing die) by the cost savings per cutter gives the number of days needed to recoup the fixed costs, reported in the 10th row. The median firm can recover all fixed costs within 43 days; the payback period ranges from 10 days at the 10th percentile to 248 days at the 90th percentile (which corresponds to firms that produce very few balls). The final row reports the distribution of days to recover fixed costs that exclude the cost of purchasing the die; this row is relevant for the tech-drop firms, to which we gave dies at no cost. In this scenario, the median time to recover fixed costs is only 22 days, and three-quarters of firms can recover the fixed costs within eight weeks. In short, the available evidence indicates that for almost all firms, assuming that they are not extraordinarily myopic, there are clear net benefits to adopting the offset die.
III. Data and Summary Statistics
Between September and November 2011, we conducted a listing exercise of soccer-ball producers within Sialkot. We found 157 producers that we believed were active in the sense that they had produced soccer balls in the previous 12 months and cut their own laminated rexine. Of the 157 firms on our initial list, we subsequently discovered that 22 were not active by our definition. Of the remaining 135 firms, 3 served as pilot firms for testing our technology.
We carried out a baseline survey between January and June 2012. Of the 132 active nonpilot firms, 85 answered the survey; we refer to them as the “initial responder” sample. The low response rate was in part due to negative experiences with previous surveyors. (In the mid-1990s, there was a child-labor scandal in the industry in Sialkot. Firm owners were initially quite distrustful of us in part for that reason.) In subsequent survey rounds, our reputation in Sialkot improved and we were able to collect information from an additional 31 of the 47 nonresponding producers (the “late responder” sample), to bring the total number of responders to 116. The baseline survey collected firm and owner characteristics, standard performance variables (e.g., output, employment, prices, product mix, and inputs) and information about firms’ networks (supplier, family, employee, and business networks). To date, we have conducted seven subsequent survey rounds: July 2012, October 2012, January 2013, March–April 2013, September–November 2013, January–March 2014, and October–December 2014. The follow-up surveys have again collected information on the various performance measures and information pertinent to the adoption of the new cutting technology. In tech-drop firms, we have explicitly asked about usage of the offset die. For the other groups, we have sought to determine whether firms are using the offset die without explicitly mentioning it, by probing indirectly about changes in the factory. In addition, we have obtained reports of sales of the offset dies from the six diemakers operating in Sialkot. We have detailed information on the dates firms have ordered offset dies from the diemakers, the dates the diemakers delivered the dies, and the number of offset dies purchased. Based on this information, we believe that we have complete knowledge of offset dies purchased in Sialkot, even by firms that have never responded to any of our surveys.
We face three important choices about how to measure adoption. One is whether to impose a lower bound on the number of balls produced with the offset die. Several firms have reported that they have experimented with the die but have not actually used it for a client’s order. To be conservative, we have chosen not to count such firms as adopters. Our preferred measure of adoption requires that firms have produced at least 1,000 balls with the offset die. The measure is not particularly sensitive to the lower bound; we perform robustness checks using different cutoffs in Section VI.B. (See note 45.) A second decision we face is how to deal with the volatility of orders and output in the industry. Many of the smaller and medium-sized firms have large orders some months and no orders in others. In addition, a particular offset die may not be useful on all orders. Ball designs and pentagon/hexagon sizes requested by clients vary, and clients have been known to request that firms use exactly the same dies as on previous orders. For these reasons, we consider the number of balls ever produced (rather than produced in the past month) with the offset die when constructing the adoption measure. The third choice we face is whether to use information we gained from firms outside of the formal survey process. Because we have been concerned about recall bias over periods of more than one month, our surveys have asked firms about their production in the previous month. However, our project team has been in regular, ongoing contact with firms, including between survey rounds, and has submitted field notes that summarize these interactions. In one case in particular, the firm told our enumerators that it had produced more than 1,000 balls using the offset die, but that order did not happen to fall in the month preceding a survey wave. To address this issue, we construct two measures of adoption: a conservative measure that classifies adoption using only survey data, and a liberal measure that classifies adoption using both survey data and field reports. Our preferred measure uses the liberal definition because it incorporates all the information we have regarding firms’ activities, but we report results for both measures.
Table III presents summary statistics on various firm characteristics, including means and values at several quantiles. Panel A reports statistics for the sample of 85 initial responders and Panel B for the full sample that also includes the 31 late responders. Because the late responders did not respond to the baseline, we have a smaller set of variables for the full sample. Because firms’ responses are often noisy, where possible we have taken within-firm averages across all survey rounds for which we have responses (indicated by “Avg ...” at the beginning of variable names in the table). Focusing on the initial-responder sample where we have more complete data, a number of facts are worth emphasizing. The median firm is medium-size (18.3 employees, producing 10,000 balls/month), but there are also some very large firms (the highest reported employment and production are 1,700 people and 275,000 balls a month, respectively).26 Profit rates vary across ball types but are generally low, approximately 8% at the median and 12% at the 90th percentile. (For further discussion of the heterogeneity in profit rates [mark-ups] across firms, see Atkin et al. 2015.) The corresponding firm size and profit margins in the full sample (Panel B) are slightly larger, indicating that the late responders are larger and more profitable than the initial responders. For most firms, all or nearly all of their production of size 5 balls uses the standard 20 hexagon–12 pentagon design. The industry is relatively mature; firm age is 19.5 years at the median and 54 years at the 90th percentile. Finally, cutters tend to have high tenure; the mean tenure in the current firm for a head cutter is 11 years (9 years at the median). One other salient fact is that the vast majority of firms pay pure piece rates to their cutters and printers. Among the initial responders, 79 of 85 firms pay a piece rate to their cutters, with the remainder paying a daily, weekly, or monthly salary sometimes accompanied by performance bonuses.27
. | Mean . | Min . | 10th . | 25th . | 50th . | 75th . | 90th . | Max . | N . |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Panel A: Initial responder sample | |||||||||
Avg output/month (000s) | 31.2 | 0.8 | 1.5 | 3.2 | 10.0 | 34.1 | 71.7 | 275.0 | 85 |
Avg employment | 89.8 | 4.0 | 5.6 | 7.4 | 18.3 | 50.0 | 235.0 | 1,700.0 | 85 |
Avg employment(cutters) | 5.6 | 0.7 | 1.0 | 1.0 | 2.2 | 5.0 | 12.0 | 123.0 | 85 |
Avg Rs/ball(head cutter) | 1.5 | 1.0 | 1.2 | 1.3 | 1.5 | 1.6 | 1.9 | 2.9 | 79 |
Avg % size 5 | 89.4 | 52.4 | 68.1 | 84.0 | 94.0 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 85 |
Avg % size 4 | 3.1 | 0.0 | 0.0 | 0.0 | 0.0 | 4.1 | 7.8 | 35.0 | 85 |
Avg % size other | 7.5 | 0.0 | 0.0 | 0.0 | 1.7 | 11.2 | 20.0 | 47.6 | 85 |
Avg % promotional(of size 5) | 41.4 | 0.0 | 2.0 | 18.8 | 41.1 | 62.4 | 80.0 | 100.0 | 85 |
Avg price, size 5promotional | 243.1 | 152.5 | 185.0 | 200.0 | 231.2 | 269.1 | 300.0 | 575.0 | 64 |
Avg price, size 5training | 441.3 | 200.0 | 275.0 | 316.7 | 392.5 | 490.0 | 600.0 | 2,250.0 | 73 |
Avg profit %,size 5 promo | 8.1 | 2.6 | 3.9 | 5.0 | 7.9 | 10.2 | 12.5 | 20.0 | 64 |
Avg profit %, size 5training | 7.9 | 1.6 | 3.2 | 4.6 | 7.8 | 9.9 | 11.8 | 22.2 | 71 |
Avg % laminationin-house | 95.7 | 31.2 | 81.2 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 75 |
% standard design(of size 5) | 90.7 | 0.0 | 70.0 | 85.0 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 80 |
Age of firm | 25.4 | 2.0 | 6.0 | 12.0 | 19.5 | 36.5 | 54.0 | 108.0 | 84 |
CEO experience | 17.0 | 3.0 | 6.0 | 9.0 | 15.5 | 22.0 | 28.0 | 66.0 | 82 |
Head cutterexperience | 20.5 | 2.0 | 8.0 | 12.0 | 18.5 | 26.5 | 41.0 | 46.0 | 36 |
Head cuttertenure | 11.1 | 0.0 | 2.0 | 6.0 | 9.0 | 15.0 | 22.0 | 46.0 | 35 |
Panel B: Full sample | |||||||||
Avg output/month (000s) | 33.4 | 0.0 | 1.6 | 4.6 | 15.2 | 37.0 | 86.2 | 275.0 | 116 |
Avg employment | 103.2 | 4.0 | 6.0 | 8.2 | 24.9 | 75.0 | 227.0 | 2,180.0 | 115 |
Avg employment(cutters) | 5.2 | 0.7 | 1.0 | 1.2 | 2.4 | 5.0 | 12.0 | 123.0 | 115 |
Avg Rs/ball(head cutter) | 1.6 | 1.0 | 1.1 | 1.3 | 1.5 | 1.7 | 2.1 | 3.0 | 108 |
Avg % size 5 | 88.6 | 42.8 | 64.2 | 83.3 | 94.4 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 115 |
Avg % size 4 | 2.5 | 0.0 | 0.0 | 0.0 | 0.0 | 3.3 | 6.0 | 35.0 | 115 |
Avg % size other | 8.9 | 0.0 | 0.0 | 0.0 | 2.2 | 13.3 | 31.9 | 57.2 | 115 |
Avg % promotional(of size 5) | 37.0 | 0.0 | 0.0 | 8.3 | 33.8 | 55.2 | 80.0 | 100.0 | 114 |
Avg price, size 5promotional | 248.6 | 150.0 | 185.0 | 205.0 | 236.7 | 270.0 | 310.0 | 575.0 | 83 |
Avg price, size 5training | 465.3 | 200.0 | 300.0 | 335.2 | 400.0 | 508.2 | 662.5 | 2,250.0 | 102 |
Avg profit (%),size 5 promo | 8.1 | 2.6 | 3.9 | 5.0 | 7.4 | 10.4 | 13.6 | 20.0 | 82 |
Avg profit (%),size 5 training | 8.1 | 1.6 | 3.2 | 5.0 | 8.0 | 10.0 | 13.0 | 22.2 | 98 |
Avg % laminationin-house | 96.2 | 25.0 | 85.0 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 104 |
. | Mean . | Min . | 10th . | 25th . | 50th . | 75th . | 90th . | Max . | N . |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Panel A: Initial responder sample | |||||||||
Avg output/month (000s) | 31.2 | 0.8 | 1.5 | 3.2 | 10.0 | 34.1 | 71.7 | 275.0 | 85 |
Avg employment | 89.8 | 4.0 | 5.6 | 7.4 | 18.3 | 50.0 | 235.0 | 1,700.0 | 85 |
Avg employment(cutters) | 5.6 | 0.7 | 1.0 | 1.0 | 2.2 | 5.0 | 12.0 | 123.0 | 85 |
Avg Rs/ball(head cutter) | 1.5 | 1.0 | 1.2 | 1.3 | 1.5 | 1.6 | 1.9 | 2.9 | 79 |
Avg % size 5 | 89.4 | 52.4 | 68.1 | 84.0 | 94.0 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 85 |
Avg % size 4 | 3.1 | 0.0 | 0.0 | 0.0 | 0.0 | 4.1 | 7.8 | 35.0 | 85 |
Avg % size other | 7.5 | 0.0 | 0.0 | 0.0 | 1.7 | 11.2 | 20.0 | 47.6 | 85 |
Avg % promotional(of size 5) | 41.4 | 0.0 | 2.0 | 18.8 | 41.1 | 62.4 | 80.0 | 100.0 | 85 |
Avg price, size 5promotional | 243.1 | 152.5 | 185.0 | 200.0 | 231.2 | 269.1 | 300.0 | 575.0 | 64 |
Avg price, size 5training | 441.3 | 200.0 | 275.0 | 316.7 | 392.5 | 490.0 | 600.0 | 2,250.0 | 73 |
Avg profit %,size 5 promo | 8.1 | 2.6 | 3.9 | 5.0 | 7.9 | 10.2 | 12.5 | 20.0 | 64 |
Avg profit %, size 5training | 7.9 | 1.6 | 3.2 | 4.6 | 7.8 | 9.9 | 11.8 | 22.2 | 71 |
Avg % laminationin-house | 95.7 | 31.2 | 81.2 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 75 |
% standard design(of size 5) | 90.7 | 0.0 | 70.0 | 85.0 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 80 |
Age of firm | 25.4 | 2.0 | 6.0 | 12.0 | 19.5 | 36.5 | 54.0 | 108.0 | 84 |
CEO experience | 17.0 | 3.0 | 6.0 | 9.0 | 15.5 | 22.0 | 28.0 | 66.0 | 82 |
Head cutterexperience | 20.5 | 2.0 | 8.0 | 12.0 | 18.5 | 26.5 | 41.0 | 46.0 | 36 |
Head cuttertenure | 11.1 | 0.0 | 2.0 | 6.0 | 9.0 | 15.0 | 22.0 | 46.0 | 35 |
Panel B: Full sample | |||||||||
Avg output/month (000s) | 33.4 | 0.0 | 1.6 | 4.6 | 15.2 | 37.0 | 86.2 | 275.0 | 116 |
Avg employment | 103.2 | 4.0 | 6.0 | 8.2 | 24.9 | 75.0 | 227.0 | 2,180.0 | 115 |
Avg employment(cutters) | 5.2 | 0.7 | 1.0 | 1.2 | 2.4 | 5.0 | 12.0 | 123.0 | 115 |
Avg Rs/ball(head cutter) | 1.6 | 1.0 | 1.1 | 1.3 | 1.5 | 1.7 | 2.1 | 3.0 | 108 |
Avg % size 5 | 88.6 | 42.8 | 64.2 | 83.3 | 94.4 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 115 |
Avg % size 4 | 2.5 | 0.0 | 0.0 | 0.0 | 0.0 | 3.3 | 6.0 | 35.0 | 115 |
Avg % size other | 8.9 | 0.0 | 0.0 | 0.0 | 2.2 | 13.3 | 31.9 | 57.2 | 115 |
Avg % promotional(of size 5) | 37.0 | 0.0 | 0.0 | 8.3 | 33.8 | 55.2 | 80.0 | 100.0 | 114 |
Avg price, size 5promotional | 248.6 | 150.0 | 185.0 | 205.0 | 236.7 | 270.0 | 310.0 | 575.0 | 83 |
Avg price, size 5training | 465.3 | 200.0 | 300.0 | 335.2 | 400.0 | 508.2 | 662.5 | 2,250.0 | 102 |
Avg profit (%),size 5 promo | 8.1 | 2.6 | 3.9 | 5.0 | 7.4 | 10.4 | 13.6 | 20.0 | 82 |
Avg profit (%),size 5 training | 8.1 | 1.6 | 3.2 | 5.0 | 8.0 | 10.0 | 13.0 | 22.2 | 98 |
Avg % laminationin-house | 96.2 | 25.0 | 85.0 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 104 |
Notes. Variables beginning with “Avg” represent within-firm averages across all rounds for which responses are available. Initial responder sample contains firms that responded to baseline survey. Piece rate and prices are in rupees (exchange rate 100 Rs = US|${\$}$|1). Size 5 is regulation size for adults; size 4 is commonly used by children; Avg % size other refers to sizes 1, 2, and 3. % standard design (of size 5) refers to percentage of size 5 balls produced with standard 20 hexagon–12 pentagon design. Age, experience, and tenure in years. Firms with missing values in all rounds in which questions were asked are dropped (hence the variation in N in final column).
. | Mean . | Min . | 10th . | 25th . | 50th . | 75th . | 90th . | Max . | N . |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Panel A: Initial responder sample | |||||||||
Avg output/month (000s) | 31.2 | 0.8 | 1.5 | 3.2 | 10.0 | 34.1 | 71.7 | 275.0 | 85 |
Avg employment | 89.8 | 4.0 | 5.6 | 7.4 | 18.3 | 50.0 | 235.0 | 1,700.0 | 85 |
Avg employment(cutters) | 5.6 | 0.7 | 1.0 | 1.0 | 2.2 | 5.0 | 12.0 | 123.0 | 85 |
Avg Rs/ball(head cutter) | 1.5 | 1.0 | 1.2 | 1.3 | 1.5 | 1.6 | 1.9 | 2.9 | 79 |
Avg % size 5 | 89.4 | 52.4 | 68.1 | 84.0 | 94.0 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 85 |
Avg % size 4 | 3.1 | 0.0 | 0.0 | 0.0 | 0.0 | 4.1 | 7.8 | 35.0 | 85 |
Avg % size other | 7.5 | 0.0 | 0.0 | 0.0 | 1.7 | 11.2 | 20.0 | 47.6 | 85 |
Avg % promotional(of size 5) | 41.4 | 0.0 | 2.0 | 18.8 | 41.1 | 62.4 | 80.0 | 100.0 | 85 |
Avg price, size 5promotional | 243.1 | 152.5 | 185.0 | 200.0 | 231.2 | 269.1 | 300.0 | 575.0 | 64 |
Avg price, size 5training | 441.3 | 200.0 | 275.0 | 316.7 | 392.5 | 490.0 | 600.0 | 2,250.0 | 73 |
Avg profit %,size 5 promo | 8.1 | 2.6 | 3.9 | 5.0 | 7.9 | 10.2 | 12.5 | 20.0 | 64 |
Avg profit %, size 5training | 7.9 | 1.6 | 3.2 | 4.6 | 7.8 | 9.9 | 11.8 | 22.2 | 71 |
Avg % laminationin-house | 95.7 | 31.2 | 81.2 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 75 |
% standard design(of size 5) | 90.7 | 0.0 | 70.0 | 85.0 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 80 |
Age of firm | 25.4 | 2.0 | 6.0 | 12.0 | 19.5 | 36.5 | 54.0 | 108.0 | 84 |
CEO experience | 17.0 | 3.0 | 6.0 | 9.0 | 15.5 | 22.0 | 28.0 | 66.0 | 82 |
Head cutterexperience | 20.5 | 2.0 | 8.0 | 12.0 | 18.5 | 26.5 | 41.0 | 46.0 | 36 |
Head cuttertenure | 11.1 | 0.0 | 2.0 | 6.0 | 9.0 | 15.0 | 22.0 | 46.0 | 35 |
Panel B: Full sample | |||||||||
Avg output/month (000s) | 33.4 | 0.0 | 1.6 | 4.6 | 15.2 | 37.0 | 86.2 | 275.0 | 116 |
Avg employment | 103.2 | 4.0 | 6.0 | 8.2 | 24.9 | 75.0 | 227.0 | 2,180.0 | 115 |
Avg employment(cutters) | 5.2 | 0.7 | 1.0 | 1.2 | 2.4 | 5.0 | 12.0 | 123.0 | 115 |
Avg Rs/ball(head cutter) | 1.6 | 1.0 | 1.1 | 1.3 | 1.5 | 1.7 | 2.1 | 3.0 | 108 |
Avg % size 5 | 88.6 | 42.8 | 64.2 | 83.3 | 94.4 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 115 |
Avg % size 4 | 2.5 | 0.0 | 0.0 | 0.0 | 0.0 | 3.3 | 6.0 | 35.0 | 115 |
Avg % size other | 8.9 | 0.0 | 0.0 | 0.0 | 2.2 | 13.3 | 31.9 | 57.2 | 115 |
Avg % promotional(of size 5) | 37.0 | 0.0 | 0.0 | 8.3 | 33.8 | 55.2 | 80.0 | 100.0 | 114 |
Avg price, size 5promotional | 248.6 | 150.0 | 185.0 | 205.0 | 236.7 | 270.0 | 310.0 | 575.0 | 83 |
Avg price, size 5training | 465.3 | 200.0 | 300.0 | 335.2 | 400.0 | 508.2 | 662.5 | 2,250.0 | 102 |
Avg profit (%),size 5 promo | 8.1 | 2.6 | 3.9 | 5.0 | 7.4 | 10.4 | 13.6 | 20.0 | 82 |
Avg profit (%),size 5 training | 8.1 | 1.6 | 3.2 | 5.0 | 8.0 | 10.0 | 13.0 | 22.2 | 98 |
Avg % laminationin-house | 96.2 | 25.0 | 85.0 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 104 |
. | Mean . | Min . | 10th . | 25th . | 50th . | 75th . | 90th . | Max . | N . |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Panel A: Initial responder sample | |||||||||
Avg output/month (000s) | 31.2 | 0.8 | 1.5 | 3.2 | 10.0 | 34.1 | 71.7 | 275.0 | 85 |
Avg employment | 89.8 | 4.0 | 5.6 | 7.4 | 18.3 | 50.0 | 235.0 | 1,700.0 | 85 |
Avg employment(cutters) | 5.6 | 0.7 | 1.0 | 1.0 | 2.2 | 5.0 | 12.0 | 123.0 | 85 |
Avg Rs/ball(head cutter) | 1.5 | 1.0 | 1.2 | 1.3 | 1.5 | 1.6 | 1.9 | 2.9 | 79 |
Avg % size 5 | 89.4 | 52.4 | 68.1 | 84.0 | 94.0 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 85 |
Avg % size 4 | 3.1 | 0.0 | 0.0 | 0.0 | 0.0 | 4.1 | 7.8 | 35.0 | 85 |
Avg % size other | 7.5 | 0.0 | 0.0 | 0.0 | 1.7 | 11.2 | 20.0 | 47.6 | 85 |
Avg % promotional(of size 5) | 41.4 | 0.0 | 2.0 | 18.8 | 41.1 | 62.4 | 80.0 | 100.0 | 85 |
Avg price, size 5promotional | 243.1 | 152.5 | 185.0 | 200.0 | 231.2 | 269.1 | 300.0 | 575.0 | 64 |
Avg price, size 5training | 441.3 | 200.0 | 275.0 | 316.7 | 392.5 | 490.0 | 600.0 | 2,250.0 | 73 |
Avg profit %,size 5 promo | 8.1 | 2.6 | 3.9 | 5.0 | 7.9 | 10.2 | 12.5 | 20.0 | 64 |
Avg profit %, size 5training | 7.9 | 1.6 | 3.2 | 4.6 | 7.8 | 9.9 | 11.8 | 22.2 | 71 |
Avg % laminationin-house | 95.7 | 31.2 | 81.2 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 75 |
% standard design(of size 5) | 90.7 | 0.0 | 70.0 | 85.0 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 80 |
Age of firm | 25.4 | 2.0 | 6.0 | 12.0 | 19.5 | 36.5 | 54.0 | 108.0 | 84 |
CEO experience | 17.0 | 3.0 | 6.0 | 9.0 | 15.5 | 22.0 | 28.0 | 66.0 | 82 |
Head cutterexperience | 20.5 | 2.0 | 8.0 | 12.0 | 18.5 | 26.5 | 41.0 | 46.0 | 36 |
Head cuttertenure | 11.1 | 0.0 | 2.0 | 6.0 | 9.0 | 15.0 | 22.0 | 46.0 | 35 |
Panel B: Full sample | |||||||||
Avg output/month (000s) | 33.4 | 0.0 | 1.6 | 4.6 | 15.2 | 37.0 | 86.2 | 275.0 | 116 |
Avg employment | 103.2 | 4.0 | 6.0 | 8.2 | 24.9 | 75.0 | 227.0 | 2,180.0 | 115 |
Avg employment(cutters) | 5.2 | 0.7 | 1.0 | 1.2 | 2.4 | 5.0 | 12.0 | 123.0 | 115 |
Avg Rs/ball(head cutter) | 1.6 | 1.0 | 1.1 | 1.3 | 1.5 | 1.7 | 2.1 | 3.0 | 108 |
Avg % size 5 | 88.6 | 42.8 | 64.2 | 83.3 | 94.4 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 115 |
Avg % size 4 | 2.5 | 0.0 | 0.0 | 0.0 | 0.0 | 3.3 | 6.0 | 35.0 | 115 |
Avg % size other | 8.9 | 0.0 | 0.0 | 0.0 | 2.2 | 13.3 | 31.9 | 57.2 | 115 |
Avg % promotional(of size 5) | 37.0 | 0.0 | 0.0 | 8.3 | 33.8 | 55.2 | 80.0 | 100.0 | 114 |
Avg price, size 5promotional | 248.6 | 150.0 | 185.0 | 205.0 | 236.7 | 270.0 | 310.0 | 575.0 | 83 |
Avg price, size 5training | 465.3 | 200.0 | 300.0 | 335.2 | 400.0 | 508.2 | 662.5 | 2,250.0 | 102 |
Avg profit (%),size 5 promo | 8.1 | 2.6 | 3.9 | 5.0 | 7.4 | 10.4 | 13.6 | 20.0 | 82 |
Avg profit (%),size 5 training | 8.1 | 1.6 | 3.2 | 5.0 | 8.0 | 10.0 | 13.0 | 22.2 | 98 |
Avg % laminationin-house | 96.2 | 25.0 | 85.0 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 100.0 | 104 |
Notes. Variables beginning with “Avg” represent within-firm averages across all rounds for which responses are available. Initial responder sample contains firms that responded to baseline survey. Piece rate and prices are in rupees (exchange rate 100 Rs = US|${\$}$|1). Size 5 is regulation size for adults; size 4 is commonly used by children; Avg % size other refers to sizes 1, 2, and 3. % standard design (of size 5) refers to percentage of size 5 balls produced with standard 20 hexagon–12 pentagon design. Age, experience, and tenure in years. Firms with missing values in all rounds in which questions were asked are dropped (hence the variation in N in final column).
IV. Experiment 1: The Technology Drop
Here we briefly describe our first experiment, the technology drop. For the purposes of the current article, the first experiment mainly serves to provide evidence of low adoption, a puzzle we investigate using our second experiment, motivated in Section V and described in Section VI. As mentioned in the introduction, we originally planned to focus on spillovers of the technology to non-tech-drop firms. This partly explains why we treated a relatively small proportion of firms in the first experiment. We are planning to focus on spillovers in a companion project.28
The 85 firms in the initial-responder sample were divided into four strata based on quartiles of the number of balls produced in a normal month from the baseline survey. Within these strata firms were randomly assigned to one of three groups: the tech-drop group, the cash-drop group, and the no-drop group. We included the cash-drop group to shed light on the possible role of credit constraints in the technology-adoption decision.29 The top panel of Table IV summarizes the distribution of firms across groups for the initial responder sample.30 To increase sample size, we also randomized the initial nonresponders into three groups using the same proportions as for the initial responders (treating them as a separate stratum). The bottom panel of Table IV summarizes the response rates for the initial nonresponders. It is important to note that response rates of the active initial nonresponders are clearly correlated with treatment assignment: firms assigned to the tech-drop and cash-drop groups were more likely to respond than firms assigned to the no-drop group. For this reason, when it is important that assignment to treatment in the tech-drop experiment be exogenous, we focus on the initial responder sample. In our second experiment, where we focus only on active tech-drop firms, all of which responded, this distinction will not be important.
. | # Firms . | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | Tech drop . | Cash drop . | No drop . | . | Total . |
Panel A: Initial responders | |||||
Smallest | 5 | 3 | 12 | 20 | |
Medium-small | 6 | 3 | 13 | 22 | |
Medium-large | 6 | 3 | 13 | 22 | |
Largest | 6 | 3 | 12 | 21 | |
Total | 23 | 12 | 50 | 85 | |
Panel B: Initial nonresponders | |||||
Active, late response | 12 | 5 | 14 | 31 | |
Active, refused all surveys | 0 | 1 | 15 | 16 | |
Inactive (revealed not to be a producer) | 7 | 3 | 12 | 22 |
. | # Firms . | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | Tech drop . | Cash drop . | No drop . | . | Total . |
Panel A: Initial responders | |||||
Smallest | 5 | 3 | 12 | 20 | |
Medium-small | 6 | 3 | 13 | 22 | |
Medium-large | 6 | 3 | 13 | 22 | |
Largest | 6 | 3 | 12 | 21 | |
Total | 23 | 12 | 50 | 85 | |
Panel B: Initial nonresponders | |||||
Active, late response | 12 | 5 | 14 | 31 | |
Active, refused all surveys | 0 | 1 | 15 | 16 | |
Inactive (revealed not to be a producer) | 7 | 3 | 12 | 22 |
Notes. Table reports numbers of firms by treatment assignment among initial responders (Panel A) and initial nonresponders (Panel B). Active firms are those who had produced soccer balls in the previous 12 months and cut their own laminated rexine. Last row reports numbers of firms included in initial randomization that were believed to be active (based on an initial listing exercise) but were later revealed not to be active by our definition because they had shifted entirely to other products, had gone out of business, or were not cutting their own laminated rexine.
. | # Firms . | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | Tech drop . | Cash drop . | No drop . | . | Total . |
Panel A: Initial responders | |||||
Smallest | 5 | 3 | 12 | 20 | |
Medium-small | 6 | 3 | 13 | 22 | |
Medium-large | 6 | 3 | 13 | 22 | |
Largest | 6 | 3 | 12 | 21 | |
Total | 23 | 12 | 50 | 85 | |
Panel B: Initial nonresponders | |||||
Active, late response | 12 | 5 | 14 | 31 | |
Active, refused all surveys | 0 | 1 | 15 | 16 | |
Inactive (revealed not to be a producer) | 7 | 3 | 12 | 22 |
. | # Firms . | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | Tech drop . | Cash drop . | No drop . | . | Total . |
Panel A: Initial responders | |||||
Smallest | 5 | 3 | 12 | 20 | |
Medium-small | 6 | 3 | 13 | 22 | |
Medium-large | 6 | 3 | 13 | 22 | |
Largest | 6 | 3 | 12 | 21 | |
Total | 23 | 12 | 50 | 85 | |
Panel B: Initial nonresponders | |||||
Active, late response | 12 | 5 | 14 | 31 | |
Active, refused all surveys | 0 | 1 | 15 | 16 | |
Inactive (revealed not to be a producer) | 7 | 3 | 12 | 22 |
Notes. Table reports numbers of firms by treatment assignment among initial responders (Panel A) and initial nonresponders (Panel B). Active firms are those who had produced soccer balls in the previous 12 months and cut their own laminated rexine. Last row reports numbers of firms included in initial randomization that were believed to be active (based on an initial listing exercise) but were later revealed not to be active by our definition because they had shifted entirely to other products, had gone out of business, or were not cutting their own laminated rexine.
We began the technology-drop experiment in May 2012. Firms assigned to the technology group were given a four-pentagon offset die, along with a blueprint that could be used to modify the die (Figure IV). They were also given a 30-minute demonstration, which involved first watching the firm’s cutter cut a sheet using the traditional die and counting the number of panels, then instructing the cutter how to cut using the offset die and counting the panels. We continued the demonstration until the cutter was able to cut 272 pentagons from a sheet. In almost all cases, this required one or two sheets; in no case did it require more than three. The die we provided cuts pentagons with edge length of 44 mm. As noted in Section II, firms often use slightly different size dies, and the pentagon die size must match the hexagon die size. For this reason, we also offered firms a free trade-in: we offered to replace the die we gave them with an offset die of a different size, produced by a local diemaker of their choice. Firms could also trade in the four-panel offset die we gave them for a two-panel offset die (of the same or a different size). Of the 35 tech-drop firms, 19 took up the trade-in offer. All chose to trade-in for the two-panel version. The cash group was given cash equal to the price we paid for each four-pentagon offset die, Rs 30,000 (US|${\$}$|300), but no information about the offset die. Firms in the no-drop group were given nothing.
To examine baseline balance, Panel A of Online Appendix Table A.3 reports the mean of various firm characteristics across the tech-drop, cash-drop and no-drop groups for the initial-responder sample. We find no significant differences across groups. Panel B of Online Appendix Table A.3 reports the analog for the 31 late responders. Here we see significant differences for various variables, consistent with the observation that response rates among this group are endogenous to treatment assignment.
Table V reports adoption rates as of August 2013, 15 months after we introduced the technology, with the initial-responder sample in Panel A and the full sample in Panel B. The first three rows of each panel indicate the number of firms that were both active and responded to our surveys. The fourth row shows that a high proportion of tech-drop firms took up our offer of a trade-in for a different die, as mentioned already. The fifth and sixth rows report the number of firms that ordered and that received dies (beyond the one trade-in offered to tech-drop firms). The numbers are modest: in the full sample, one tech-drop firm and six no-drop firms made an additional order. (One diemaker was slow in delivering dies and firms canceled their orders, hence the discrepancy between the fifth and sixth rows.) The seventh and eighth rows report adoption as of August 2013 using the conservative and liberal adoption measures discussed in Section III. Using the liberal adoption variable, in the full sample there were five adopters in the tech-drop group and one in the no-drop group. (In the initial-responder sample, the corresponding numbers are four and zero.) This number of adopters struck us as small. Given the apparently clear advantages of the technology, we were expecting much faster take-up among the firms in the tech-drop group.
. | Tech drop . | Cash drop . | No drop . | . | Total . |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Panel A: Initial-responder sample | |||||
# ever active firms | 23 | 12 | 50 | 85 | |
# ever responded | 23 | 12 | 50 | 85 | |
# currently active and ever responded | 22 | 11 | 46 | 79 | |
# traded in | 15 | 0 | 0 | 15 | |
# ordered offset die (beyond trade-in) | 1 | 0 | 4 | 5 | |
# received offset die (beyond trade-in) | 1 | 0 | 2 | 3 | |
# ever used offset die(>1,000 balls, conservative) | 3 | 0 | 0 | 3 | |
# ever used offset die(>1,000 balls, liberal) | 4 | 0 | 0 | 4 | |
Panel B: Full sample | |||||
# ever active firms | 35 | 18 | 79 | 132 | |
# ever responded | 35 | 17 | 64 | 116 | |
# currently active and everresponded | 32 | 15 | 59 | 106 | |
# traded in | 19 | 0 | 0 | 19 | |
# ordered offset die (beyond trade-in) | 1 | 0 | 6 | 7 | |
# received offset die (beyond trade-in) | 1 | 0 | 4 | 5 | |
# ever used offset die(>1,000 balls, conservative) | 4 | 0 | 1 | 5 | |
# ever used offset die(>1,000 balls, liberal) | 5 | 0 | 1 | 6 |
. | Tech drop . | Cash drop . | No drop . | . | Total . |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Panel A: Initial-responder sample | |||||
# ever active firms | 23 | 12 | 50 | 85 | |
# ever responded | 23 | 12 | 50 | 85 | |
# currently active and ever responded | 22 | 11 | 46 | 79 | |
# traded in | 15 | 0 | 0 | 15 | |
# ordered offset die (beyond trade-in) | 1 | 0 | 4 | 5 | |
# received offset die (beyond trade-in) | 1 | 0 | 2 | 3 | |
# ever used offset die(>1,000 balls, conservative) | 3 | 0 | 0 | 3 | |
# ever used offset die(>1,000 balls, liberal) | 4 | 0 | 0 | 4 | |
Panel B: Full sample | |||||
# ever active firms | 35 | 18 | 79 | 132 | |
# ever responded | 35 | 17 | 64 | 116 | |
# currently active and everresponded | 32 | 15 | 59 | 106 | |
# traded in | 19 | 0 | 0 | 19 | |
# ordered offset die (beyond trade-in) | 1 | 0 | 6 | 7 | |
# received offset die (beyond trade-in) | 1 | 0 | 4 | 5 | |
# ever used offset die(>1,000 balls, conservative) | 4 | 0 | 1 | 5 | |
# ever used offset die(>1,000 balls, liberal) | 5 | 0 | 1 | 6 |
Notes. Table reports adoption statistics as of August 2013 in the initial-responder sample (Panel A) and the full sample (Panel B). # ever responded is the number of firms that answered at least one of the surveys across rounds. Fourth row reports the number of firms that took up the option to trade in the original four-panel offset die for a different offset die. The discrepancy between the fifth and sixth rows is due to one diemaker being very slow in delivering offset dies and firms canceling their orders. Seventh row uses conservative definition of adoption: the number of firms that produced at least 1,000 balls as of August 2013 based on survey data. Eighth row uses liberal definition, which combines survey data and field reports from our enumerators.
. | Tech drop . | Cash drop . | No drop . | . | Total . |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Panel A: Initial-responder sample | |||||
# ever active firms | 23 | 12 | 50 | 85 | |
# ever responded | 23 | 12 | 50 | 85 | |
# currently active and ever responded | 22 | 11 | 46 | 79 | |
# traded in | 15 | 0 | 0 | 15 | |
# ordered offset die (beyond trade-in) | 1 | 0 | 4 | 5 | |
# received offset die (beyond trade-in) | 1 | 0 | 2 | 3 | |
# ever used offset die(>1,000 balls, conservative) | 3 | 0 | 0 | 3 | |
# ever used offset die(>1,000 balls, liberal) | 4 | 0 | 0 | 4 | |
Panel B: Full sample | |||||
# ever active firms | 35 | 18 | 79 | 132 | |
# ever responded | 35 | 17 | 64 | 116 | |
# currently active and everresponded | 32 | 15 | 59 | 106 | |
# traded in | 19 | 0 | 0 | 19 | |
# ordered offset die (beyond trade-in) | 1 | 0 | 6 | 7 | |
# received offset die (beyond trade-in) | 1 | 0 | 4 | 5 | |
# ever used offset die(>1,000 balls, conservative) | 4 | 0 | 1 | 5 | |
# ever used offset die(>1,000 balls, liberal) | 5 | 0 | 1 | 6 |
. | Tech drop . | Cash drop . | No drop . | . | Total . |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Panel A: Initial-responder sample | |||||
# ever active firms | 23 | 12 | 50 | 85 | |
# ever responded | 23 | 12 | 50 | 85 | |
# currently active and ever responded | 22 | 11 | 46 | 79 | |
# traded in | 15 | 0 | 0 | 15 | |
# ordered offset die (beyond trade-in) | 1 | 0 | 4 | 5 | |
# received offset die (beyond trade-in) | 1 | 0 | 2 | 3 | |
# ever used offset die(>1,000 balls, conservative) | 3 | 0 | 0 | 3 | |
# ever used offset die(>1,000 balls, liberal) | 4 | 0 | 0 | 4 | |
Panel B: Full sample | |||||
# ever active firms | 35 | 18 | 79 | 132 | |
# ever responded | 35 | 17 | 64 | 116 | |
# currently active and everresponded | 32 | 15 | 59 | 106 | |
# traded in | 19 | 0 | 0 | 19 | |
# ordered offset die (beyond trade-in) | 1 | 0 | 6 | 7 | |
# received offset die (beyond trade-in) | 1 | 0 | 4 | 5 | |
# ever used offset die(>1,000 balls, conservative) | 4 | 0 | 1 | 5 | |
# ever used offset die(>1,000 balls, liberal) | 5 | 0 | 1 | 6 |
Notes. Table reports adoption statistics as of August 2013 in the initial-responder sample (Panel A) and the full sample (Panel B). # ever responded is the number of firms that answered at least one of the surveys across rounds. Fourth row reports the number of firms that took up the option to trade in the original four-panel offset die for a different offset die. The discrepancy between the fifth and sixth rows is due to one diemaker being very slow in delivering offset dies and firms canceling their orders. Seventh row uses conservative definition of adoption: the number of firms that produced at least 1,000 balls as of August 2013 based on survey data. Eighth row uses liberal definition, which combines survey data and field reports from our enumerators.
We investigated several alternative hypotheses for the low take-up, but found little evidence for the most common existing explanations. Lack of awareness of the technology (the assumption underlying “epidemic” models of diffusion, one of two main categories reviewed by Geroski 2000) cannot be the explanation among tech-drop firms, since we ourselves manipulated the firms’ information set. Another natural hypothesis is simply that the technology does not reduce variable costs as much as we have argued that it does. One piece of evidence against this hypothesis is the revealed preference of the six firms who adopted. Although these revealed preferences do not indicate the profitability of the technology among the full distribution of firms (as our calculations in Section II.D do), they are still instructive. In particular, the one adopter in the no-drop group, which we refer to as Firm Z, is one of the largest firms in Sialkot. This firm ordered 32 offset dies on nine separate purchasing occasions between May 2012 and August 2013, and has ordered 8 more dies since then. Online Appendix Figure A.10 plots the timing and quantity of its die orders. In March–April 2013 (round 4 of our survey) the firm reported that it was using the offset die for approximately 50% of its production and has since reported that the share has risen to 100%. It would be hard to rationalize this behavior if the offset die were not profitable for this firm.
We have estimated a number of simple linear probability models relating adoption as of August 2013 to measures of scale of production, quality of output produced, managerial ability, and employee skill. Scale may be important to allow firms to spread fixed costs over more units. Quality may matter because the offset die generates greater cost saving for firms using more expensive, high-quality rexine. Manager and worker skill are often thought to be important for technology adoption. Online Appendix Tables A.4 and A.5 report the results. They can be briefly summarized: we do not find robust correlations between adoption and any of the covariates reflecting scale, quality, manager, or employee skill. Given the small number of adopters as of August 2013, it is perhaps not surprising that we have not found robust correlations with firm characteristics. But we do interpret the results as deepening the mystery of why so few firms adopted the offset die.
V. Theory: Motivating Evidence and Summary
In this section, we first discuss qualitative evidence that motivates our model of strategic communication in a principal-agent setting (Section V.A). We then summarize the model and discuss its implications (Section V.B). To save space, the formal exposition of the model appears in Online Appendix B.
V.A. Motivating Evidence
Puzzled by the lack of adoption, in the March–April 2013 survey round we added a question asking tech-drop group firms to rank the reasons they had not adopted the new technology, providing nine options (including an “other” category). Table VI reports the responses for the 18 tech-drop firms that responded. Ten of the 18 firms reported that their primary reason for not adopting was that their “cutters are unwilling to work with the offset die.” Four of the 18 said that their primary problem related to “problems adapting the printing process to match the offset patterns,” and 5 more firms selected this as the second most important barrier to adoption. This issue may be related to the technical problem of redesigning printing screens, but as noted already, the cost of a new screen from an outside designer is approximately US|${\$}$|6. It seems likely that the printing problems were related to resistance from the printers. (The other popular response to the question, to which most firms gave lower priority, was that the firm had received insufficient orders.)
. | . | . | . | Waiting for . | Waiting for . | . | . | Other . | . |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | No orders . | Too . | Doubt . | others to . | others to . | Cutters . | Printing . | production . | . |
Firm . | to try on . | busy . | profitable . | prove value . | iron out kinks . | unwilling . | problems . | issues . | Other . |
1 | 2 | 3 | 1 | ||||||
2 | 2 | 1 | |||||||
3 | 2 | 1 | |||||||
4 | 2 | 1 | |||||||
5 | 2 | 1 | |||||||
6 | 4 | 3 | 1 | 2 | |||||
7 | 3 | 2 | 1 | ||||||
8 | 3 | 1 | 2 | ||||||
9 | 3 | 2 | 1 | ||||||
10 | 1 | ||||||||
11 | 1 | ||||||||
12 | 1 | ||||||||
13 | 3 | 1 | 2 | ||||||
14 | 3 | 1 | 2 | ||||||
15 | 2 | 1 | 3 | ||||||
16 | 1 | ||||||||
17 | 5 | 3 | 1 | 2 | 4 | ||||
18 | 2 | 1 | 3 |
. | . | . | . | Waiting for . | Waiting for . | . | . | Other . | . |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | No orders . | Too . | Doubt . | others to . | others to . | Cutters . | Printing . | production . | . |
Firm . | to try on . | busy . | profitable . | prove value . | iron out kinks . | unwilling . | problems . | issues . | Other . |
1 | 2 | 3 | 1 | ||||||
2 | 2 | 1 | |||||||
3 | 2 | 1 | |||||||
4 | 2 | 1 | |||||||
5 | 2 | 1 | |||||||
6 | 4 | 3 | 1 | 2 | |||||
7 | 3 | 2 | 1 | ||||||
8 | 3 | 1 | 2 | ||||||
9 | 3 | 2 | 1 | ||||||
10 | 1 | ||||||||
11 | 1 | ||||||||
12 | 1 | ||||||||
13 | 3 | 1 | 2 | ||||||
14 | 3 | 1 | 2 | ||||||
15 | 2 | 1 | 3 | ||||||
16 | 1 | ||||||||
17 | 5 | 3 | 1 | 2 | 4 | ||||
18 | 2 | 1 | 3 |
Notes. Table reports responses from the March–April 2013 survey round of the 18 tech-drop firms that responded to the question “Select the main reason(s) why you are not currently using an offset die. If more than one, please rank those that apply in order.” The nine categories were: (a) “I have not had any orders to try out the offset die.” (b) “I have been too busy to implement a new technology.” (c) “I do not think the offset die will be profitable to use.” (d) “I am waiting for other firms to adopt first to prove the potential of the technology.” (e) “I am waiting for other firms to adopt first to iron out any issues with the new technology.” (f) “The cutters are unwilling to work with the offset die.” (g) “I have had problems adapting the printing process to match the offset patterns.” (h) “There are problems adapting other parts of the production process (excluding printing or cutting problems).” (i) “Other [fill in reason].”
. | . | . | . | Waiting for . | Waiting for . | . | . | Other . | . |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | No orders . | Too . | Doubt . | others to . | others to . | Cutters . | Printing . | production . | . |
Firm . | to try on . | busy . | profitable . | prove value . | iron out kinks . | unwilling . | problems . | issues . | Other . |
1 | 2 | 3 | 1 | ||||||
2 | 2 | 1 | |||||||
3 | 2 | 1 | |||||||
4 | 2 | 1 | |||||||
5 | 2 | 1 | |||||||
6 | 4 | 3 | 1 | 2 | |||||
7 | 3 | 2 | 1 | ||||||
8 | 3 | 1 | 2 | ||||||
9 | 3 | 2 | 1 | ||||||
10 | 1 | ||||||||
11 | 1 | ||||||||
12 | 1 | ||||||||
13 | 3 | 1 | 2 | ||||||
14 | 3 | 1 | 2 | ||||||
15 | 2 | 1 | 3 | ||||||
16 | 1 | ||||||||
17 | 5 | 3 | 1 | 2 | 4 | ||||
18 | 2 | 1 | 3 |
. | . | . | . | Waiting for . | Waiting for . | . | . | Other . | . |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | No orders . | Too . | Doubt . | others to . | others to . | Cutters . | Printing . | production . | . |
Firm . | to try on . | busy . | profitable . | prove value . | iron out kinks . | unwilling . | problems . | issues . | Other . |
1 | 2 | 3 | 1 | ||||||
2 | 2 | 1 | |||||||
3 | 2 | 1 | |||||||
4 | 2 | 1 | |||||||
5 | 2 | 1 | |||||||
6 | 4 | 3 | 1 | 2 | |||||
7 | 3 | 2 | 1 | ||||||
8 | 3 | 1 | 2 | ||||||
9 | 3 | 2 | 1 | ||||||
10 | 1 | ||||||||
11 | 1 | ||||||||
12 | 1 | ||||||||
13 | 3 | 1 | 2 | ||||||
14 | 3 | 1 | 2 | ||||||
15 | 2 | 1 | 3 | ||||||
16 | 1 | ||||||||
17 | 5 | 3 | 1 | 2 | 4 | ||||
18 | 2 | 1 | 3 |
Notes. Table reports responses from the March–April 2013 survey round of the 18 tech-drop firms that responded to the question “Select the main reason(s) why you are not currently using an offset die. If more than one, please rank those that apply in order.” The nine categories were: (a) “I have not had any orders to try out the offset die.” (b) “I have been too busy to implement a new technology.” (c) “I do not think the offset die will be profitable to use.” (d) “I am waiting for other firms to adopt first to prove the potential of the technology.” (e) “I am waiting for other firms to adopt first to iron out any issues with the new technology.” (f) “The cutters are unwilling to work with the offset die.” (g) “I have had problems adapting the printing process to match the offset patterns.” (h) “There are problems adapting other parts of the production process (excluding printing or cutting problems).” (i) “Other [fill in reason].”
The responses to the survey question were consistent with anecdotal reports from several firms. One notable piece of evidence is from Firm Z, the large adopter from the no-drop group, which is an exception to the local norm of piece-rate contracts. In part because of pressure from an international client, for several years the firm has instead paid a guaranteed monthly salary supplemented by a performance bonus, to guarantee that all workers earn at least the legal minimum wage in Pakistan. The fact that this large early adopter uses an uncommon incentive structure for cutters and printers seemed very suggestive.
We also feel that it is useful to quote at some length from field reports submitted by our survey team. To be clear, the following reports are from factory visits during the second experiment, which is described in Section VI, and we are distorting the chronology of events by reporting them here. But they are useful to capture the flavor of the owner–cutter interactions that we seek to capture in the theoretical model. As described in more detail shortly, in our second experiment we offered one cutter in each firm (conditional on the approval of the owner) a lump-sum Rs 15,000 (US|${\$}$|150) incentive payment to demonstrate competence in using the offset die. (We also offered an incentive to one printer.) The following excerpts are all from firms in the group assigned to treatment for the second experiment.
In one firm, the owner told the survey team that he was willing to participate in the experiment but that the team should ask the cutter whether he wanted to participate. The report continues:
[The cutter] explained that the owner will not compensate him for the extra panels he will get out of each sheet. He said that the incentive offer of [Rs] 15,000 is not worth all the tensions in future.
It appears in this case that the cutter, anticipating that the owner would not adjust his wage, sought to withhold information about the offset die to avoid a future decline in his pay. The cutter declined to participate, and the firm was not treated.
In another firm, the owner, who had agreed to participate in the treatment, was skeptical when the enumerators returned to test the cutter. Our survey team writes,
[The owner] told us that the firm is getting only 2 to 4 extra pentagon panels by using our offset panel… The owner thinks that the cost savings are not large enough to adopt the offset die… He allowed us to time the cutter.
The team then continued to the cutting room without the owner.
On entering the cutting area, we saw the cutter practicing with our offset die… We tested the cutter… He got 279 pentagon pieces in 2 minutes 32 seconds… The cutter privately told us that he can get 10 to 12 pieces extra by using our offset die.
The owner then arrived in the cutting area.
We informed the owner about the cutter’s performance. The owner asked the cutter how many more pieces he can get by using the offset die. The cutter replied, “only 2 to 4 extra panels.”
It appears that the cutter had been misinforming the owner. But the cutter did not hide the performance of the die in the cutting process itself, likely either because it was difficult to do so or because he did not want to jeopardize his incentive payment.
The owner asked the cutter to cut a sheet in front of him. The cutter got 275 pieces in 2 minutes 25 seconds. The owner looked satisfied by the cutter’s speed… The owner requested us to experiment with volleyball dies.
This firm subsequently adopted the offset die.
In a third firm, the owner reported that he had modified the wage he pays to his cutter to make up for the slower speed of the offset die. Our team writes,
[The owner] said that it takes 1 hour for his cutter to cut 25 sheets with the conventional die. With the offset die it takes his cutter 15 mins more to cut 25 sheets for which he pays him [Rs] 100 extra for the day which is not a big deal.
This firm has generally not been cooperative in our survey, and we have not been able to verify that it has produced more than 1,000 balls with the offset die. For this reason it is not classified as an adopter.
V.B. Summary of Model
The survey results and qualitative evidence highlight the role of misaligned incentives and suggest that workers are discouraging some firms from adopting. But this raises two important questions. First, given that owners should be aware that workers have an incentive to discourage adoption of the offset dies, why are they influenced by what the workers say? Second, why do owners not simply offer a different labor contract, to give workers an incentive to support the adoption of the cost-saving technology? To address these questions and motivate our second experiment, we develop a model embedding a cheap-talk interaction along the lines of Crawford and Sobel (1982) in a standard principal-agent model. We recognize that other models with misaligned incentives and an ability of cutters to impose direct costs on firms may generate similar predictions. (See in particular Dow and Perotti 2013 and Sections IV and V of Garicano and Rayo 2016.) But in our view the model provides a particularly parsimonious account of the main forces at play. (The full exposition is in Online Appendix B.)
We consider a principal (she) and an agent (he) in a one-time interaction. Production technologies are characterized by marginal cost, c, and speed, s. There is an existing technology, with c0 and s0. The principal is aware of the existence of a new technology, which may be of three types: θ1, which has the same costs as the existing technology but is slower; θ2, which is similar to our technology in that it has lower marginal cost than the existing technology but is slower (with the cost reduction more than offsetting the increased labor time); and θ3, which has the same marginal costs as the existing technology but is faster. The principal has priors ρ1, ρ2, and ρ3 that the technology is of each type.31
In stage 1, the principal must choose the contract she offers the agent. In stage 2, nature reveals the type of the new technology to the agent but not the principal. Although this is clearly an extreme assumption, it captures in an analytically tractable way the observation from our qualitative work that the cutters are better informed about the cutting dies (which they work with all day every day) than are owners. In stage 3, the agent can send a message to the principal about the technology. In stage 4, the principal decides whether to adopt. In stage 5, the agent chooses his level of effort. In stage 6, output is observed, the technology is revealed to the principal, and payoffs are realized.
We consider two cases of the model, one in which the only available contract is a standard piece rate that must be chosen in stage 1 (Section V.B.1), and the other a “conditional” contract in which the piece rate can be conditioned on marginal cost, which is only revealed ex post, in stage 6 (Section V.B.2). We discuss the implications in Section V.B.3 and the relation to our second experiment in Section V.B.4.
1. No Conditional Contracts
In this case, we assume that the piece rate cannot be conditioned on information that is revealed later in the game, in particular on marginal cost. Given this, the agent strictly prefers faster technologies. Hence the principal and agent have a common interest to adopt type θ3 and not to adopt type θ1 but divergent interests over type θ2.
The analysis of the model is complicated by the fact that we have cheap talk embedded in a principal-agent interaction: for every choice of the piece rate there is a different cheap-talk subgame. But the analysis is greatly simplified by Lemma 1 (Lemma 1 and both propositions appear in Online Appendix B.), which holds that in any subgame, modulo treating messages that induce the same action by the principal as equivalent (following Crawford and Sobel 1982), there are just two possible subgame equilibria: a “babbling” equilibrium in which the principal ignores what the agent says and does not adopt; and an “informative” equilibrium in which the agent seeks to encourage adoption of type θ3 and discourage adoption of types θ1 and θ2, and the principal is influenced by the agent’s message. We place no restrictions on the richness of the space of possible messages, but as shorthand we refer to a message that encourages the principal to adopt as “technology is good” and one that discourages her as “technology is bad.” In the informative subgame equilibrium (if it exists), if the principal hears the message technology is bad, she infers that the technology is type θ1 or θ2; if technology is good, she infers θ3. One implication of Lemma 1 is that there cannot exist an equilibrium in which the agent fully reveals the technology type to the principal.
Our key proposition in this case (Proposition 1) holds that there exists an equilibrium in which the principal offers the same piece rate as under the existing technology, the agent says technology is bad if it is type θ1 or θ2 and technology is good if it is type θ3, and the principal follows the agent’s advice. In particular, if the technology is type θ2 the agent discourages the principal from adopting and she does not adopt.32 It is common in the literature on cheap talk to assume that players will coordinate on the most informative equilibrium in cheap-talk interactions.33 If we adopt this assumption (for every cheap-talk subgame), then the equilibrium described in Proposition 1 is unique.
2. Conditional Contracts
In this case, we allow the principal at stage 0 to pay a fixed cost, G, to be able to offer a contract that conditions the piece rate on marginal cost, revealed in stage 6. Given our assumptions, only type θ2 differs in marginal cost from the existing technology. The conditional contract is useful in that it enables the principal to offer a higher piece rate if the technology is type θ2. The fixed cost G can be interpreted as the cost of a commitment device to pay a piece rate above the one that would be paid for the existing technology, which otherwise the principal would not be able to credibly commit to. (We discuss other possible interpretations in Section V.B.3.)
Our main proposition in this case (Proposition 2) holds that there exists an equilibrium in which, if the contracting fixed cost G is sufficiently small, the principal pays G and offers a supplement to the piece rate if the technology is revealed to be type θ2. Given the supplement, the agent wants to adopt the same technologies that the principal wants to adopt, θ2 or θ3, and technologies of type θ2 are adopted.
“Sufficiently small” for G means less than the expected benefit of adopting technology θ2 relative to the existing technology, which depends on speed and cost of the technologies as well as the principal’s prior, ρ2, that the technology is type θ2. If ρ2 is sufficiently low, then the principal will not pay G and the players will be back in the world of the first case, where their interests diverge and type θ2 will not be adopted. Again, if we assume players coordinate on the most informative subgame equilibria, then the Proposition 2 equilibrium is unique.
3. Discussion
Let us come back to the two questions posed at the beginning of the model summary. First, why are owners influenced by cutters’ messages, given that they should be aware that cutters have an incentive to resist adoption of our die? The answer from the model is that the interests of the principal and agent are sufficiently aligned—they have common interests over types θ1 and θ3—that the agent’s message can be informative. In particular, in the Proposition 1 equilibrium, the principal can infer whether θ = θ3 or θ ∈ {θ1, θ2}, and this is valuable enough that she pays attention to the agent’s message, knowing that it may lead her not to adopt type θ2.
Second, why don’t owners offer a labor contract that incentivizes cutters to support the adoption of our die? The model suggests two reasons. One is simply that the principal may be unaware of the existence of the conditional contract; this corresponds to the no-conditional-contracts case. The conditional contract may be an organizational innovation that was previously unknown, at least to some firms, in the same way that our technical innovation was previously unknown.
Another reason, corresponding to the conditional-contracts case, is that the principal is aware of the conditional contract but perceives the cost of implementing it to be higher than the expected benefit. The contracting fixed cost, G, can be interpreted in a number of ways. It may be that a fairness norm has arisen around standard piece-rate contracts, such that any deviation would carry a morale cost. Or firms may worry that if they offer a higher piece rate in one case, workers will demand higher rates in others. G can also be interpreted as a cost of a commitment device for the principal’s pledge to pay the higher piece rate if the technology is type θ2.34 Finally, the fixed cost can be interpreted in light of the ratchet effect (e.g., Gibbons 1987). If a worker on a piece-rate contract discovers a labor-saving innovation, he may not reveal it to the owner if he expects her to cut the piece rate in response. It may be optimal for the principal to commit to not changing the piece rate to encourage labor-saving innovations. If most innovations in Sialkot are labor-saving, this may explain why piece rates are sticky and why it may be costly for firms to start offering conditional contracts—contracts that open the door to ratcheting. In Section VII, we discuss the previous cutting innovation in Sialkot, which was labor-saving. It seems plausible for firms to expect other new technologies to be labor-saving as well and to be reluctant to modify piece rates for this reason.
These two possible explanations for the stickiness of labor contracts—that owners are not aware of the existence of conditional contracts, and that the benefits owners expect do not outweigh the costs of adopting them—have similar implications for the players’ behavior. In either case, the principal offers a pure (nonconditional) piece-rate contract and a technology of type θ2 is not adopted. The key point is that for whatever reason, many owners did not in fact adjust labor contracts. This left scope for our incentive intervention, described below, to have an effect.
This discussion is related to a broader debate in organizational economics about the underlying causes of organizational failure, of which the lack of adoption of our dies is arguably an example. An organization may fail because it was poorly designed ex ante. Or its design may represent an ex ante optimal solution to trade-offs between uncertain costs and benefits, but a shock yields a suboptimal outcome ex post. In our context, the idea that an owner is simply not aware of the existence of conditional contracts corresponds to the first view. The idea that the owner perceives the fixed cost of offering a conditional contract to be greater than the expected benefit of adopting a type θ2 technology corresponds to the second. Our preferred interpretation is the latter; we believe that most owners are aware of the possibility of conditional contracts but choose not to offer them because they assign low probability to the arrival of beneficial new technologies like our dies. But we recognize that the two interpretations predict similar behavior and it is difficult to discriminate between them empirically.35
4. Motivation for Incentive Intervention
Testing the implications of our model presents a number of practical challenges. In principle, one approach would be to pay the fixed cost, G, for firms and examine whether they change the labor contract and adopt the technology. But this cost is not observable and depends on complex social dynamics within firms; it is not clear how much we (the experimenters) would pay or to whom. Another approach would be to offer a piece-rate supplement ourselves. But firms are reluctant to share the detailed production information that would be required to implement such a payment. The challenges we faced simply in surveying firms indicated to us that it would be impossible to manipulate the piece rate directly in our second experiment.36
Facing these constraints, we opted for a third approach: we offered a one-time lump-sum payment to one cutter and one printer per firm, conditional on revealing the offset die to be cost-saving in front of the owner. (Presumably, other nonmonetary inducements, such as increased authority or greater work schedule flexibility, could have served a role similar to our one-time lump-sum payment.) In Online Appendix B.4, we prove a formal proposition that if such a conditional lump-sum payment by a third-party experimenter is sufficiently large, then there exists an equilibrium in which the agent encourages adoption of type θ2 and the principal adopts it, even if she would not have offered the conditional contract on her own. Intuitively, the incentive payment plays the same role as the supplement to the piece rate in the conditional contracts case: it raises the payoff to the agent of revealing the technology to be type θ2. Empirically, the main implication is that we would expect a sufficiently large lump-sum incentive payment to increase adoption of the offset die. It is worth noting that “sufficiently large” in this context is relative to the possible wage losses of a single cutter, not to the revenues or profits of a firm. Indeed, we will see that a lump-sum incentive payment that appears small from the point of view of firms has a large effect on adoption.37
VI. Experiment 2: The Incentive Payment
VI.A. Experimental Design
Motivated by the theoretical model, we conducted our second experiment, the incentive payment, in September–November 2013. To avoid interfering with the process of diffusion to the non-tech-drop firms that is the focus of our companion project on spillovers (see note 28), we focused on the 35 tech-drop firms (including both initial responders and initial nonresponders). The 31 still-active firms among these were divided into four similarly sized strata:38 (i) firms in the two smaller strata from the tech-drop experiment that had not yet adopted the die as of August 2013; (ii) firms in the two larger strata from the tech-drop experiment that had not yet adopted the die; (iii) firms from the initial nonresponder stratum from the tech-drop experiment that had not yet adopted the die; and (iv) firms that had already adopted the die.39 Within each stratum, firms were randomly assigned with equal proportion to a treatment subgroup (which we call Group A) and a control subgroup (Group B). There were 15 firms assigned to Group A and 16 to Group B.
To firms in Group B we gave a reminder about the offset die and the new cutting pattern and explicitly informed them about the two-pentagon variant of the offset die (which, as noted, had proven more popular than the four-pentagon offset die we originally distributed.) We also offered to do a new demonstration with their cutters. To each firm in Group A, we gave the same refresher, the same information about the two-pentagon variant, and the same offer of a new demonstration. In addition, we explained the misalignment of incentives to the owner and offered to pay one cutter and one printer lump-sum bonuses roughly equivalent to their monthly incomes—15,000 Rs (US|${\$}$|150) and 12,000 Rs (US|${\$}$|120), respectively—on the condition that within one month they demonstrate competence in using the new technology in front of the owner. If the owner agreed to the intervention, we explained the intervention to one cutter and one printer chosen by the owner, paid them one third of the incentive payment on the spot, and scheduled a time to return to test their performance using the die.40
The performance target for cutters was 272 pentagons from a single sheet in three minutes using the offset die. The target for the printer was 48 pairs of offset pentagons in three minutes.41 We provided the owner with 20 laminated rexine sheets and printing screens for offset pentagon pairs for his workers to practice with, and a nominal Rs 5,000 (US|${\$}$|50) to cover additional costs such as overhead (e.g., electricity while the cutters were practicing). We returned after approximately one month to test the employees and, upon successful achievement of the performance targets, to pay the remaining two thirds of the incentive payments. Without revealing ahead of time that we would do so, we allowed for a buffer of 30 seconds and five pentagons for cutters and 30 seconds for printers.
Table VII evaluates baseline balance by comparing firm characteristics across Group A and Group B firms at the time of our visit to explain the intervention (September 2013). No differences in means are statistically significant. It appears that the randomization was successful.42
. | Group A . | Group B . | . |
---|---|---|---|
. | incentive . | no incentive . | Difference . |
. | contract . | contract . | . |
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . |
Log avg output/month | 9.86 | 9.31 | 0.55 |
(0.41) | (0.29) | (0.50) | |
Log avg employment | 3.35 | 3.23 | 0.13 |
(0.38) | (0.25) | (0.45) | |
Log avg price, size 5 promo | 5.40 | 5.45 | − 0.05 |
(0.02) | (0.07) | (0.07) | |
Log avg price, size 5 training | 6.00 | 5.93 | 0.07 |
(0.06) | (0.06) | (0.08) | |
Avg % promotional (of size 5) | 34.90 | 32.04 | 2.86 |
(6.20) | (7.26) | (9.60) | |
Avg Rs/ball, head cutter | 1.45 | 1.63 | − 0.17 |
(0.10) | (0.15) | (0.18) | |
CEO university indicator | 0.56 | 0.36 | 0.19 |
(0.18) | (0.15) | (0.23) | |
CEO experience | 15.50 | 16.50 | − 1.00 |
(3.60) | (3.60) | (5.13) | |
Age of firm | 24.53 | 20.60 | 3.93 |
(2.83) | (2.28) | (3.64) | |
N | 15 | 16 | 31 |
. | Group A . | Group B . | . |
---|---|---|---|
. | incentive . | no incentive . | Difference . |
. | contract . | contract . | . |
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . |
Log avg output/month | 9.86 | 9.31 | 0.55 |
(0.41) | (0.29) | (0.50) | |
Log avg employment | 3.35 | 3.23 | 0.13 |
(0.38) | (0.25) | (0.45) | |
Log avg price, size 5 promo | 5.40 | 5.45 | − 0.05 |
(0.02) | (0.07) | (0.07) | |
Log avg price, size 5 training | 6.00 | 5.93 | 0.07 |
(0.06) | (0.06) | (0.08) | |
Avg % promotional (of size 5) | 34.90 | 32.04 | 2.86 |
(6.20) | (7.26) | (9.60) | |
Avg Rs/ball, head cutter | 1.45 | 1.63 | − 0.17 |
(0.10) | (0.15) | (0.18) | |
CEO university indicator | 0.56 | 0.36 | 0.19 |
(0.18) | (0.15) | (0.23) | |
CEO experience | 15.50 | 16.50 | − 1.00 |
(3.60) | (3.60) | (5.13) | |
Age of firm | 24.53 | 20.60 | 3.93 |
(2.83) | (2.28) | (3.64) | |
N | 15 | 16 | 31 |
Notes. Table reports baseline balance in the incentive payment experiment (experiment 2). Sample is the 31 tech-drop firms from the tech-drop experiment that were still active as of September 2013. There are no significant differences between treatment and control groups. Standard errors in parentheses.
. | Group A . | Group B . | . |
---|---|---|---|
. | incentive . | no incentive . | Difference . |
. | contract . | contract . | . |
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . |
Log avg output/month | 9.86 | 9.31 | 0.55 |
(0.41) | (0.29) | (0.50) | |
Log avg employment | 3.35 | 3.23 | 0.13 |
(0.38) | (0.25) | (0.45) | |
Log avg price, size 5 promo | 5.40 | 5.45 | − 0.05 |
(0.02) | (0.07) | (0.07) | |
Log avg price, size 5 training | 6.00 | 5.93 | 0.07 |
(0.06) | (0.06) | (0.08) | |
Avg % promotional (of size 5) | 34.90 | 32.04 | 2.86 |
(6.20) | (7.26) | (9.60) | |
Avg Rs/ball, head cutter | 1.45 | 1.63 | − 0.17 |
(0.10) | (0.15) | (0.18) | |
CEO university indicator | 0.56 | 0.36 | 0.19 |
(0.18) | (0.15) | (0.23) | |
CEO experience | 15.50 | 16.50 | − 1.00 |
(3.60) | (3.60) | (5.13) | |
Age of firm | 24.53 | 20.60 | 3.93 |
(2.83) | (2.28) | (3.64) | |
N | 15 | 16 | 31 |
. | Group A . | Group B . | . |
---|---|---|---|
. | incentive . | no incentive . | Difference . |
. | contract . | contract . | . |
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . |
Log avg output/month | 9.86 | 9.31 | 0.55 |
(0.41) | (0.29) | (0.50) | |
Log avg employment | 3.35 | 3.23 | 0.13 |
(0.38) | (0.25) | (0.45) | |
Log avg price, size 5 promo | 5.40 | 5.45 | − 0.05 |
(0.02) | (0.07) | (0.07) | |
Log avg price, size 5 training | 6.00 | 5.93 | 0.07 |
(0.06) | (0.06) | (0.08) | |
Avg % promotional (of size 5) | 34.90 | 32.04 | 2.86 |
(6.20) | (7.26) | (9.60) | |
Avg Rs/ball, head cutter | 1.45 | 1.63 | − 0.17 |
(0.10) | (0.15) | (0.18) | |
CEO university indicator | 0.56 | 0.36 | 0.19 |
(0.18) | (0.15) | (0.23) | |
CEO experience | 15.50 | 16.50 | − 1.00 |
(3.60) | (3.60) | (5.13) | |
Age of firm | 24.53 | 20.60 | 3.93 |
(2.83) | (2.28) | (3.64) | |
N | 15 | 16 | 31 |
Notes. Table reports baseline balance in the incentive payment experiment (experiment 2). Sample is the 31 tech-drop firms from the tech-drop experiment that were still active as of September 2013. There are no significant differences between treatment and control groups. Standard errors in parentheses.
VI.B. Results
Ten of the 15 Group A firms agreed to participate in the experiment.43Online Appendix Table A.6 reports the times achieved by the chosen cutter at each firm (all using the two-pentagon variant of the offset die). The average time was 2 minutes, 52 seconds, approximately 27% longer than the typical time to cut with the traditional die (2 minutes, 15 seconds). For this reason, we believe that the 100% increase in labor time factored into the cost calculations in Section II is conservative. In addition, many cutters expressed confidence that with additional use they could lower their cutting time. All printers easily achieved their target, consistent with the assumption in Section II that despite some printers’ fears, the offset die does not increase labor time for printing.
To measure short-run adoption responses, we carried out a survey round in January–March 2014 (round 6 of our survey), two to five months after the completion of the incentive payment intervention. Before turning to the formal regressions, it is useful to examine the raw adoption statistics. Of the 10 Group A firms that agreed to participate in the experiment, 2 had already adopted the die. Of the remaining 8 firms, 5 subsequently adopted using the liberal definition (or 4 using the conservative definition). Of the 16 Group B firms, 3 firms had already adopted prior to the invention. None of the remaining 13 firms adopted in the short run, by either measure. To examine medium-run responses, we carried out another survey round in October–December 2014 (round 7 of our survey), 11–13 months after the completion of the intervention. If the technology is beneficial, as we have argued, one would expect it eventually to be adopted by all firms (once there has been sufficient social learning, for instance) and there would then be no long-run effect of our incentive treatment. In this sense, it would be reasonable to expect the medium- and long-run treatment effect to be smaller than the short-run one. Indeed, by October–December 2014, one initial nonadopter in Group B (that is, a Group B firm that had not yet adopted at the start of experiment 2) had adopted the die (by either definition).
Table VIII uses the liberal adoption measure to assess formally the impact of the incentive payment intervention on adoption rates. All regressions include dummies for the four strata. Panel A reports impacts on adoption in the short run, and Panel B in the medium run. Focusing on the short run first, the first-stage estimates (column 1) indicate, not surprisingly, that assignment to Group A is significantly associated with greater probability of receiving the incentive payment treatment; that is, we have a strong first stage. The dependent variable in columns (2)–(4) is a binary indicator for whether a firm has adopted. The OLS estimate of the coefficient on treatment in column (2) is positive and significant, but one might be worried about selection into treatment. The reduced-form (intent-to-treat, ITT) result in column (3) does not suffer from such selection issues and indicates a positive and significant (at the 5% level) causal relationship between assignment and adoption. The estimate indicates that the probability of adoption increased by 0.32 among those assigned to treatment (from a baseline of 13%).44 The IV estimate (the effect of treatment on the treated) is substantially higher: 0.48. However, since the one third of firms who refused the intervention may have chosen to do so because of particularly large costs of adoption (or small benefits), these IV estimates should be treated with caution. The medium-run ITT estimate in Panel B is slightly lower at 0.27 (and statistically significant at the 10% level) because of the one Group B firm that adopted in the second six-month period after the intervention. (The number of observations falls in the medium-run results because two firms exited.) Table IX reports very similar results using the conservative adoption measure—the short-run ITT is 0.31 and statistically significant at the 5% level, and the medium-run ITT is 0.26 and statistically significant at the 10% level.45
. | Dep. var.: adoption (>1,000 balls, liberal measure) . | |||
---|---|---|---|---|
. | First . | . | Reduced . | IV . |
. | stage . | OLS . | form (ITT) . | (TOT) . |
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
Panel A: Short run (as of round 6) | ||||
Received treatment | 0.48*** | 0.48*** | ||
(0.15) | (0.15) | |||
Assigned to Group A | 0.68*** | 0.32** | ||
(0.12) | (0.12) | |||
Stratum dummies | Y | Y | Y | Y |
Mean of Group B (control group) | 0.19 | 0.19 | 0.19 | |
R-squared | 0.57 | 0.69 | 0.60 | 0.69 |
N | 31 | 31 | 31 | 31 |
Panel B: Medium run (as of round 7) | ||||
Received treatment | 0.41** | 0.37** | ||
(0.16) | (0.17) | |||
Assigned to Group A | 0.72*** | 0.27* | ||
(0.12) | (0.14) | |||
Stratum dummies | Y | Y | Y | Y |
Mean of Group B(control group) | 0.27 | 0.27 | 0.27 | |
R-squared | 0.60 | 0.61 | 0.52 | 0.61 |
N | 29 | 29 | 29 | 29 |
. | Dep. var.: adoption (>1,000 balls, liberal measure) . | |||
---|---|---|---|---|
. | First . | . | Reduced . | IV . |
. | stage . | OLS . | form (ITT) . | (TOT) . |
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
Panel A: Short run (as of round 6) | ||||
Received treatment | 0.48*** | 0.48*** | ||
(0.15) | (0.15) | |||
Assigned to Group A | 0.68*** | 0.32** | ||
(0.12) | (0.12) | |||
Stratum dummies | Y | Y | Y | Y |
Mean of Group B (control group) | 0.19 | 0.19 | 0.19 | |
R-squared | 0.57 | 0.69 | 0.60 | 0.69 |
N | 31 | 31 | 31 | 31 |
Panel B: Medium run (as of round 7) | ||||
Received treatment | 0.41** | 0.37** | ||
(0.16) | (0.17) | |||
Assigned to Group A | 0.72*** | 0.27* | ||
(0.12) | (0.14) | |||
Stratum dummies | Y | Y | Y | Y |
Mean of Group B(control group) | 0.27 | 0.27 | 0.27 | |
R-squared | 0.60 | 0.61 | 0.52 | 0.61 |
N | 29 | 29 | 29 | 29 |
Notes. Table reports results of incentive payment experiment on adoption rates using the liberal definition of adoption. Panel A reports short-run results as of round 6 (January–March 2014). Panel B reports medium-run results as of round 7 (October–December 2014). The dependent variable in column (1) is an indicator for whether the firm received treatment. Two firms exited between rounds 6 and 7. All regressions include stratum dummies and report robust standard errors. Significance: *.10, **.05; ***.01.
. | Dep. var.: adoption (>1,000 balls, liberal measure) . | |||
---|---|---|---|---|
. | First . | . | Reduced . | IV . |
. | stage . | OLS . | form (ITT) . | (TOT) . |
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
Panel A: Short run (as of round 6) | ||||
Received treatment | 0.48*** | 0.48*** | ||
(0.15) | (0.15) | |||
Assigned to Group A | 0.68*** | 0.32** | ||
(0.12) | (0.12) | |||
Stratum dummies | Y | Y | Y | Y |
Mean of Group B (control group) | 0.19 | 0.19 | 0.19 | |
R-squared | 0.57 | 0.69 | 0.60 | 0.69 |
N | 31 | 31 | 31 | 31 |
Panel B: Medium run (as of round 7) | ||||
Received treatment | 0.41** | 0.37** | ||
(0.16) | (0.17) | |||
Assigned to Group A | 0.72*** | 0.27* | ||
(0.12) | (0.14) | |||
Stratum dummies | Y | Y | Y | Y |
Mean of Group B(control group) | 0.27 | 0.27 | 0.27 | |
R-squared | 0.60 | 0.61 | 0.52 | 0.61 |
N | 29 | 29 | 29 | 29 |
. | Dep. var.: adoption (>1,000 balls, liberal measure) . | |||
---|---|---|---|---|
. | First . | . | Reduced . | IV . |
. | stage . | OLS . | form (ITT) . | (TOT) . |
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
Panel A: Short run (as of round 6) | ||||
Received treatment | 0.48*** | 0.48*** | ||
(0.15) | (0.15) | |||
Assigned to Group A | 0.68*** | 0.32** | ||
(0.12) | (0.12) | |||
Stratum dummies | Y | Y | Y | Y |
Mean of Group B (control group) | 0.19 | 0.19 | 0.19 | |
R-squared | 0.57 | 0.69 | 0.60 | 0.69 |
N | 31 | 31 | 31 | 31 |
Panel B: Medium run (as of round 7) | ||||
Received treatment | 0.41** | 0.37** | ||
(0.16) | (0.17) | |||
Assigned to Group A | 0.72*** | 0.27* | ||
(0.12) | (0.14) | |||
Stratum dummies | Y | Y | Y | Y |
Mean of Group B(control group) | 0.27 | 0.27 | 0.27 | |
R-squared | 0.60 | 0.61 | 0.52 | 0.61 |
N | 29 | 29 | 29 | 29 |
Notes. Table reports results of incentive payment experiment on adoption rates using the liberal definition of adoption. Panel A reports short-run results as of round 6 (January–March 2014). Panel B reports medium-run results as of round 7 (October–December 2014). The dependent variable in column (1) is an indicator for whether the firm received treatment. Two firms exited between rounds 6 and 7. All regressions include stratum dummies and report robust standard errors. Significance: *.10, **.05; ***.01.
. | Dep. var.: adoption (>1,000 balls, cons. measure) . | |||
---|---|---|---|---|
. | First . | . | Reduced . | IV . |
. | stage . | OLS . | form (ITT) . | (TOT) . |
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
Panel A: Short run (as of round 6) | ||||
Received treatment | 0.45*** | 0.46*** | ||
(0.16) | (0.16) | |||
Assigned to Group A | 0.68*** | 0.31** | ||
(0.12) | (0.12) | |||
Stratum dummies | Y | Y | Y | Y |
Mean of Group B(control group) | 0.12 | 0.12 | 0.12 | |
R-squared | 0.57 | 0.56 | 0.46 | 0.56 |
N | 31 | 31 | 31 | 31 |
Panel B: Medium run (as of Round 7) | ||||
Received treatment | 0.39** | 0.35* | ||
(0.17) | (0.19) | |||
Assigned to Group A | 0.72*** | 0.26* | ||
(0.12) | (0.14) | |||
Stratum dummies | Y | Y | Y | Y |
Mean of Group B(control group) | 0.20 | 0.20 | 0.20 | |
R-squared | 0.60 | 0.46 | 0.38 | 0.45 |
N | 29 | 29 | 29 | 29 |
. | Dep. var.: adoption (>1,000 balls, cons. measure) . | |||
---|---|---|---|---|
. | First . | . | Reduced . | IV . |
. | stage . | OLS . | form (ITT) . | (TOT) . |
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
Panel A: Short run (as of round 6) | ||||
Received treatment | 0.45*** | 0.46*** | ||
(0.16) | (0.16) | |||
Assigned to Group A | 0.68*** | 0.31** | ||
(0.12) | (0.12) | |||
Stratum dummies | Y | Y | Y | Y |
Mean of Group B(control group) | 0.12 | 0.12 | 0.12 | |
R-squared | 0.57 | 0.56 | 0.46 | 0.56 |
N | 31 | 31 | 31 | 31 |
Panel B: Medium run (as of Round 7) | ||||
Received treatment | 0.39** | 0.35* | ||
(0.17) | (0.19) | |||
Assigned to Group A | 0.72*** | 0.26* | ||
(0.12) | (0.14) | |||
Stratum dummies | Y | Y | Y | Y |
Mean of Group B(control group) | 0.20 | 0.20 | 0.20 | |
R-squared | 0.60 | 0.46 | 0.38 | 0.45 |
N | 29 | 29 | 29 | 29 |
Notes. Table reports results of incentive payment experiment on adoption rates using the conservative definition of adoption. Panel A reports short-run results as of round 6 (January–March 2014). Panel B reports medium-run results as of round 7 (October–December 2014). The dependent variable in column (1) is an indicator variable for whether the firm received treatment. Two firms exited between rounds 6 and 7. All regressions include stratum dummies and report robust standard errors. Significance: *.10, **.05; ***.01.
. | Dep. var.: adoption (>1,000 balls, cons. measure) . | |||
---|---|---|---|---|
. | First . | . | Reduced . | IV . |
. | stage . | OLS . | form (ITT) . | (TOT) . |
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
Panel A: Short run (as of round 6) | ||||
Received treatment | 0.45*** | 0.46*** | ||
(0.16) | (0.16) | |||
Assigned to Group A | 0.68*** | 0.31** | ||
(0.12) | (0.12) | |||
Stratum dummies | Y | Y | Y | Y |
Mean of Group B(control group) | 0.12 | 0.12 | 0.12 | |
R-squared | 0.57 | 0.56 | 0.46 | 0.56 |
N | 31 | 31 | 31 | 31 |
Panel B: Medium run (as of Round 7) | ||||
Received treatment | 0.39** | 0.35* | ||
(0.17) | (0.19) | |||
Assigned to Group A | 0.72*** | 0.26* | ||
(0.12) | (0.14) | |||
Stratum dummies | Y | Y | Y | Y |
Mean of Group B(control group) | 0.20 | 0.20 | 0.20 | |
R-squared | 0.60 | 0.46 | 0.38 | 0.45 |
N | 29 | 29 | 29 | 29 |
. | Dep. var.: adoption (>1,000 balls, cons. measure) . | |||
---|---|---|---|---|
. | First . | . | Reduced . | IV . |
. | stage . | OLS . | form (ITT) . | (TOT) . |
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
Panel A: Short run (as of round 6) | ||||
Received treatment | 0.45*** | 0.46*** | ||
(0.16) | (0.16) | |||
Assigned to Group A | 0.68*** | 0.31** | ||
(0.12) | (0.12) | |||
Stratum dummies | Y | Y | Y | Y |
Mean of Group B(control group) | 0.12 | 0.12 | 0.12 | |
R-squared | 0.57 | 0.56 | 0.46 | 0.56 |
N | 31 | 31 | 31 | 31 |
Panel B: Medium run (as of Round 7) | ||||
Received treatment | 0.39** | 0.35* | ||
(0.17) | (0.19) | |||
Assigned to Group A | 0.72*** | 0.26* | ||
(0.12) | (0.14) | |||
Stratum dummies | Y | Y | Y | Y |
Mean of Group B(control group) | 0.20 | 0.20 | 0.20 | |
R-squared | 0.60 | 0.46 | 0.38 | 0.45 |
N | 29 | 29 | 29 | 29 |
Notes. Table reports results of incentive payment experiment on adoption rates using the conservative definition of adoption. Panel A reports short-run results as of round 6 (January–March 2014). Panel B reports medium-run results as of round 7 (October–December 2014). The dependent variable in column (1) is an indicator variable for whether the firm received treatment. Two firms exited between rounds 6 and 7. All regressions include stratum dummies and report robust standard errors. Significance: *.10, **.05; ***.01.
To check robustness, Table X reports results using an alternative indicator of adoption: whether the firm purchased its first offset die (beyond the trade-in that we paid for) after September 1, 2013. Of the eight firms that accepted the intervention and had not adopted by August 2013, three subsequently purchased their first offset die. (One of these firms had not yet produced with it at the time of our October–December 2014 survey round.)46Table X shows that the positive causal effect of the incentive-payment treatment on adoption is robust to using this alternative measure. As before, we report both short- and medium-run impacts. The short- and medium-run ITT estimates are 0.27 and 0.28, respectively, and are statistically significant at the 5% level.
. | Dep. var.: purchased offset die after Sept. 1, 2013 . | |||
---|---|---|---|---|
. | First . | . | Reduced . | IV . |
. | stage . | OLS . | form (ITT) . | (TOT) . |
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
Panel A: Short run (as of round 6) | ||||
Received treatment | 0.42** | 0.40** | ||
(0.15) | (0.16) | |||
Assigned to Group A | 0.68*** | 0.27** | ||
(0.12) | (0.12) | |||
Stratum dummies | Y | Y | Y | Y |
Mean of Group B(control group) | 0.00 | 0.00 | 0.00 | |
R-squared | 0.57 | 0.40 | 0.24 | 0.40 |
N | 31 | 31 | 31 | 31 |
Panel B: Medium run (as of round 7) | ||||
Received treatment | 0.41** | 0.38** | ||
(0.15) | (0.16) | |||
Assigned to Group A | 0.72*** | 0.28** | ||
(0.12) | (0.12) | |||
Stratum dummies | Y | Y | Y | Y |
Mean of Group B(control group) | 0.00 | 0.00 | 0.00 | |
R-squared | 0.60 | 0.40 | 0.24 | 0.40 |
N | 29 | 29 | 29 | 29 |
. | Dep. var.: purchased offset die after Sept. 1, 2013 . | |||
---|---|---|---|---|
. | First . | . | Reduced . | IV . |
. | stage . | OLS . | form (ITT) . | (TOT) . |
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
Panel A: Short run (as of round 6) | ||||
Received treatment | 0.42** | 0.40** | ||
(0.15) | (0.16) | |||
Assigned to Group A | 0.68*** | 0.27** | ||
(0.12) | (0.12) | |||
Stratum dummies | Y | Y | Y | Y |
Mean of Group B(control group) | 0.00 | 0.00 | 0.00 | |
R-squared | 0.57 | 0.40 | 0.24 | 0.40 |
N | 31 | 31 | 31 | 31 |
Panel B: Medium run (as of round 7) | ||||
Received treatment | 0.41** | 0.38** | ||
(0.15) | (0.16) | |||
Assigned to Group A | 0.72*** | 0.28** | ||
(0.12) | (0.12) | |||
Stratum dummies | Y | Y | Y | Y |
Mean of Group B(control group) | 0.00 | 0.00 | 0.00 | |
R-squared | 0.60 | 0.40 | 0.24 | 0.40 |
N | 29 | 29 | 29 | 29 |
Notes. Table reports results of incentive payment experiment on adoption rates using additional die purchases (beyond the trade-in offer) after September 1, 2013, as the measure of adoption. Panel A reports short-run results as of round 6 (January–March 2014). Panel B reports medium-run results as of round 7 (October–December 2014). The dependent variable in column 1 is an indicator variable for whether the firm received treatment. Two firms exited between rounds 6 and 7. All regressions include stratum dummies and report robust standard errors. Significance: *.10, **.05; ***.01.
. | Dep. var.: purchased offset die after Sept. 1, 2013 . | |||
---|---|---|---|---|
. | First . | . | Reduced . | IV . |
. | stage . | OLS . | form (ITT) . | (TOT) . |
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
Panel A: Short run (as of round 6) | ||||
Received treatment | 0.42** | 0.40** | ||
(0.15) | (0.16) | |||
Assigned to Group A | 0.68*** | 0.27** | ||
(0.12) | (0.12) | |||
Stratum dummies | Y | Y | Y | Y |
Mean of Group B(control group) | 0.00 | 0.00 | 0.00 | |
R-squared | 0.57 | 0.40 | 0.24 | 0.40 |
N | 31 | 31 | 31 | 31 |
Panel B: Medium run (as of round 7) | ||||
Received treatment | 0.41** | 0.38** | ||
(0.15) | (0.16) | |||
Assigned to Group A | 0.72*** | 0.28** | ||
(0.12) | (0.12) | |||
Stratum dummies | Y | Y | Y | Y |
Mean of Group B(control group) | 0.00 | 0.00 | 0.00 | |
R-squared | 0.60 | 0.40 | 0.24 | 0.40 |
N | 29 | 29 | 29 | 29 |
. | Dep. var.: purchased offset die after Sept. 1, 2013 . | |||
---|---|---|---|---|
. | First . | . | Reduced . | IV . |
. | stage . | OLS . | form (ITT) . | (TOT) . |
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . |
Panel A: Short run (as of round 6) | ||||
Received treatment | 0.42** | 0.40** | ||
(0.15) | (0.16) | |||
Assigned to Group A | 0.68*** | 0.27** | ||
(0.12) | (0.12) | |||
Stratum dummies | Y | Y | Y | Y |
Mean of Group B(control group) | 0.00 | 0.00 | 0.00 | |
R-squared | 0.57 | 0.40 | 0.24 | 0.40 |
N | 31 | 31 | 31 | 31 |
Panel B: Medium run (as of round 7) | ||||
Received treatment | 0.41** | 0.38** | ||
(0.15) | (0.16) | |||
Assigned to Group A | 0.72*** | 0.28** | ||
(0.12) | (0.12) | |||
Stratum dummies | Y | Y | Y | Y |
Mean of Group B(control group) | 0.00 | 0.00 | 0.00 | |
R-squared | 0.60 | 0.40 | 0.24 | 0.40 |
N | 29 | 29 | 29 | 29 |
Notes. Table reports results of incentive payment experiment on adoption rates using additional die purchases (beyond the trade-in offer) after September 1, 2013, as the measure of adoption. Panel A reports short-run results as of round 6 (January–March 2014). Panel B reports medium-run results as of round 7 (October–December 2014). The dependent variable in column 1 is an indicator variable for whether the firm received treatment. Two firms exited between rounds 6 and 7. All regressions include stratum dummies and report robust standard errors. Significance: *.10, **.05; ***.01.
It is important to acknowledge that the sample sizes in the incentive payment experiment are small. An alternative to large-N statistical inference are permutation tests whose properties are independent of sample size. (See Bloom et al. 2013 for the use of this type of inference in a similar context.) We determine the proportion of all 25,872,000 possible treatment assignments that would produce coefficients as large as or larger than the ones we find (holding the observed outcome for each firm unchanged).47 This procedure does not require asymptotic approximations. Given the selection discussion above, we focus on the ITT estimates in column (3) of Tables VIII–X. Online Appendix Figure A.11 plots the distribution of coefficients obtained from regressing the liberal adoption measure on assignment to Group A for the millions of possible treatment assignments. Because of the small number of adopters, there are only a handful of possible coefficients, despite the large number of possible assignments. For the short run, our estimated ITT is the most extreme coefficient that could be observed under any treatment assignment and is equal to the critical value for a 1% significance test. For the medium run, where we would expect the treatment effect to have begun to attenuate, a fraction 0.061 of assignments are more extreme and our point estimate is equal to the critical value for a 10% significance test. Online Appendix Figure A.12 reports the corresponding plots using the conservative adoption measure. Our short-run ITT estimate lies between the 1% and 5% critical values, with a fraction 0.018 of assignments being more extreme. Our medium-run ITT estimate lies just below the 10% critical value with a fraction 0.118 of assignments being more extreme. Online Appendix Figure A.13 presents a similar analysis for our alternative indicator of adoption: die purchases. The short-run ITT estimate is the most extreme outcome possible and is equal to the 1% critical value. The medium-run ITT estimate is equal to the 5% critical value, with a fraction 0.036 of assignments being more extreme.
To sum up: although the level of significance dips slightly below 90% in one of the specifications (using the more conservative adoption measure and the small-sample-robust permutation test in the medium-run specification, when we would expect the effect to have begun to attenuate), overall the results strongly suggest that, consistent with our theoretical model of misaligned incentives, the incentive payment treatment spurred adoption among firms.
VII. Additional Evidence on Mechanisms
In this section, we present additional (nonexperimental) evidence on two key features of our theoretical model: wage stickiness and information flows within the firm. So as not to reveal the existence of the offset die to non-tech-drop firms, most of the questions we discuss were asked only of the 31 tech-drop firms involved in the second experiment, and we focus on these tech-drop firms throughout this section. (This section focuses on responses from round 7 of our survey, conducted in October–December 2014.)
To shed light on wage stickiness, we recorded the wages of cutters and printers for each month between August 2013 and September 2014. Generally, it appears that firms change wages relatively seldom. Of the 24 tech-drop firms that provided complete information, 10 did not change the head cutter’s wage at all over the entire 13-month period, a period of 8.4% annual inflation (Online Appendix Table A.10). Thirteen out of 24 did not change the wage for the head printer. This evidence is corroborated by the survey responses from the head cutters and printers themselves: only 2 out of 15 cutters who responded indicated that their wage had changed during this period, and only 4 out of 17 printers reported a change. We asked firms why they changed wages, and the responses for the few firms that provided answers are in Online Appendix Table A.11. The two main reasons cited by owners were (a) inflation and (b) the change was a regular “end of year” change. Only one firm reported changing wages because of the offset die. In addition to the reasons discussed already, another possible reason for the wage stickiness is that it is conventional to use round numbers for piece rates. Online Appendix Figure A.14 shows that 78% of piece rates are 1, 1.5, 2, 2.5, 3, or 4 rupees per ball. Given this convention, it may be that wage increases must be reasonably large when they occur. These several pieces of evidence reinforce the idea that piece rates are sticky, consistent with the theoretical ideas (i) that they are chosen in stage 1 of the game, prior to the technology arriving, and (ii) that there is a significant cost to adopting contracts that involve changing piece rates.
We also asked owners and head cutters directly why payments were not conditioned on the technology and whether such a possibility was ever discussed. The reason cited most often by owners (6 out of 18) was that offering such incentives would lead workers to expect additional incentives in the future. The next two most common answers were that workers would perceive these incentives as unfair or that the owners did not think of it (Online Appendix Table A.12). Cutters overwhelmingly stated that they feel it is not their place to make suggestions to the owner about the payment schemes (Online Appendix Table A.13). In almost no case did the owner report discussing payments to adopt the die with any employee (Online Appendix Table A.14). Similarly, cutters never reported talking to the owner or other co-workers about payments to adopt the die. These responses are consistent with both of the hypotheses for lack of adjustment of contracts: that owners and cutters were largely unaware of the possibility of conditional contracts, or that both were aware of the contracts but there were transaction costs associated with adopting them.
Turning to information flows within the firm, we asked owners if they had ever had a conversation with their head cutter, other cutters, or head printer about whether to adopt the offset die.48 It appears that this question did not capture all forms of communication between owners and cutters. For instance, of the 10 firms that reported “cutters unwilling” as the main reason for not adopting the technology in round 4 of our survey (Table VI), only 6 reported that they had had a conversation with the head cutter about whether to adopt the die. Presumably the remaining respondents received signals from cutters through less direct means or were too proud to admit to taking advice from subordinates. With this caveat, the responses do suggest that owners were swayed by the opinions of cutters in their adoption decisions. Ten of 22 respondents reported consulting with their head cutter about the decision (Online Appendix Table A.15). There is a clear association between what the cutter recommends and what owners eventually do. Online Appendix Table A.16 reports the recommendations given by the cutters in the 10 cases where owners report consulting them, and the firms’ corresponding adoption decisions using the liberal definition. In all three instances where the head cutter recommended adopting, the firm adopted; in four of the six instances where the head cutter’s recommendation was negative, the firm did not adopt.49 These responses are consistent with the assumption in the model that owners are less informed than cutters, and the result that in some circumstances the principal finds it worthwhile to follow the cutter’s advice.
As mentioned, additional corroborative evidence for our story comes from firms’ experience with a previous innovation in the cutting process. Prior to 1994, all firms used a single-panel die to cut pentagons. In 1994, the first firms began using the two-panel nonoffset pentagon die pictured on the right side of Figure I, referred to in Sialkot as the back-to-back die. This die is much faster than a single-pentagon die, since each strike by the hydraulic press cuts two pentagons, and the die does not appear to have reduced the number of pentagons per sheet. Owners report that the back-to-back die was adopted much more quickly than our offset die has been, and with little resistance from cutters. All 14 owners who could recall the speed of adoption indicated that they adopted the die within six months of hearing about it (Online Appendix Table A.17). Furthermore, 23 out of the 24 respondents report there was no resistance among cutters to adopt this die (Online Appendix Table A.18) and very few firms changed their payment structure in any way (Online Appendix Table A.19). Relating this evidence to our theory, the back-to-back die can be interpreted as corresponding to technology type θ3 (equal marginal cost but faster than the existing technology), which both principal and agent want to adopt. The fact that the back-to-back die was adopted quickly and with little resistance from cutters reinforces two ideas from the theory: first, that cutters’ and owners’ interests over some new technologies coincide (a precondition for informative communication); and second, that the misalignment of incentives for our offset die is (at least in part) responsible for the slow adoption of it.
VIII. Alternative Hypotheses
Here we examine what we consider to be the two leading competing explanations for the results of our second experiment: (i) that we mechanically induced firms to adopt by subsidizing the fixed costs of adoption, rather than by aligning incentives and inducing information flows within firms; and (ii) that we simply increased the salience of the new technology and this in itself led firms to adopt.
VIII.A. Subsidies for Fixed Costs
Suppose in our model that the principal and agent had the same information about the technology. The owner would then simply weigh the expected variable cost reduction from the new technology against the fixed costs of adoption, F. These fixed costs might include a lump-sum bonus to workers to compensate them for a learning period in which their incomes are reduced. Our incentive payment experiment could be seen as providing a subsidy for these fixed costs, and the subsidy may itself have induced the owner to adopt.
As a first step toward answering the quantitative plausibility question, suppose that there is no uncertainty about the technology (i.e., P = 1) and no unobserved fixed costs (i.e., no fixed costs beyond the US|${\$}$|428). Under these assumptions, equation (1) can be reconciled with nonadoption only if firms face extremely high interest rates and hence have a small effective discount factor |$\frac{1}{1+r}$|.53 The values of firm-specific interest rates that set Πf = 0 in equation (1) represent lower bounds on the firm-specific interest rates for nonadopters. At the 10th percentile, the lower bound is 13.8% per month; at the 90th percentile, the lower bound is 134% per month. We asked firms explicitly about the interest rates they face, and the responses ranged from 9% to 25% per year; these are an order of magnitude lower than the implied lower bound for most firms. That is, in the absence of both uncertainty about the technology and unobserved fixed costs, the interest rates (or rate of discounting) that would be required to explain the low initial rates of adoption appear to be implausibly high.
This argument leaves open the possibility that some combination of uncertainty and unobserved fixed costs can account for the low initial rates of adoption we observed. To address this possibility, we take a different approach: we allow for both uncertainty and unobserved fixed costs and ask whether these can explain both the low rates of initial adoption and the magnitude of the response to our incentive payment intervention. The unobserved fixed costs may represent attention costs for the owner or psychic costs involved in changing established routines. We assume, conservatively, that the interest rate is the highest of the self-reported interest rates, 25% a year. As a benchmark, we assume that owners place a 50% probability on the event that the technology works as we described (i.e., P = 0.5); we consider alternative priors below. Under these assumptions, we can place bounds on the values of unobserved fixed costs that can explain the behavior we observe. In particular, from equation (1), if a firm does not adopt initially, it must be that Πf < 0 and hence that |$F_{f} > (0.5)\frac{NVB_{f}}{0.0187}$|. (A 25% annualized interest rate corresponds to a 1.87% monthly rate.) If a firm adopts in response to the incentive payment experiment, it must be that Πf > 0 after the US|${\$}$|320 reduction in fixed costs, and hence that |$F_{f} < (0.5)\frac{NVB_{f}}{0.0187} + 320$|. These bounds on fixed costs are plotted by rank in Figure V for the 31 firms in the incentive payment experiment (using the liberal adoption measure). The solid black bars indicate upper bounds on fixed costs for the initial adopters (for which we can only calculate upper bounds). The white bars indicate lower bounds for the never-adopters (for which we can only calculate lower bounds). The solid gray bars indicate lower bounds for initial nonadopters that adopted in response to the incentive treatment (i.e., compliers in experiment 2); the black outlines above the solid gray bars indicate upper bounds for these firms. The figure highlights that the US|${\$}$|320 subsidy (indicated by the distance between the top of the solid gray bars and the black outlines just above them) is small relative to the implied lower bound on fixed costs for almost all initial nonadopters.

Implied Bounds on Fixed Costs under a Learning Subsidy Explanation
Figure displays implied bounds on fixed costs for each firm in the incentive payment intervention, assuming a 25% annual interest rate and a prior of 0.5 that the technology works (see Section VIII.A). Solid black bars indicate upper bounds for the initial adopters, and white bars indicate lower bounds for the never-adopters. Solid gray bars indicate lower bounds for initial nonadopters that adopted in response to the incentive treatment (experiment 2 compliers); black outlines above the solid gray bars indicate upper bounds for these firms. (Unobserved fixed costs can simultaneously explain both initial nonadoption and subsequent adoption for these firms only if they fall between top of gray bar and black outline.)
. | Value of prior for whether offset die . | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | works as described . | |||||
. | 0.01 . | 0.05 . | 0.1 . | 0.25 . | 0.5 . | 1 . |
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . | (6) . |
Panel A: Estimates of fixed costs | ||||||
Estimate of μ | 6.46*** | 7.41*** | 8.00*** | 8.85*** | 9.53*** | 10.21*** |
(0.50) | (0.30) | (0.29) | (0.28) | (0.28) | (0.28) | |
Estimate of σε | 1.87** | 1.29** | 1.23*** | 1.21*** | 1.20*** | 1.20*** |
(0.75) | (0.48) | (0.44) | (0.41) | (0.40) | (0.40) | |
N | 31 | 31 | 31 | 31 | 31 | 31 |
Panel B: ITT estimate | ||||||
Assigned to Group A | 0.24 | 0.10 | 0.06 | 0.03 | 0.01 | 0.01 |
(0.11) | (0.09) | (0.06) | (0.04) | (0.03) | (0.02) | |
N | 31 | 31 | 31 | 31 | 31 | 31 |
Panel C: p-values of observing ≥5 adopters in incentive payment experiment | ||||||
.234 | .013 | .000 | .000 | .000 | .000 |
. | Value of prior for whether offset die . | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | works as described . | |||||
. | 0.01 . | 0.05 . | 0.1 . | 0.25 . | 0.5 . | 1 . |
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . | (6) . |
Panel A: Estimates of fixed costs | ||||||
Estimate of μ | 6.46*** | 7.41*** | 8.00*** | 8.85*** | 9.53*** | 10.21*** |
(0.50) | (0.30) | (0.29) | (0.28) | (0.28) | (0.28) | |
Estimate of σε | 1.87** | 1.29** | 1.23*** | 1.21*** | 1.20*** | 1.20*** |
(0.75) | (0.48) | (0.44) | (0.41) | (0.40) | (0.40) | |
N | 31 | 31 | 31 | 31 | 31 | 31 |
Panel B: ITT estimate | ||||||
Assigned to Group A | 0.24 | 0.10 | 0.06 | 0.03 | 0.01 | 0.01 |
(0.11) | (0.09) | (0.06) | (0.04) | (0.03) | (0.02) | |
N | 31 | 31 | 31 | 31 | 31 | 31 |
Panel C: p-values of observing ≥5 adopters in incentive payment experiment | ||||||
.234 | .013 | .000 | .000 | .000 | .000 |
Notes. Sample is tech-drop firms still active at the time of second experiment (September 2013). Panel A reports estimates for μ and σε from maximizing the likelihood function in equation (3) for the value of prior noted in the column heading. Panel B reports the average and standard deviation of the ITT estimates across 1,000 simulation draws of log fixed costs from a normal distribution with mean |$\hat{\mu }$| and standard deviation |$\hat{\sigma }_\varepsilon$| for the corresponding prior. Panel C reports the p-values of observing five or more adopters in the short run (recall that we observed five adopters in the short run according to the liberal-definition adoption variable), based on the frequency of occurrence in the 1,000 simulations, under the null hypothesis that the second experiment only changed fixed costs. Significance: *.10, **.05, ***.01.
. | Value of prior for whether offset die . | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | works as described . | |||||
. | 0.01 . | 0.05 . | 0.1 . | 0.25 . | 0.5 . | 1 . |
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . | (6) . |
Panel A: Estimates of fixed costs | ||||||
Estimate of μ | 6.46*** | 7.41*** | 8.00*** | 8.85*** | 9.53*** | 10.21*** |
(0.50) | (0.30) | (0.29) | (0.28) | (0.28) | (0.28) | |
Estimate of σε | 1.87** | 1.29** | 1.23*** | 1.21*** | 1.20*** | 1.20*** |
(0.75) | (0.48) | (0.44) | (0.41) | (0.40) | (0.40) | |
N | 31 | 31 | 31 | 31 | 31 | 31 |
Panel B: ITT estimate | ||||||
Assigned to Group A | 0.24 | 0.10 | 0.06 | 0.03 | 0.01 | 0.01 |
(0.11) | (0.09) | (0.06) | (0.04) | (0.03) | (0.02) | |
N | 31 | 31 | 31 | 31 | 31 | 31 |
Panel C: p-values of observing ≥5 adopters in incentive payment experiment | ||||||
.234 | .013 | .000 | .000 | .000 | .000 |
. | Value of prior for whether offset die . | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
. | works as described . | |||||
. | 0.01 . | 0.05 . | 0.1 . | 0.25 . | 0.5 . | 1 . |
. | (1) . | (2) . | (3) . | (4) . | (5) . | (6) . |
Panel A: Estimates of fixed costs | ||||||
Estimate of μ | 6.46*** | 7.41*** | 8.00*** | 8.85*** | 9.53*** | 10.21*** |
(0.50) | (0.30) | (0.29) | (0.28) | (0.28) | (0.28) | |
Estimate of σε | 1.87** | 1.29** | 1.23*** | 1.21*** | 1.20*** | 1.20*** |
(0.75) | (0.48) | (0.44) | (0.41) | (0.40) | (0.40) | |
N | 31 | 31 | 31 | 31 | 31 | 31 |
Panel B: ITT estimate | ||||||
Assigned to Group A | 0.24 | 0.10 | 0.06 | 0.03 | 0.01 | 0.01 |
(0.11) | (0.09) | (0.06) | (0.04) | (0.03) | (0.02) | |
N | 31 | 31 | 31 | 31 | 31 | 31 |
Panel C: p-values of observing ≥5 adopters in incentive payment experiment | ||||||
.234 | .013 | .000 | .000 | .000 | .000 |
Notes. Sample is tech-drop firms still active at the time of second experiment (September 2013). Panel A reports estimates for μ and σε from maximizing the likelihood function in equation (3) for the value of prior noted in the column heading. Panel B reports the average and standard deviation of the ITT estimates across 1,000 simulation draws of log fixed costs from a normal distribution with mean |$\hat{\mu }$| and standard deviation |$\hat{\sigma }_\varepsilon$| for the corresponding prior. Panel C reports the p-values of observing five or more adopters in the short run (recall that we observed five adopters in the short run according to the liberal-definition adoption variable), based on the frequency of occurrence in the 1,000 simulations, under the null hypothesis that the second experiment only changed fixed costs. Significance: *.10, **.05, ***.01.
VIII.B. Salience
A second alternative explanation is that the incentive payment treatment increased the salience of the new technology and that this itself led firms to adopt, independent of any effects on information flows within the firm. There are two variants of this explanation. One variant is that the reminder about the technology during the incentive-intervention visit “nudged” firms into adoption. This variant seems an unlikely explanation. We gave the same reminder to the control firms for the incentive intervention (Group B firms) and we saw no firms adopt in the next six months as a result. Also, it is worth noting that we visited all of the tech-drop firms multiple times in our survey rounds. During each visit, we discussed the new technology with them and if they were not using it we asked why.
A subtler variant of the salience story is that by putting more money on the table we sent a stronger signal about our own beliefs about the efficacy of our technology, and that this in turn led firms to update their priors about the technology, inducing some to adopt. While this explanation is sufficiently flexible that it is difficult to dismiss definitively, it also seems unlikely to have played a major role. We believe that it was clear to firms from the outset, in the initial technology-drop implementation, that we thought that the technology was effective. We then returned to each firm numerous times and in the case of the tech-drop firms discussed the offset die each time. The amount of money we spent on surveying each firm far exceeded the US|${\$}$|320 payment in the incentive intervention. In short, although in retrospect it seems clear that many owners did not believe us when we told them that the technology works, it does not appear that their skepticism was based on their beliefs about how strongly we held our beliefs, or that the US|${\$}$|320 affected their beliefs about how strongly we held our beliefs. It seems more likely that they simply thought all along that we had insufficient knowledge and experience in the industry, and hence that our (strongly held) confidence in the technology was misplaced.
IX. Conclusion
This article has two basic empirical findings. First, despite the evident advantages of the technology we invented, a surprisingly small number of firms have adopted it, even among the set of firms we gave it to. This is consistent with a long tradition of research that has found diffusion to be slow for many technologies, but given the characteristics of our technology—low fixed costs, minimal required changes to other aspects of the production process, easily measured cost advantages—the low adoption rate seems particularly puzzling. Second, with a modest change to the incentives of key employees in the firm—very small in monetary terms relative to firms’ revenues and the benefits of adoption—we induced a statistically significant increase in adoption. This is consistent with the hypothesis that a misalignment of incentives within the firm is an important barrier to adoption. Although we do not observe all of the communication between employees and owners, it appears that at least one way that employees have resisted the adoption of our new technology is by misinforming owners about the value of the technology. It further appears that the incentive payment intervention had a significant effect because it induced workers to reveal the benefits of the technology.
A natural question is why many owners did not simply change the payment scheme on their own, to give employees a greater incentive to adopt the new technology. Survey evidence indicates that some firms are not aware of the availability of alternative payment schemes, and that many firms believe that there are nontrivial transaction costs involved in changing contracts, even implicit ones. One would expect owners to weigh any costs of modifying contracts against the expected benefits of adopting new technologies. If owners have low priors that a new technology is beneficial (or that a beneficial new technology will arrive in the future), they may rationally be unwilling to pay even quite small transaction costs. Although it is difficult for us to distinguish empirically between lack of awareness of alternative contracts and stickiness of contracts as explanations for why owners did not change payment schemes, the key point is that many owners did not in fact change schemes, and this left scope for our very modest incentive intervention to have a large effect on adoption.
Our study carried out a particular intervention with a particular technology in a particular sector. This naturally raises questions about external validity. For example, both of our experiments were relatively hands-off: we gave limited advice to firms after the initial demonstration in the first experiment, or the incentive payment in the second. Would organizational barriers still hinder adoption if the innovators (or their salespeople) had financial incentives to work with firms to promote adoption? We strongly suspect so, since there would still be costs associated with overcoming such barriers, and it is not clear that innovators’ incentives would be strong enough to induce them to pay such costs for firms, or that the firms themselves would be willing ex ante to grant innovators the access and time to identify the barriers and resolve them (especially if they receive negative feedback about the technology from their own workers).57 Nevertheless, we recognize that more research is required, in other sectors, with other technologies, to determine to what extent our findings in Sialkot can be generalized.
With that caveat, we believe that three implications of our study are likely to apply more broadly. First, we have provided reasonably direct evidence of a complementarity, in the sense of Milgrom and Roberts (1990, 1995), between a technological innovation (the offset die) and an organizational innovation (conditional wage contracts). We suspect that similar complementarities between technical and organizational innovations exist in many other settings, and that it is common for technology adoption to require organizational changes to be successful.
Second, there appears to be a form of inertia in employment relationships that can hinder technological change. We have argued that firms’ choices of labor contracts depend on the rate at which beneficial new technologies are expected to arrive. It also appears that labor contracts, once established, are difficult to modify. The implication is that firms and industries that evolve in technologically stable environments may be less able to adapt to technological change than new firms and industries, or firms and industries that evolve in technologically dynamic environments. Simple piece-rate contracts may well have been optimal for firms in Sialkot before we showed up, but the very fact that firms in Sialkot have been producing for decades using them may itself have contributed to low adoption rates of the offset die.
Finally, it seems likely that for technology adoption to be successful, employees need to have an expectation that they will share in the gains from adoption. Such an expectation may be generated by a variety of different types of contracts, implicit or explicit. But to the extent that firms must rely on the knowledge of shopfloor workers about the value of new technologies or how best to implement them, it appears to be important that some sort of credible gain-sharing mechanism be in place.
In a well-cited review article, Geroski (2000, 604) writes: “The central feature of most discussions of technology diffusion is the apparently slow speed at which firms adopt new technologies.” Perhaps the foremost economic historian of technology, Nathan Rosenberg, writes “If one examines the history of the diffusion of many inventions, one cannot help being struck by two characteristics of the diffusion process: its apparent overall slowness on the one hand and the wide variations in the rates of acceptance of different inventions on the other” (Rosenberg 1972, 6).
See, for instance, Ryan and Gross (1943), Griliches (1957), Coleman, Katz, and Menzel (1966), Foster and Rosenzweig (1995), and Conley and Udry (2010).
In this introduction, we use our “liberal” measure of adoption; see Section III for a discussion of our “liberal” and “conservative” adoption measures.
Our data suggest that the long-run speed is only slightly slower than for the existing die, although the workers did not know this prior to adoption and may plausibly have been worried that they would be substantially slower in the long run as well as the short.
If we assume, following Crawford and Sobel (1982), that players are able to coordinate on the “most informative” equilibrium in every cheap-talk subgame, then this equilibrium is unique.
A recent study by Hardy and McCasland (2016), which appeared after our paper was widely circulated, randomly allocated a weaving technology to textile producers in Ghana, but focuses on diffusion rather than barriers to adoption.
A more recent precursor is a case study by Freeman and Kleiner (2005), which provides descriptive evidence that a U.S. shoe company’s shift away from piece rates helped it increase productivity.
Also related are recent papers on adoption of health technologies in the presence of externalities (Miguel and Kremer 2004; Cohen and Dupas 2010; Dupas,2014), on adoption of change-holding behavior by Kenyan retail micro-enterprises (Beaman, Magruder, and Robinson 2014), and on adoption of energy efficient technologies by households and firms in the United States (Anderson and Newell 2004; Fowlie, Greenstone, and Wolfram 2015a, 2015b). Again, organizational conflict does not appear to play an important role in these settings.
Our study is also related to the “insider econometrics” literature reviewed by Ichniowski and Shaw (2013), which focuses on relationships between management practices and productivity, typically in a cross-sectional context, and generally does not focus on technology adoption. A recent experimental study by Khan, Khwaja, and Olken (2016) of tax collectors in Pakistan focuses on a related issue: the effect of altering wage contracts on employee performance.
Lazear (1986) also notes that workers under a piece-rate scheme may have an incentive to restrict output to avoid such a ratchet effect, but argues that (assuming employers can commit to future contracts) this can be counteracted by a suitable set of piece rates in all periods. The key difference between Lazear (1986) and Gibbons (1987) is the assumption about the employer’s ability to commit.
This idea has parallels in the work of Marglin (1974) and Stole and Zwiebel (1996), who argue that owners may prefer technically less efficient technologies that shift the distribution of rents in their favor. Also related, with very different emphases, are Dearden, Ickes, and Samuelson (1990), Aghion and Tirole (1997), Dessein (2002), and Krishna and Morgan (2008).
Whereas the literature reviewed by Garicano and Rayo (2016) has focused on major technical disruptions, this article shows that firms have difficulty adapting even to incremental technological improvements. While the forgone surplus is modest in this case, it seems plausible that such mini-failures are common in organizations and that their cumulative effect is substantial.
The evolution of soccer-ball imports to the United States (which tracks soccer balls specifically, unlike other major importers) is shown in Online Appendix Figure A.1.
The ball for the 2014 World Cup, also produced in Sialkot, used a new thermo-molding technology.
All of the owners and employees we have encountered have been men.
One might wonder whether firms in Sialkot also observed the production process in the Chinese firm producing for Adidas, since it was so easy for us to do so. We found one owner, of one of the larger firms in Sialkot, who said that he had been to China and observed the offset cutting pattern (illustrated in the left panel in Figure IV) and was planning to implement it on a new large cutting press to cut half a laminated rexine sheet at once, a process known as “table cutting.” As of May 2012, he had not yet implemented the new pattern, however, and he had not developed a hand-held offset die. It is also important to note that two of the largest firms in Sialkot have not allowed us to see their production processes. Because these two firms are known to produce for Adidas, we suspect that they were aware of the offset cutting pattern before we arrived. What is clear, however, is that neither the offset cutting pattern nor the offset die were in use in any other firm we visited as of the beginning of our experiment in May 2012.
The cutting pattern represents the densest known packing of regular pentagons into a plane. Kuperberg and Kuperberg (1990) conjecture that the pattern represents the densest possible packing, but this is not a theorem.
If a cutter reduces the margin between cuts, or if the laminated rexine sheet is slightly larger than 39 in by 54 in, it is possible to cut more than 272 pentagons with a size 44 mm die.
In the baseline survey, firms were asked for a cost breakdown of a size 5 promotional ball with two layers (one cotton and one polyester), the rexine they most commonly use on a two-layer size 5 promotional ball, a glue composed of 50% latex and 50% chemical substitute (a cheaper alternative), and a 60–65 g inflatable latex bladder.
The exchange rate has varied from 90 Rs/US|${\$}$| to 105 Rs/US|${\$}$| over the period of the study. To make calculations easy, we use an exchange rate of 100 Rs/US|${\$}$| throughout the article.
As discussed below, in our first experiment firms were stratified according to total monthly output (measured in number of balls) at baseline. One stratum (the “late responder” stratum) is composed of firms that did not respond to the baseline survey. Because information on laminated rexine shares was collected only at baseline, we draw laminated rexine shares for late responders from the empirical distribution that pools the other strata. (We do not pool for the other variables, for which we have information on the late responders from later rounds.)
Note that because a firm at a given percentile of the distribution of rexine cost reductions is not necessarily the same as the firm at that percentile of the distribution of rexine as a share of cost, the numbers should not be multiplied across rows for a particular percentile.
As noted, the two-pentagon version of the offset die has proven more popular with firms. As discussed in more detail in Section IV, we offered firms the ability to trade in the four-pentagon die, and all firms that traded in requested the less expensive two-pentagon version. This suggests that any potential speed benefits from cutting four pentagons at a time with the four pentagon die are negated by the fact that it is heavier and more difficult to maneuver.
The cutter wage as a share of costs reported here is lower than in Online Appendix Table A.1 because that table reports input components as a share of the cost of a promotional ball. In Table II, we explicitly account for firms’ product mixes across promotional, training, and match balls. To get the firm’s average ball cost, we divide its reported price by 1 plus its reported profit margin for each ball type and then construct a weighted-average unit cost using output weights for each type. The cutter share of cost is calculated as the per-ball payment divided by this weighted-average unit cost.
After the endline survey, we conducted a short survey on firms in experiment 2 (see Section VI) to collect information on deadlines and defect rates. As shown in Online Appendix Table A.2, Panel A, defect rates for the traditional and offset dies (reported by adopters) are virtually identical. Moreover, firms did not appear concerned about missing orders prior to adopting the die, nor did any adopter report missing an order deadline because the offset die was too slow. The table further reveals that the cutting stage is not a bottleneck in the production process (Online Appendix Table A.2, Panel B). At full capacity, the median firm only requires 20 days a month of cutting. Firms easily adjust to reach full capacity, or to meet tight deadlines, by expanding both the number of cutters and the hours each cutter works. Moreover, most firms can find an additional cutter within a day or less. Taken together, this evidence indicates that firms were not concerned about missing deadlines if they adopted the offset die.
The employment numbers understate the true size of firms since the most labor-intensive stage of production, stitching, is often done outside of firms in stitching centers or homes.
In a later survey round, we found that more than 90% of firms pay their printers a piece rate.
Spillovers are thought to be a key mechanism generating increasing returns, and they also provide the primary economic rationale for industrial policies to increase investment in innovation. To investigate such spillovers and their pathways, we collected detailed data on firm networks, as mentioned in Section III. We chose the number of firms to be treated based on calculations for statistical power to pick up spillover effects. We are continuing to track information flows and adoption by non-tech-drop firms, and are planning to analyze the patterns in the companion project. But given the low adoption rates among the tech-drop firms—and hence the very limited adoption among firms who did not receive the technology—we decided to focus first on the puzzle of low take-up among the firms we gave the technology to. We chose not to do the second experiment on the non-tech-drop firms (cash-drop and no-drop groups) from the first experiment for the reasons discussed in note 44. There are natural synergies between the two projects because in the presence of misaligned incentives, we would predict that spillovers disproportionately originate from firms with better alignment of incentives.
In an experiment with micro-enterprises in Sri Lanka, de Mel, McKenzie, and Woodruff (2008) find very high returns—higher than going interest rates—to drops of cash of US|${\$}$|100 or US|${\$}$|200 (or of capital of roughly similar magnitudes), suggesting that the micro-enterprises operate under credit constraints. Although our prior was that the cash value of the offset die would matter less to the larger firms in our sample, we included the cash-drop component to be able to separate the effect of the shock to capital from the effect of knowledge about the technology.
At the moment of assignment, we believed that there were 88 active initial-responder firms with 22 in each stratum. In each stratum, 6 firms were assigned to the tech-drop group, 3 to cash-drop group, and 13 to the no-drop group. Three firms that responded to our baseline survey subsequently either shut down or were revealed not to be firms by our definition, leaving 85 firms.
We impose restrictions on the parameters of the model such that, for all the values of the piece rate that will be relevant, the principal, if she knew the technology type with certainty, would choose to adopt technology types θ2 and θ3 and not type θ1. In addition, the restrictions imply that the principal would not adopt the new technology given only her priors.
A word of explanation about whether the equilibrium involves misinformation: formally, the actual words that the agent uses to convey his message are immaterial; what matters is how the principal interprets the message, and in the Proposition 1 equilibrium the principal interprets “technology is bad” to mean “technology is type θ1 or θ2”. In this sense, the agent technically does not misinform the principal about type θ2, and we avoid using this terminology in the theory. But in the empirical setting we have found that workers tend to use particular words to discourage adoption that paint the type θ2 technology as ineffective, and describing the communication as misinformation there is more apt.
Crawford and Sobel (1982) argue that the most informative equilibrium is “a reasonable one for agents to coordinate on” because it is Pareto-optimal in their setting. Other justifications for the assumption have also been discussed in the literature; see, for example, Chen, Kartik, and Sobel (2008).
In our model, marginal cost is revealed in stage 6, after effort has been supplied in stage 5. Since the game is one-shot, the principal would have an incentive not to pay the higher piece rate as promised. (This incentive would be present under the existing technology as well, but it seems plausible that it would be more difficult for firms to avoid paying the going rate in the industry, which here corresponds to the optimal piece rate under the existing technology.)
A third view should be considered: that the pure (nonconditional) piece rate is a first-best contract (with no misalignment of incentives) ex ante, and the misalignment arises only because of the intervening shock. In our model, this can be interpreted as a limiting case of the second view above, where ex ante the owner is certain that the technology is not of type θ2 (that is, ρ2 = 0).
In the end, one-third of firms chose not to participate in the much less invasive intervention we decided to implement; see Section VI for details. This confirmed our earlier belief that firms’ willingness to participate would be limited.
Note, however, that the required size of the lump-sum transfer may vary across workers, depending on individual and firm characteristics. In the first anecdote above, for instance, it appears that the proposed payment was not large enough to induce the cutter to report accurately. In all other cases it appears that the proposed transfer was large enough to induce cutters to participate in the intervention.
At the time of randomization, we believed that 34 of these firms were still active. Three of these were subsequently revealed to have stopped manufacturing soccer balls.
As shown in Table V, there were four adopters as of August 2013 in the full sample using the conservative definition (which is based on our survey data), and five adopters according to the liberal definition (which combines survey data with field reports submitted by our enumerators). We stratified using the liberal definition, our preferred measure.
To the extent possible, we attempted to make the payment directly to the cutter and printer. In two cases, the owner insisted that we pay him and that he pass on the money to the employees, and we acceded to this request.
The three-minute targets were chosen after conducting speed tests at two of the pilot firms mentioned in Section IV. They are approximately 33% higher than the time to cut a single sheet using the original die and the time to print 48 two-pentagon panels cut using the original die.
Because of an error by our enumerators, one firm that was assigned to Group B was offered the incentive payment intervention. This occurred while two coauthors were in the field, and the error was caught within hours of its occurrence. To maintain balance, we randomly selected one as-yet-untreated Group A firm from the same stratum and reassigned it to Group B. As neither firm adopted, our results hold with the original randomization (available on request).
In 2 of these 10 firms, it was not possible to complete the printer performance test.
An interesting question to consider is how our estimates would differ if we had included the non-tech-drop firms in our second experiment—that is, if we had offered the technology and incentive payment at the same time to firms that had not received the offset die initially. We suspect that the ITT estimate would have been larger among these firms. Among the original tech-drop firms, cutters that did not reveal that the technology was a good one before experiment 2 may have been particularly reluctant to do so in experiment 2, since it would have revealed that they had previously been misreporting the benefits of the technology. By contrast, if we had given the technology and incentive simultaneously to the original non-tech-drop firms, cutters in those firms would have had no reason to be reluctant. Because of this difference, treating the non-tech-drop firms in experiment 2 would not have represented a simple increase in sample size.
Online Appendix Tables A.7–A.9 rerun the results using more stringent adoption thresholds of 5,000, 10,000, or 20,000 balls, respectively (as opposed to the 1,000 ball threshold used in Tables VIII–IX). The results are even stronger because no control firm is classified as an adopter using these cutoffs. Note that the adoption rates are the same for the 5,000 and 10,000 cutoffs, so the numbers in those tables are identical to each other.
In addition, one large Group A firm that was already classified as an adopter because it was using the offset cutting pattern for table cutting (see note 16), purchased its first die (beyond the four-panel offset die we originally gave) following the beginning of our intervention.
Within each of the four strata, we assigned treatment status with equal proportion. The stratum of smaller firms contained 6 firms, the stratum of larger firms contained 12 firms, the stratum of initial nonresponders contained 8 firms and the stratum of already-adopters contained 5 firms. This means there are 25,872,000 |$\textstyle=(\mathop{^6_ 3})(\mathop{^{12}_ 6})(\mathop{^8_ 4}) ((\mathop{^5_ 2})+(\mathop{^5_ 3}))$| possible treatment assignments.
The exact wording of the questions was “Did you have a conversation with [the following employee] about whether you should adopt the offset die?” and “If yes, what did they say?” with response codes “(a) the technology is beneficial and should be adopted, (b) the technology is not beneficial and should not be adopted, (c) not sure whether the technology is beneficial or not, (d) other (_____).”
Using the conservative definition, in five of the six cases the firm did not adopt.
Here we are abstracting from the possibility that firms can learn from others about the profitability of adoption, which would tend to lead them to delay adoption (and wait for others to adopt), as emphasized by Foster and Rosenzweig (1995). Such an effect could help to explain low initial adoption, but not the large increase in adoption in response to our second experiment, and the argument of this section that our subsidies were too small to generate the latter would continue to hold in a more complex social-learning model.
As discussed in Section VI.A, we paid Rs 15,000/US|${\$}$|150 to the cutter, Rs 12,000/US|${\$}$|120 to the printer, plus Rs 5,000/US|${\$}$|50 to the owner to cover overhead. In Section II.D, we assumed that workers' wages went up by 100% to compensate them for using the slower technology. The discussions in Sections V and VII suggest that many firms did not adjust their wages and so here we assume that firms make no changes in piece rates but make a one-off lump-sum payment to cutters and printers of the same size as in our experiment 2.
We take these to be the fixed costs per cutter. This is a conservative assumption because it is possible that firms could, for example, share the combing machine across cutters.
This is another way of stating the argument from Section II.D that the observable fixed costs of adoption can be recouped within a relatively short amount of time by almost all firms.
We use the short-run liberal adoption rates for this exercise. Let adopt1f denote an indicator if firm f had adopted the technology in experiment 1, and adopt2f an analogous indicator for adoption after experiment 2. The log likelihood function for Group A firms is:
Table XI, Panel C reports the corresponding probabilities that five or more Group A firms adopt in the short-run (recall that the incentive payment treatment induced five adopters according to the liberal adoption measure). The probability of observing an increase in adoption of that magnitude is exceedingly low, between 0.000 and 0.013, for all but the most pessimistic prior of P = 0.01.
Recall that we visited each treatment firm and performed a demonstration of the technology in front of the owner. This demonstration involved having the firm’s cutter cut using the traditional die and count the pentagons and then cut using the offset die and count the pentagons. The latter was repeated until the cutter achieved 272 pentagons from a sheet. In no case did this require more than three sheets. The nature of the technology is sufficiently transparent that, even if the owners were not convinced of all aspects of the technology, it seems to us implausible that they placed less than 1% probability on the fact that the technology worked as we said it did.
We also believe that our results are directly relevant to a number of real-world settings in which innovations are developed by nonprofits and public sector entities (e.g., agricultural extension services) that have weak financial incentives but that nonetheless aim to promote adoption of beneficial new technologies.
Supplementary Material
An Online Appendix for this article can be found at The Quarterly Journal of Economics online.
References
Author notes
We are grateful to Tariq Raza, our project manager, and to Research Consultants (RCONS), our local survey firm, in particular Irfan Ahmad, Kashif Abid and Syed Hassan Raza Rizvi, for tireless work in carrying out the firm surveys; to Fatima Aqeel, Muhammad Haseeb Ashraf, Sabyasachi Das, Golvine de Rochambeau, Abdul Rehman Khan, Menghan Xu, and Daniel Rappoport for excellent research assistance; to the editor (Pol Antrás) and four anonymous referees whose suggestions greatly improved the manuscript; to Laura Alfaro, Charles Angelucci, Simon Board, Esther Duflo, Florian Ederer, Cecilia Fieler, Dean Karlan, Navin Kartik, Asim Khwaja, Rocco Macchiavello, David McKenzie, Moritz Meyer-ter-Vehn, Ben Olken, Ralph Ossa, Simon Quinn, Anja Sautmann, Chris Udry, Johannes Van Biesebroeck, Rodrigo Wagner, Reed Walker, Chris Woodruff, Daniel Xu, and many seminar audiences for helpful discussions; and to the International Growth Centre, especially Ijaz Nabi and Naved Hamid, and the Private Enterprise Development in Low-Income Countries research initiative for generous research support. We are particularly indebted to Annalisa Guzzini, who shares credit for the invention of the new technology described in the text, and to Naved Hamid, who first suggested we study the soccer-ball sector in Sialkot. All errors are ours.