-
PDF
- Split View
-
Views
-
Cite
Cite
Diana Bonfim, Gil Nogueira, Steven Ongena, “Sorry, We're Closed” Bank Branch Closures, Loan Pricing, and Information Asymmetries, Review of Finance, Volume 25, Issue 4, July 2021, Pages 1211–1259, https://doi.org/10.1093/rof/rfaa036
- Share Icon Share
Abstract
We study local loan conditions when banks close branches. In places where branch closures do not take place, firms that purposely switch banks receive a sixty-three basis points (bps) discount. However, after the closure of nearby branches of their credit-granting banks, firms that locally and hurriedly transfer to other banks receive no such discount. Yet, the loan default rate for the latter (more expensive) transfer loans is on average a full percentage point lower than that for the former (cheaper) switching loans. This suggests that transfer firms are of “better” quality than switching firms. In sum, even if local markets remain competitive, when banks close branches, firms lose.
1. Introduction
Bank branch closures and their impact on local business are a recurring concern for policy makers and empirical researchers alike. Garmaise and Moskowitz (2005), for example, link mergers between large banks in the USA to within-county deteriorating credit conditions, economic development, and crime, while Nguyen (2019) finds that merger-related branch closures cause prolonged declines in small-business lending and employment growth within six to eight miles of the closure. When branches close, credit may be rationed—for example, in so-called banking deserts (Morgan, Pinkovskiy, and Yang, 2016)—or become more expensive due to a softening in local market competition and/or an intensification in spatial price discrimination (Degryse and Ongena, 2005).1
However, if the local market remains competitive and many branches of other banks remain located close-by, what happens to credit conditions for firms connected to the closing bank branch? Do firms simply “walk over to” the nearest branch of another bank, without facing any losses or frictions, as if to buy a standardized commodity from another vendor? Or is it the case that firms incur informational switching costs à la von Thadden (2004) or shoe leather switching costs à la Klemperer (1987) when engaging with the new bank?2 Put differently, is there a “stand-alone” loss for a firm when its bank branch closes? Is this loss observable and measurable at the individual loan level?
To answer these questions, we study firms affected by the closure of a branch of one of their credit-granting banks. In particular, we study individual loan contracts the firms obtain at branches of other banks (that have not lent to the firm recently), and compare them to the contracts of firms that stay with their banks or that switch banks in “regular times” (when no bank branches close).
Portugal provides us with an almost ideal laboratory for our study. Portugal is a representative country with a Gross Domestic Product Purchasing Power Parity (PPP) per capita that ranks 42nd out of 185 countries (International Monetary Fund, 2019 estimates). It has a well-developed financial sector where most firms are uniquely reliant on bank funding. Most firms are small and not publicly listed, which means that apart from the information shared through the accounting and credit registries and the information gathered through a relationship, banks have few other external sources of information to base their credit evaluations on.
After 2012, hundreds of branch closures were forced upon banks in the country, but given the high branch density, it is unlikely that local competition softened. According to the World Bank, in 2012 Portugal was 5th (out of 230 countries), ranked by the number of commercial bank branches per capita. In 2018, Portugal was fourteenth on the same list. Despite the large number of branch closures during this period, it remained one of the countries with the highest branch density in the world. This allows us to focus on disruptions to bank–firm relationships caused by branch closures rather than by changes in local market competition or impaired access to financial services.
Furthermore, Portugal maintains and connects unique datasets that have recently been accessed for fundamental research purposes (e.g., Farinha and Santos, 2002; Iyer et al., 2014; Farinha, Spaliara, and Tsoukas, 2019; Beck, Da-Rocha-Lopes, and Silva, 2020). We singularly collate four unique datasets from the Banco de Portugal (BdP) for the period from June 2012 to December 2015. We collect: (i) a list of all branch closures in Portugal; (ii) a complete overview of all the corporate credit exposures of Portuguese banks; (iii) the interest rates on all new loans; and (iv) the balance sheets and income statements for all Portuguese firms. We arrange all information accurately together by matching on the unique bank and firm identifiers.
We first document that firms that were prompted (by the closure of a branch of their incumbent bank) to “transfer” to another bank receive an almost equal interest rate for their first loan from this other bank to similar (or even the same) firms contemporaneously receive on similar loans from similar (or even the same) banks. We establish similarity of banks, firms, and loans here through coarsened exact matching on various combinations of salient bank, firm, and/or loan characteristics.
So at first sight, one could argue that there are no apparent losses for a firm if one (or more) of its bank branches closes. This argument may, however, be based on an improper counterfactual. Indeed, to obtain a more comprehensive picture one should also compare these transfer loans, originated following branch closures, to switching loans in regular times. Performing such an analysis, we find that when they “switch” banks firms obtain interest rate discounts of around sixty-three bps on average.3
Hence, strikingly, transfer loans do not carry with them any discount while switching loans do. In time, however, discounts reappear for subsequent switching loans or when firms wait more than half a year to transfer to another bank. Discounts are also present when firms decide to transfer to a (non-local) branch of the incumbent bank. However, despite receiving higher interest rates than do switching loans, loan default rates on transfer loans are on average one percentage point lower for these firms. This evidence suggests that (transferring) firms affected by branch closures are “better” than regular switchers in terms of unobservable characteristics.
Importantly, the branch closures examined were forced upon the banks in a very short time frame, and did not reflect banks’ long-term optimal business strategies. This unique setting allows us to shed light on theories that explain the well-documented switching discounts that firms obtain when borrowing from new banks.
Our results are entirely consistent with seminal theories of informational holdup by Sharpe (1990), Rajan (1992), von Thadden (2004), and Hauswald and Marquez (2006), among others, which we summarize in Appendix A: Informational Holdup Theory. As hypothesized by these models, private (repayment) information on firms collected by incumbent banks generates interest rate discounts for switchers. Bank branch closures devalue this locally stocked private information. Without such a private information advantage, switching discounts disappear for firms orphaned by a branch closure and compelled to swiftly transfer to another bank. For firms that subsequently—later in time or across geographical space—switch, discounts reappear.
An alternative explanation for the existence of switching discounts is related to the compensation for shoe leather switching costs à la Klemperer (1987). Firms may get a discount from banks to pay for switching costs (e.g., filling out paperwork, providing detailed information about themselves, and adjusting connection software). Following branch closure, banks would still need to compensate firms for these costs.
We address these potential explanations for the existence of switching costs with two tests. First, we adopt a strict within-firm matching strategy that allows us to compare transfer loans with other loans given to the same firm at the same time. Second, we run our specifications in a subset of regions with high levels of competition. Results remain qualitatively the same. Shoe leather costs are unlikely to drive results because they would be reflected in loan rates other banks offer the firm (the loans we match transfer loans to), and competitive pressure would force banks to give discounts to capture customers even after branch closures.
We then investigate and discard many alternative explanations for our findings. Branch closures may be associated with other phenomena besides the loss of private information. For instance, one can argue that branch closures cause selection at the firm level, given that branch closures are not exogenous. We tackle this question in two ways. First, we only look at branches that a subset of banks had to close because of restructuring agreements with the European Commission. To boost profitability and capital on a short horizon, banks were forced to close some branches even if they found them profitable. Results remain unchanged. Second, we predict the probability of branch closure using total credit amount outstanding, defaulted loans, and branch density in the region where the branch operates, and select only closed branches that were predicted to be the least likely to close. In this case too, we still obtain the same results as before.
Even when we are convinced about the exogeneity of branch closures, particular firms may select themselves into transferring following branch closures, and such firms could have different characteristics to those of regular switchers (firm selection). To address this question, we match transfer loans with other loans given to the same firm. We still observe no discount after branch closure, but we observe discounts before closure and for subsequent switching loans after closure. Even with within firm matching, one may argue that firms that switch before closure are different from firms that switch after closure. In our main specification, we further restrict the sample to include only firms that switch at least once after branch closure. We get similar results. Therefore, our results are not likely to be driven by unobserved differences between endogenous closures or firms.
Finally, selection at the bank level could also be driving results. Firms may switch to certain banks in normal times and to other banks following branch closures, as banks may specialize in different types of customers. To address this, in our main specifications, we match transfer loans with other loans given by the outside bank—that is, the bank firms transfer to. The results are still valid, showing that our findings cannot be driven by bank-specific differences with regard to how each attracts customers.
We pursue a number of other robustness tests—namely, using alternative matching methods, performing sample splits, and matching according to specific characteristics (e.g., population density, credit worthiness). We also measure the impact of branch closures on other loan conditions. Qualitatively, the results do not change.
Taken together, all our analyses provide support for the seminal theories of information holdup that explain the lack of discounts for transfer loans and the presence of discounts for switching loans. The unique setting in which branches in our study were closed allows for a clear understanding of the mechanisms that explain this specific finding, ruling out alternative explanations that have been proposed.
In addition, our article also contributes to the understanding of the consequences of bank branch closures on lending conditions. It has been documented that such closures are detrimental to access to loans for small businesses (Morgan, Pinkovskiy, and Yang, 2016; Nguyen, 2019; Duquerroy et al., 2020). We show that branch closures also affect loan pricing through the loss of information privately held by the branches that close. Furthermore, we observe that firms tend to move to new banks after closure, but do not find that affected areas have statistically different interest rates, levels of monitoring, or loan volumes. We do, however, observe that banks tend to prioritize informationally transparent firms following branch closures.
The rest of the article proceeds as follows. Section 2 describes the data. Section 3 presents variable definitions, descriptive statistics, and methodology. Section 4 presents our main findings and Section 5 provides an overview of the many robustness checks. Section 7 briefly discusses the other consequences of bank branch closures. Section 7 concludes.
2. Data
Our analysis merges records from four large and unique databases. First, we have access to all the data from the Portuguese public credit registry, the Central de Reponsabilidades de Crédito, which is managed by the BdP. The BdP requires all banks to report total loan exposures of non-financial companies (henceforth “firms”). Accessing this unique database—one of the most comprehensive in the world (Miller, 2003)—we have monthly corporate loans for all banks operating in Portugal between January 1987 and July 2015. This data allow us to retrieve loan monthly exposures for every firm–bank pair, including information on loan type and status (e.g., short or long term, in default, on or off-balance sheet exposure).
We also employ the Portuguese database of new credit operations, the Informação Individual de Taxas de Juro, which is also managed by the BdP. The BdP requires Portuguese banks to report the interest rate of new loans given to firms. From June 2012 to December 2014, banks with an annual volume of new loans to firms >€50 million had to report the interest rates of new loans and this obligation was extended to all banks in January 2015.4 For each loan, there is information about the date of origination, interest rate, maturity, interest rate fixation period, and loan amount.5 For each borrowing firm, we have information about their industry, postal code, and total bank debt.
We complement the detailed information on corporate bank loans with information on the balance sheet and income statements of all the firms in Portugal from the Informação Empresarial Simplificada. This dataset is a joint project of the Ministry of Justice, the Ministry of Finance, Statistics Portugal, and the BdP. All Portuguese firms are required to file information. We use a version of this dataset managed by the BdP, in which the information is treated to improve its statistical quality. We also use credit scores computed by the BdP.
Finally, the article relies on the list of bank branches maintained by the BdP, that is, the Registo Especial de Instituições (REI). For each branch, REI provides the opening day, closing day, and postal code. This database can be matched with loan data because banks are identified with the same codes in every dataset. We also geographically map the postal codes of bank branches and firms to calculate the physical distance between them.
Because the available information for banks in the credit register is limited to the previous 2 months, information asymmetries remain.6 For example, if a firm pays back an overdue loan, the record resets without any trace of overdue payments on the credit history (Campion, 2001).
Apart from the information shared through the registry and the information gathered through a relationship, banks have few other sources of information for their credit evaluations in Portugal. Most firms are micro or small firms and do not have audited financial statements. As a result, the capital markets are accessible only for a few large firms and the banking sector is the principal source of capital for most firms. Since credit derivatives are not widely available for small and medium firms, those seeking to adjust interest payments have to renegotiate or switch.
The analysis focuses on loans to private non-financial firms, in particular, on new loan initiations by all commercial banks between June 2012 and May 2015.7 We exclude overdrafts and current account credits to avoid distortions in the analysis of loan interest rates. Analyzing only new loans allows us to employ up-to-date and comparable firm and contract information at the precise time that firms “switch” or “transfer” to a new bank.
The vast majority of new loans are given to firms that have more than one relationship (86%). However, from all firms with some bank credit exposure in the beginning of the sample, only 36% have multiple relationships, suggesting that firms with multiple relationships get new loans much more often. The incidence of collateral is 38%, between the 24% reported by Ioannidou and Ongena (2010) and 53% reported by Berger and Udell (1995).8
There were 839 branch closures during the sample period. In the month preceding our analysis window, there were 5,971 branches in Portugal. About 82% of all branch closures are associated with six banks, which had 70% of all firm–bank relationships (in June 2012). In geographic terms, closures are concentrated in Lisbon and Porto. These two regions represent 25 and 18% of all bank relationships (in June 2012), and 27% and 19% of all closures, respectively.9
The significant net decrease in the number of branches occurred against a backdrop of pressures for cost-cutting measures. However, these pressures were not homogenously felt across all banks. Some of the largest banks in Portugal were recapitalized with funds from the bailout package agreed with the IMF, the ECB and the European Commission in 2011. In exchange for these funds, banks had to submit restructuring plans with the aim of improving profitability and solvency. Given that there was a widely shared concern about over-branching in Portugal, this included substantial reductions in both the number of branches and staff members as a prime cost-cutting measure.10 As a consequence these expedited branch closures were likely to be somewhat indiscriminate, that is, not always based on local branch quality of firms and their profitability, providing for an unencumbered set of quasi-natural experiments.
3. Definitions, Statistics, and Methodology
3.1 Definitions of Transfers and Switches
We take the operational definition of switching from Ioannidou and Ongena (2010). There are two conditions for a new loan to be classified as a switching loan. First, this new loan should be obtained from a bank with which the firm did not have a relationship during the previous 12 months. This bank is called the outside bank. Second, the firm must have had at least one relationship in the previous 12 months with at least one other bank. This bank is the inside bank. All new loans that do not observe these two conditions are non-switching loans. In effect, we conservatively assume that key inside information can get stale as quickly as within 1 year.11
Transfer loans are a subgroup we split off from the switching loans. In particular, we classify a switching loan as a transfer loan if the nearest branch of any of the inside banks of the firm was closed in any of the considered periods prior to the concession of the new loan by the outside bank (we consider 1–6 months after closure, 7–12 months after, and >12 months after as periods). Two additional conditions have to be observed in transfer loans. First, the physical distance between the firm and the closing branch must be <5 km (as the crow flies). Second, after the closure, the closest branch from this inside bank must be >5 km away from the firm.12 These conditions ensure that there is a strong locational driver for the firms to approach a branch of another bank. Figure 1 illustrates the definitions of non-switching, switching and transfer loans, while Figure 2 sketches the geographical set-up.13

Switching loans, transfers, inside banks, and outside banks. The figure above represents the relationships between Firm A and five different banks. Before t = 0 Firm A has a loan outstanding with Banks 1 and 2, the inside banks. At t = 0, Firm A establishes a relationship with Bank 3. Bank 3 is an outside bank because the firm did not have a relationship with Bank 3 in the previous 12 months. Loans i and ii are non-switching loans because these loans are granted by the inside banks. Loan iii is a switching loan because it is a new loan granted by an outside bank. Loan iv given by Bank 4 is a transfer loan because the loan is a switching loan and it was given after the branch of an inside bank (say Bank 1) was closed. Loan iv is also a first transfer loan. A subsequent switching loan v obtained by Firm A from yet another Bank 5 is called a later transfer loan.

Transfer loans given bank branch and firm location. The figure displays the branch of Bank 1 that is being closed and the location of the other bank branches. Transfer loans are switching loans granted in the period after the bank branch closes by a branch of another bank to firms that are located within 5 km of the closing branch (and that had a relationship with the bank of the closing branch) and that are located more than 5 km from another branch of the bank that closes its branch. Firms 1 and 2 get transfer loans from Bank 2 but Firm 3 does not, as there is another branch of Bank 1 ˂5 km away.
The 12-month window was chosen to match the definition of Ioannidou and Ongena (2010).14 In the same manner, we assume that lending relationships comprise all sorts of used and unused credit, including credit contracts in which the firm shares the responsibility of repayment with other institutions. Our definition of switching does also not differentiate between those firms that “move” between banks and those firms that “add” a bank relationship.15
Moreover, we do not retain firms that cease their relationship with the inside bank (i.e., firms that do not have any business dealings with this bank for >12 months), because this question is not relevant in the context of the informational holdup models that we are testing empirically.
3.2 Statistics
Table I provides descriptive statistics for transfer, non-switching, and switching loans. There are 1,129 loan transfers, representing 0.08% of the 1,338,829 non-switching loans and 5% of the 24,292 switching loans. The 24,292 switches in the sample represent 1.8% of all new loans in the period.16
Selected characteristics of transfer, non-switching, and switching loans
We report the mean, standard deviation, and median for selected loan and firm characteristics. The unit of observation in this table is the number (n) of loan initiations for transfer, non-switching, and switching loans. We assess the differences in means of transfer or switching loans versus the non-switching loans using the Student’s t-test. We assess the differences in medians using the Wilcoxon–Mann–Whitney test for continuous variables and the Pearson’s chi-square test for categorical variables. We assess the differences in standard deviations using Levene’s test. We indicate whether the differences between the corresponding mean and median values are significant at the 10, 5, and 1% levels using a, b, and c, respectively.
. | Transfer loans . | Non-switching loans . | Switching loans . | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
(n = 1,129) . | (n = 1,338,829) . | (n = 24,292) . | |||||||
Mean . | St. Dev. . | Median . | Mean . | St. Dev. . | Median . | Mean . | St. Dev. . | Median . | |
Interest rate (in bps) | 536c | 233c | 521c | 755 | 368 | 643 | 609c | 268c | 546c |
Risk indicator (100 = default) | 2.86c | 7.87c | 1.9c | 6.73 | 19.00 | 2.35 | 3.39c | 9.37c | 2.01c |
Defaulted firm (in %) | 0.53c | 7.27c | 0c | 3.37 | 18.00 | 0 | 0.663c | 8.11c | 0c |
Limited company (in %) | 74c | 43.9c | 100c | 67.60 | 46.80 | 100 | 80.3c | 39.8c | 100c |
Public LLC (in %) | 23.6c | 42.5c | 0c | 30.70 | 46.10 | 0 | 16.1c | 36.7c | 0c |
Collateralized loan (in %) | 59.9c | 49c | 100c | 37.90 | 48.50 | 0 | 66.1c | 47.3c | 100c |
Loan maturity (months) | 24.1c | 34.5c | 6.03c | 7.0 | 16.7 | 2.9 | 28.5c | 36c | 6.13c |
Loan amount (in EUR) | 107,924a | 393,434a | 25,000c | 57,347 | 960,996 | 9,000 | 102,721c | 596,717c | 25,000c |
Amount of bank debt (in EUR) | 1,051,500c | 2,281,304c | 312,336c | 3,266,369 | 12,000,435 | 597,851 | 848,602c | 3,563,670c | 89,486c |
Floating rate loan (in %) | 54.7c | 49.8c | 100c | 81.30 | 39.00 | 100 | 50.6c | 50c | 100c |
Multiple relationships (in %) | 86.40 | 34.3 | 100 | 86.80 | 33.90 | 100 | 61.8c | 48.6c | 100c |
Primary lender (in %) | 22.9c | 42.1c | 0c | 53.90 | 49.80 | 100 | 35.4c | 47.8c | 0c |
Relationship with multiple products (in %) | 21.2c | 40.9c | 0c | 84.30 | 36.40 | 100 | 18.5c | 38.8c | 0c |
. | Transfer loans . | Non-switching loans . | Switching loans . | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
(n = 1,129) . | (n = 1,338,829) . | (n = 24,292) . | |||||||
Mean . | St. Dev. . | Median . | Mean . | St. Dev. . | Median . | Mean . | St. Dev. . | Median . | |
Interest rate (in bps) | 536c | 233c | 521c | 755 | 368 | 643 | 609c | 268c | 546c |
Risk indicator (100 = default) | 2.86c | 7.87c | 1.9c | 6.73 | 19.00 | 2.35 | 3.39c | 9.37c | 2.01c |
Defaulted firm (in %) | 0.53c | 7.27c | 0c | 3.37 | 18.00 | 0 | 0.663c | 8.11c | 0c |
Limited company (in %) | 74c | 43.9c | 100c | 67.60 | 46.80 | 100 | 80.3c | 39.8c | 100c |
Public LLC (in %) | 23.6c | 42.5c | 0c | 30.70 | 46.10 | 0 | 16.1c | 36.7c | 0c |
Collateralized loan (in %) | 59.9c | 49c | 100c | 37.90 | 48.50 | 0 | 66.1c | 47.3c | 100c |
Loan maturity (months) | 24.1c | 34.5c | 6.03c | 7.0 | 16.7 | 2.9 | 28.5c | 36c | 6.13c |
Loan amount (in EUR) | 107,924a | 393,434a | 25,000c | 57,347 | 960,996 | 9,000 | 102,721c | 596,717c | 25,000c |
Amount of bank debt (in EUR) | 1,051,500c | 2,281,304c | 312,336c | 3,266,369 | 12,000,435 | 597,851 | 848,602c | 3,563,670c | 89,486c |
Floating rate loan (in %) | 54.7c | 49.8c | 100c | 81.30 | 39.00 | 100 | 50.6c | 50c | 100c |
Multiple relationships (in %) | 86.40 | 34.3 | 100 | 86.80 | 33.90 | 100 | 61.8c | 48.6c | 100c |
Primary lender (in %) | 22.9c | 42.1c | 0c | 53.90 | 49.80 | 100 | 35.4c | 47.8c | 0c |
Relationship with multiple products (in %) | 21.2c | 40.9c | 0c | 84.30 | 36.40 | 100 | 18.5c | 38.8c | 0c |
Selected characteristics of transfer, non-switching, and switching loans
We report the mean, standard deviation, and median for selected loan and firm characteristics. The unit of observation in this table is the number (n) of loan initiations for transfer, non-switching, and switching loans. We assess the differences in means of transfer or switching loans versus the non-switching loans using the Student’s t-test. We assess the differences in medians using the Wilcoxon–Mann–Whitney test for continuous variables and the Pearson’s chi-square test for categorical variables. We assess the differences in standard deviations using Levene’s test. We indicate whether the differences between the corresponding mean and median values are significant at the 10, 5, and 1% levels using a, b, and c, respectively.
. | Transfer loans . | Non-switching loans . | Switching loans . | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
(n = 1,129) . | (n = 1,338,829) . | (n = 24,292) . | |||||||
Mean . | St. Dev. . | Median . | Mean . | St. Dev. . | Median . | Mean . | St. Dev. . | Median . | |
Interest rate (in bps) | 536c | 233c | 521c | 755 | 368 | 643 | 609c | 268c | 546c |
Risk indicator (100 = default) | 2.86c | 7.87c | 1.9c | 6.73 | 19.00 | 2.35 | 3.39c | 9.37c | 2.01c |
Defaulted firm (in %) | 0.53c | 7.27c | 0c | 3.37 | 18.00 | 0 | 0.663c | 8.11c | 0c |
Limited company (in %) | 74c | 43.9c | 100c | 67.60 | 46.80 | 100 | 80.3c | 39.8c | 100c |
Public LLC (in %) | 23.6c | 42.5c | 0c | 30.70 | 46.10 | 0 | 16.1c | 36.7c | 0c |
Collateralized loan (in %) | 59.9c | 49c | 100c | 37.90 | 48.50 | 0 | 66.1c | 47.3c | 100c |
Loan maturity (months) | 24.1c | 34.5c | 6.03c | 7.0 | 16.7 | 2.9 | 28.5c | 36c | 6.13c |
Loan amount (in EUR) | 107,924a | 393,434a | 25,000c | 57,347 | 960,996 | 9,000 | 102,721c | 596,717c | 25,000c |
Amount of bank debt (in EUR) | 1,051,500c | 2,281,304c | 312,336c | 3,266,369 | 12,000,435 | 597,851 | 848,602c | 3,563,670c | 89,486c |
Floating rate loan (in %) | 54.7c | 49.8c | 100c | 81.30 | 39.00 | 100 | 50.6c | 50c | 100c |
Multiple relationships (in %) | 86.40 | 34.3 | 100 | 86.80 | 33.90 | 100 | 61.8c | 48.6c | 100c |
Primary lender (in %) | 22.9c | 42.1c | 0c | 53.90 | 49.80 | 100 | 35.4c | 47.8c | 0c |
Relationship with multiple products (in %) | 21.2c | 40.9c | 0c | 84.30 | 36.40 | 100 | 18.5c | 38.8c | 0c |
. | Transfer loans . | Non-switching loans . | Switching loans . | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
(n = 1,129) . | (n = 1,338,829) . | (n = 24,292) . | |||||||
Mean . | St. Dev. . | Median . | Mean . | St. Dev. . | Median . | Mean . | St. Dev. . | Median . | |
Interest rate (in bps) | 536c | 233c | 521c | 755 | 368 | 643 | 609c | 268c | 546c |
Risk indicator (100 = default) | 2.86c | 7.87c | 1.9c | 6.73 | 19.00 | 2.35 | 3.39c | 9.37c | 2.01c |
Defaulted firm (in %) | 0.53c | 7.27c | 0c | 3.37 | 18.00 | 0 | 0.663c | 8.11c | 0c |
Limited company (in %) | 74c | 43.9c | 100c | 67.60 | 46.80 | 100 | 80.3c | 39.8c | 100c |
Public LLC (in %) | 23.6c | 42.5c | 0c | 30.70 | 46.10 | 0 | 16.1c | 36.7c | 0c |
Collateralized loan (in %) | 59.9c | 49c | 100c | 37.90 | 48.50 | 0 | 66.1c | 47.3c | 100c |
Loan maturity (months) | 24.1c | 34.5c | 6.03c | 7.0 | 16.7 | 2.9 | 28.5c | 36c | 6.13c |
Loan amount (in EUR) | 107,924a | 393,434a | 25,000c | 57,347 | 960,996 | 9,000 | 102,721c | 596,717c | 25,000c |
Amount of bank debt (in EUR) | 1,051,500c | 2,281,304c | 312,336c | 3,266,369 | 12,000,435 | 597,851 | 848,602c | 3,563,670c | 89,486c |
Floating rate loan (in %) | 54.7c | 49.8c | 100c | 81.30 | 39.00 | 100 | 50.6c | 50c | 100c |
Multiple relationships (in %) | 86.40 | 34.3 | 100 | 86.80 | 33.90 | 100 | 61.8c | 48.6c | 100c |
Primary lender (in %) | 22.9c | 42.1c | 0c | 53.90 | 49.80 | 100 | 35.4c | 47.8c | 0c |
Relationship with multiple products (in %) | 21.2c | 40.9c | 0c | 84.30 | 36.40 | 100 | 18.5c | 38.8c | 0c |
The average interest rate for loan transfers is 5.36%, 219 bps less than for non-switching loans and 73 bps less than for switching loans. The standard deviation is almost half the standard deviation of non-switching loans, and it is also smaller than the standard deviation of other switching loans at standard significance levels. This smaller standard deviation is consistent with pool-pricing. Given the variation across region and time in banking market conditions, and given firm characteristics that are observable to all banks, even pool-pricing will in practice not entail a similar loan rate for all firms.
Other loan characteristics seem to be similar to the ones verified for switching loans, namely the percentage of defaulted loans, collateralization, maturity, loan amount, share of floating rate loans, and of multiple relationships, the likelihood that the outside bank is the primary lender and the likelihood of multiple products in the bank relationship.
For switching loans, loan rates are on average 146 bps lower, not accounting for differences in other loan and firm characteristics, than for non-switching loans. The default rate on the pool of switching firms is 0.7%, well ˂3.4% verified for non-switching firms. This can be explained by the fact that banks can observe in the credit register whether the firm has overdue loans. It might also be consistent with evergreening practices, empirically documented by Peek and Rosengren (2005), as inside banks are clearly more likely to grant a loan to a firm in distress than outside banks.
Table II provides descriptive statistics for first and later transfers loans. In other words, we distinguish the first loan obtained with an outside bank after the branch of the inside bank closes from all the new loans obtained with outside banks subsequently. First and later transfer loans do not differ in terms of risk. In all the other dimensions analyzed, there are significant differences. First transfers have higher interest rates and are more likely to be collateralized than later transfers. At the same time, they have longer maturities and involve larger amounts.
Selected characteristics of first and later transfer loans
We report the mean, standard deviation, and median for selected loan and firm characteristics. The unit of observation in this table is the number (n) of loan initiations. Transfers are divided in first transfers (first switching loans after branch closure) and later transfers. We assess the differences in means using the Student’s t-test. We assess the differences in medians using the Wilcoxon–Mann–Whitney test for continuous variables and the Pearson’s Chi-square test for categorical variables. We assess the differences in standard deviations using Levene’s test. We indicate whether the differences between the corresponding mean and median values are significant at the 10, 5, and 1% levels using a, b, and c, respectively.
. | First transfer loans . | Later transfer loans . | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
(n = 870) . | (n = 259) . | |||||
Mean . | St. Dev. . | Median . | Mean . | St. Dev. . | Median . | |
Interest rate (in bps) | 548c | 242b | 526c | 496 | 198 | 496 |
Risk indicator (100 = default) | 3.02 | 8.27 | 1.95 | 2.38 | 6.47 | 1.73 |
Defaulted firm (%) | 0.57 | 7.56 | 0 | 0.39 | 6.21 | 0 |
Limited company (%) | 76.90c | 42.17c | 1c | 64.48 | 47.95 | 1 |
Public LLC (%) | 20.69c | 40.53c | 0c | 33.59 | 47.32 | 0 |
Collateralized loan (%) | 65.17c | 47.67c | 1c | 42.08 | 49.47 | 0 |
Loan maturity (months) | 27.10c | 36.02c | 6.13c | 14.19 | 26.80 | 3.2 |
Loan amount (in EUR) | 125,083c | 443,028c | 25,000c | 50.287 | 106,475 | 14,410 |
Amount of bank debt (in EUR) | 935,381c | 2,459,220 | 206,073c | 1,441,552 | 1,478,350 | 932,026 |
Floating rate loan (%) | 49.89c | 50.03c | 0c | 71.04 | 45.44 | 1 |
Multiple relationships (%) | 82.99c | 37.59c | 1c | 97.68 | 15.07 | 1 |
Primary lender (%) | 25.52c | 43.62c | 0c | 14.29 | 35.06 | 0 |
Relationship with multiple products (%) | 18.97c | 39.23c | 0c | 28.57 | 45.26 | 0 |
. | First transfer loans . | Later transfer loans . | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
(n = 870) . | (n = 259) . | |||||
Mean . | St. Dev. . | Median . | Mean . | St. Dev. . | Median . | |
Interest rate (in bps) | 548c | 242b | 526c | 496 | 198 | 496 |
Risk indicator (100 = default) | 3.02 | 8.27 | 1.95 | 2.38 | 6.47 | 1.73 |
Defaulted firm (%) | 0.57 | 7.56 | 0 | 0.39 | 6.21 | 0 |
Limited company (%) | 76.90c | 42.17c | 1c | 64.48 | 47.95 | 1 |
Public LLC (%) | 20.69c | 40.53c | 0c | 33.59 | 47.32 | 0 |
Collateralized loan (%) | 65.17c | 47.67c | 1c | 42.08 | 49.47 | 0 |
Loan maturity (months) | 27.10c | 36.02c | 6.13c | 14.19 | 26.80 | 3.2 |
Loan amount (in EUR) | 125,083c | 443,028c | 25,000c | 50.287 | 106,475 | 14,410 |
Amount of bank debt (in EUR) | 935,381c | 2,459,220 | 206,073c | 1,441,552 | 1,478,350 | 932,026 |
Floating rate loan (%) | 49.89c | 50.03c | 0c | 71.04 | 45.44 | 1 |
Multiple relationships (%) | 82.99c | 37.59c | 1c | 97.68 | 15.07 | 1 |
Primary lender (%) | 25.52c | 43.62c | 0c | 14.29 | 35.06 | 0 |
Relationship with multiple products (%) | 18.97c | 39.23c | 0c | 28.57 | 45.26 | 0 |
Selected characteristics of first and later transfer loans
We report the mean, standard deviation, and median for selected loan and firm characteristics. The unit of observation in this table is the number (n) of loan initiations. Transfers are divided in first transfers (first switching loans after branch closure) and later transfers. We assess the differences in means using the Student’s t-test. We assess the differences in medians using the Wilcoxon–Mann–Whitney test for continuous variables and the Pearson’s Chi-square test for categorical variables. We assess the differences in standard deviations using Levene’s test. We indicate whether the differences between the corresponding mean and median values are significant at the 10, 5, and 1% levels using a, b, and c, respectively.
. | First transfer loans . | Later transfer loans . | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
(n = 870) . | (n = 259) . | |||||
Mean . | St. Dev. . | Median . | Mean . | St. Dev. . | Median . | |
Interest rate (in bps) | 548c | 242b | 526c | 496 | 198 | 496 |
Risk indicator (100 = default) | 3.02 | 8.27 | 1.95 | 2.38 | 6.47 | 1.73 |
Defaulted firm (%) | 0.57 | 7.56 | 0 | 0.39 | 6.21 | 0 |
Limited company (%) | 76.90c | 42.17c | 1c | 64.48 | 47.95 | 1 |
Public LLC (%) | 20.69c | 40.53c | 0c | 33.59 | 47.32 | 0 |
Collateralized loan (%) | 65.17c | 47.67c | 1c | 42.08 | 49.47 | 0 |
Loan maturity (months) | 27.10c | 36.02c | 6.13c | 14.19 | 26.80 | 3.2 |
Loan amount (in EUR) | 125,083c | 443,028c | 25,000c | 50.287 | 106,475 | 14,410 |
Amount of bank debt (in EUR) | 935,381c | 2,459,220 | 206,073c | 1,441,552 | 1,478,350 | 932,026 |
Floating rate loan (%) | 49.89c | 50.03c | 0c | 71.04 | 45.44 | 1 |
Multiple relationships (%) | 82.99c | 37.59c | 1c | 97.68 | 15.07 | 1 |
Primary lender (%) | 25.52c | 43.62c | 0c | 14.29 | 35.06 | 0 |
Relationship with multiple products (%) | 18.97c | 39.23c | 0c | 28.57 | 45.26 | 0 |
. | First transfer loans . | Later transfer loans . | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
(n = 870) . | (n = 259) . | |||||
Mean . | St. Dev. . | Median . | Mean . | St. Dev. . | Median . | |
Interest rate (in bps) | 548c | 242b | 526c | 496 | 198 | 496 |
Risk indicator (100 = default) | 3.02 | 8.27 | 1.95 | 2.38 | 6.47 | 1.73 |
Defaulted firm (%) | 0.57 | 7.56 | 0 | 0.39 | 6.21 | 0 |
Limited company (%) | 76.90c | 42.17c | 1c | 64.48 | 47.95 | 1 |
Public LLC (%) | 20.69c | 40.53c | 0c | 33.59 | 47.32 | 0 |
Collateralized loan (%) | 65.17c | 47.67c | 1c | 42.08 | 49.47 | 0 |
Loan maturity (months) | 27.10c | 36.02c | 6.13c | 14.19 | 26.80 | 3.2 |
Loan amount (in EUR) | 125,083c | 443,028c | 25,000c | 50.287 | 106,475 | 14,410 |
Amount of bank debt (in EUR) | 935,381c | 2,459,220 | 206,073c | 1,441,552 | 1,478,350 | 932,026 |
Floating rate loan (%) | 49.89c | 50.03c | 0c | 71.04 | 45.44 | 1 |
Multiple relationships (%) | 82.99c | 37.59c | 1c | 97.68 | 15.07 | 1 |
Primary lender (%) | 25.52c | 43.62c | 0c | 14.29 | 35.06 | 0 |
Relationship with multiple products (%) | 18.97c | 39.23c | 0c | 28.57 | 45.26 | 0 |
Transfers are distributed among different industries and regions (see Supplementary Appendix: Statistics). Therefore, a straight comparison of simple averages is inadequate to draw any conclusions (and we will consequently rely on various matching methods to align transfer and switching loans with non-switching loans to arrive at all-around comparable spreads).
Figure 3 shows the distribution of firms that transfer or switch banks according to the residual maturity of their loans with the inside bank at the time of switching. When firms have more than one loan with the inside bank, we use as reference the shortest residual maturity.

Residual maturity of relationships with the inside bank. The figure displays the distribution of firms that switch banks according to the residual maturity of their inside bank loans. When firms have more than one loan with the inside bank(s) we use the shortest residual maturity.
Arguably, firms should more actively consider transferring or switching to a new bank when they have loans to refinance. We observe that for loan transfers 67% of firms have loans with residual maturity ˂90 days, while for switches only ∼52% of firms have loans with residual maturity ˂90 days. In both cases, there is a high concentration of firms that transfer or switch from one bank to the other when they have loans to refinance in the short run. This concentration is significantly higher for firms that are confronted with a branch closure. These firms are thus under pressure to find a new lender to refinance their maturing loans, possibly forcing them to accept the pool price that firms normally contract when they get a new loan.
3.3 Coarsened Exact Matching Methodology
The ideal setting to compare transfer and switching loans (to non-switching loans) would be to know the interest rate offered to the firm for a non-switching loan. However, we do not have this information for many loans, so we use a matching model to derive it (we return to using non-switching loans granted to the same firm in robustness).17
We first examine whether the loan rate that the transfer or switching loan receives from the outside bank is lower than the rate its inside bank offered. Since the inside bank’s unsuccessful offer is unobservable, we approximate it using similar loans that the inside bank granted in the same month to other comparable firms (Figure 4). Recognizing the possible impact of bank characteristics on the inside and outside offers, in a similar matching exercise we also compare the rates on the transfer and switching loans to the rates of similar loans that the transferee or switcher’s outside bank granted in the same month to other comparable existing customers (Figure 5).18

Switching versus non-switching loans at the switcher’s inside bank. The figure displays the analysis in Table IV (Columns I and II), where we compare the loan rate of the switching loan with comparable non-switching new loans from the switcher’s inside banks at the time of the switch, as in Ioannidou and Ongena (2010). The loan granted by Bank 3 to Firm A is the switching loan; all other loans are non-switching loans.

Switching versus non-switching loans at the switcher’s outside bank. The figure displays the analysis in Table IV (Column III) and subsequent tables, where we compare the rate of the switching loan with the rate of comparable non-switching loans that the switcher’s outside bank originates at the time of the switch, as in Ioannidou and Ongena (2010). The loan granted by Bank 3 to Firm A is the switching loan; all other loans are non-switching loans.
Table III contains the list of variables we use to establish the matching model. We employ coarsened exact matching because we rely on many categorical variables. In this way, the quality of the match is guaranteed (e.g., Stuart, 2010). For comparability purposes, we use 30% intervals for the continuous variables; these intervals are set a priori and equally for all continuous variables (hence we do not use distributional information on individual variables to further optimize the quality of the match; results are virtually unaffected by this choice). We employ four different matching strategies and revisit the choice of matching variables and matching methodology (i.e., we also employ a propensity score matching) in robustness.
Matching variables
We report the number of possible values (#) and a range (or list) of values for the matching variables.
Category . | Matching variables . | # . | Possible values . |
---|---|---|---|
Macro | Quarter | 13 | 2012–2015q2 |
Bank | Inside bank | 2 | =1 if the firm had a lending relationship with the bank in the last 12 months, and =0 otherwise |
Bank | Outside bank | 2 | =1 if the firm did not have a lending relationship with the bank in the last 12 months, and =0 otherwise |
Bank | Foreign bank | 2 | =1 if bank is part of an international banking group, and =0 otherwise |
Bank | Branch density | 0 - … | Number of branches per 1,000 adults |
Firm | Firm | 94,281 | =1 per firm identity, and =0 otherwise |
Firm | Credit rating | 6 | =1 if 1st (lowest) risk quartile, =2 if 2nd risk quartile, =3 if third risk quartile, =4 if 4th risk quartile, =5 if defaulting firm, =6 if firm without credit rating |
Firm | Region | 20 | Aveiro, Beja, Braga, Bragança, Castelo Branco, Coimbra, Faro, Funchal, Guarda, Leiria, Lisboa, Ponta Delgada, Portalegre, Porto, Santarém, Setúbal, Viana do Castelo, Vila Real, Viseu, and Évora |
Firm | Industry | 13 | Agriculture, forestry and fishing, mining and quarrying, manufacturing, utilities, construction, wholesale retail and trade, transporting and storage, accommodation and food service activities, information and communication, real estate, finance and insurance, professional/scientific/technical activities, and other services |
Firm | Legal structure | 3 | Sociedade por Quotas, Sociedade Anónima, and other legal structure |
Firm | Multiple bank relationships | 2 | =1 if firm has multiple bank relationships |
Firm | Locality | 308 | County where firm is registered |
Firm | Size | 4 | =1 for micro firms =2 for small firms, =3 for medium-sized firms, =4 for large firms |
Loan | Collateral | 2 | =1 if loan is collateralized, and =0 otherwise. |
Loan | Loan maturity | 2 | =1 if the matched loans have similar maturity (using a (−30%, +30%) window), and =0 otherwise |
Loan | Loan amount | 2 | =1 if the matched loans have similar amount (using a (−30%, +30%) window), and =0 otherwise |
Loan | Floating loan rate | 2 | =1 if the interest rate on the loan varies >50% of the time, and =0 otherwise |
Category . | Matching variables . | # . | Possible values . |
---|---|---|---|
Macro | Quarter | 13 | 2012–2015q2 |
Bank | Inside bank | 2 | =1 if the firm had a lending relationship with the bank in the last 12 months, and =0 otherwise |
Bank | Outside bank | 2 | =1 if the firm did not have a lending relationship with the bank in the last 12 months, and =0 otherwise |
Bank | Foreign bank | 2 | =1 if bank is part of an international banking group, and =0 otherwise |
Bank | Branch density | 0 - … | Number of branches per 1,000 adults |
Firm | Firm | 94,281 | =1 per firm identity, and =0 otherwise |
Firm | Credit rating | 6 | =1 if 1st (lowest) risk quartile, =2 if 2nd risk quartile, =3 if third risk quartile, =4 if 4th risk quartile, =5 if defaulting firm, =6 if firm without credit rating |
Firm | Region | 20 | Aveiro, Beja, Braga, Bragança, Castelo Branco, Coimbra, Faro, Funchal, Guarda, Leiria, Lisboa, Ponta Delgada, Portalegre, Porto, Santarém, Setúbal, Viana do Castelo, Vila Real, Viseu, and Évora |
Firm | Industry | 13 | Agriculture, forestry and fishing, mining and quarrying, manufacturing, utilities, construction, wholesale retail and trade, transporting and storage, accommodation and food service activities, information and communication, real estate, finance and insurance, professional/scientific/technical activities, and other services |
Firm | Legal structure | 3 | Sociedade por Quotas, Sociedade Anónima, and other legal structure |
Firm | Multiple bank relationships | 2 | =1 if firm has multiple bank relationships |
Firm | Locality | 308 | County where firm is registered |
Firm | Size | 4 | =1 for micro firms =2 for small firms, =3 for medium-sized firms, =4 for large firms |
Loan | Collateral | 2 | =1 if loan is collateralized, and =0 otherwise. |
Loan | Loan maturity | 2 | =1 if the matched loans have similar maturity (using a (−30%, +30%) window), and =0 otherwise |
Loan | Loan amount | 2 | =1 if the matched loans have similar amount (using a (−30%, +30%) window), and =0 otherwise |
Loan | Floating loan rate | 2 | =1 if the interest rate on the loan varies >50% of the time, and =0 otherwise |
Matching variables
We report the number of possible values (#) and a range (or list) of values for the matching variables.
Category . | Matching variables . | # . | Possible values . |
---|---|---|---|
Macro | Quarter | 13 | 2012–2015q2 |
Bank | Inside bank | 2 | =1 if the firm had a lending relationship with the bank in the last 12 months, and =0 otherwise |
Bank | Outside bank | 2 | =1 if the firm did not have a lending relationship with the bank in the last 12 months, and =0 otherwise |
Bank | Foreign bank | 2 | =1 if bank is part of an international banking group, and =0 otherwise |
Bank | Branch density | 0 - … | Number of branches per 1,000 adults |
Firm | Firm | 94,281 | =1 per firm identity, and =0 otherwise |
Firm | Credit rating | 6 | =1 if 1st (lowest) risk quartile, =2 if 2nd risk quartile, =3 if third risk quartile, =4 if 4th risk quartile, =5 if defaulting firm, =6 if firm without credit rating |
Firm | Region | 20 | Aveiro, Beja, Braga, Bragança, Castelo Branco, Coimbra, Faro, Funchal, Guarda, Leiria, Lisboa, Ponta Delgada, Portalegre, Porto, Santarém, Setúbal, Viana do Castelo, Vila Real, Viseu, and Évora |
Firm | Industry | 13 | Agriculture, forestry and fishing, mining and quarrying, manufacturing, utilities, construction, wholesale retail and trade, transporting and storage, accommodation and food service activities, information and communication, real estate, finance and insurance, professional/scientific/technical activities, and other services |
Firm | Legal structure | 3 | Sociedade por Quotas, Sociedade Anónima, and other legal structure |
Firm | Multiple bank relationships | 2 | =1 if firm has multiple bank relationships |
Firm | Locality | 308 | County where firm is registered |
Firm | Size | 4 | =1 for micro firms =2 for small firms, =3 for medium-sized firms, =4 for large firms |
Loan | Collateral | 2 | =1 if loan is collateralized, and =0 otherwise. |
Loan | Loan maturity | 2 | =1 if the matched loans have similar maturity (using a (−30%, +30%) window), and =0 otherwise |
Loan | Loan amount | 2 | =1 if the matched loans have similar amount (using a (−30%, +30%) window), and =0 otherwise |
Loan | Floating loan rate | 2 | =1 if the interest rate on the loan varies >50% of the time, and =0 otherwise |
Category . | Matching variables . | # . | Possible values . |
---|---|---|---|
Macro | Quarter | 13 | 2012–2015q2 |
Bank | Inside bank | 2 | =1 if the firm had a lending relationship with the bank in the last 12 months, and =0 otherwise |
Bank | Outside bank | 2 | =1 if the firm did not have a lending relationship with the bank in the last 12 months, and =0 otherwise |
Bank | Foreign bank | 2 | =1 if bank is part of an international banking group, and =0 otherwise |
Bank | Branch density | 0 - … | Number of branches per 1,000 adults |
Firm | Firm | 94,281 | =1 per firm identity, and =0 otherwise |
Firm | Credit rating | 6 | =1 if 1st (lowest) risk quartile, =2 if 2nd risk quartile, =3 if third risk quartile, =4 if 4th risk quartile, =5 if defaulting firm, =6 if firm without credit rating |
Firm | Region | 20 | Aveiro, Beja, Braga, Bragança, Castelo Branco, Coimbra, Faro, Funchal, Guarda, Leiria, Lisboa, Ponta Delgada, Portalegre, Porto, Santarém, Setúbal, Viana do Castelo, Vila Real, Viseu, and Évora |
Firm | Industry | 13 | Agriculture, forestry and fishing, mining and quarrying, manufacturing, utilities, construction, wholesale retail and trade, transporting and storage, accommodation and food service activities, information and communication, real estate, finance and insurance, professional/scientific/technical activities, and other services |
Firm | Legal structure | 3 | Sociedade por Quotas, Sociedade Anónima, and other legal structure |
Firm | Multiple bank relationships | 2 | =1 if firm has multiple bank relationships |
Firm | Locality | 308 | County where firm is registered |
Firm | Size | 4 | =1 for micro firms =2 for small firms, =3 for medium-sized firms, =4 for large firms |
Loan | Collateral | 2 | =1 if loan is collateralized, and =0 otherwise. |
Loan | Loan maturity | 2 | =1 if the matched loans have similar maturity (using a (−30%, +30%) window), and =0 otherwise |
Loan | Loan amount | 2 | =1 if the matched loans have similar amount (using a (−30%, +30%) window), and =0 otherwise |
Loan | Floating loan rate | 2 | =1 if the interest rate on the loan varies >50% of the time, and =0 otherwise |
We match loans on the quarter they were given, on firm characteristics (credit rating,19 region, and industry) and on loan characteristics (existence of collateral, maturity, loan amount, and floating loan rate). We feature the year: quarter in which the loan is granted to make sure loans granted under similar macro-economic conditions; credit rating, region, industry, and legal structure make firms comparable in these vital dimensions; in one matching strategy firm characteristics are supplanted by firm identity; and finally, at the loan level collateral, maturity, amount, and floating rate make loans comparable in their key loan terms.20 We also match either with other loans from the firm’s inside banks or with loans from the firm’s outside bank. For inside banks, we also match on the affiliation with an international banking group.
The impact of unobserved loan characteristics will be reflected in interest rate heterogeneity within the same matching group. Unobserved borrower heterogeneity works against finding evidence consistent with a lower interest rate granted to switchers. In von Thadden (2004), unobservably bad borrowers are more likely to switch.21 Hence, if our matching variables do not adequately capture borrower quality, then bad switchers are more likely to be paired with good (instead of bad) non-switchers, resulting in smaller estimated cuts (see simulations of the von Thadden, 2004 model in Ioannidou and Ongena, 2010).
We match all transfer or switching loans with non-switching loans that have the same characteristics and calculate the spread between the interest rates of these loans. We regress the spread on a constant and weigh each observation to the inverse of the number of matches for each transfer or switching loan i. For instance, if transfer i has six matches, each match will have a weight of 1/6 in the regression.
4. Main Results
In the previous section, we document that both transfers and switches occur. In this section, we analyze interest rates for transfers and switches, and investigate whether loan rates after transferring and switching present distinct patterns. We also assess the differential quality of transfer and switching loans. In the next section, we run many robustness tests and compare other loans conditions, namely the rate of collateralization, maturities, and loan amounts.
4.1 Interest Rate Differential for Transfer versus Switching Loans
We now turn to our main investigation. Table IV compares the interest rate of switching or transfer loans with non-switching loans before and after the closest branch of the inside bank that was servicing the firm was closed. Recall that all loans that borrowers receive after the branch is closed are classified as transfer loans. The table contains the list of matching variables used to compare the interest rate, the number of switching, transfer, and non-switching loans, the total number of observations used in each specification, and the average interest rate differential between switching or transfer and non-switching loans. Standard errors are reported in parentheses and are clustered at firm level.22
Spreads between interest rates on switching or transfer loans and matched non-switching loans when the closest branch of the inside bank closes
We assess the spread between the interest rate on switching or transfer loans and the interest rate on new non-switching loans obtained from the switchers’ inside bank (Columns I, II, and IV) and outside bank (Column III) when the closest branch of the inside bank closes. In Columns I–III, we consider other non-switching loans given to other firms. In Column IV we consider non-switching loans given to the same firm. All variables are defined in Table III. We regress the spreads on a constant and report the coefficient on the constant. We weigh each observation by one over the total number of comparable non-switching loans per switching or transfer loan. We cluster at the switching-firm level and report robust standard errors between parentheses. We report standard errors in the parentheses. a, b, and c indicate significance at the 10, 5, and 1% levels, two-tailed.
. | Main matching strategies . | Robustness . | |||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
I . | II . | III . | IV . | V . | |
Matching variables | Benchmark | Loose matching | |||
Quarter | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Inside bank | Yes | Yes | – | – | |
Outside bank | – | – | Yes | – | Yes |
Foreign bank | – | Yes | – | – | – |
Firm | – | – | – | Yes | – |
Credit rating | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | – |
Region | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | – |
Industry | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | – |
Legal structure | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | – |
Collateral | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | – |
Loan maturity | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Loan amount | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Floating loan rate | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | |
Number of switching or transfer loans | 621 | 439 | 612 | 191 | 1,768 |
Number of non-switching loans | 4,232 | 2,469 | 2,497 | 312 | 362,387 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 6,249 | 3,735 | 3,261 | 657 | 515,327 |
Rate difference | |||||
Before branch closure (Switching) | −90.21c | −90.51c | −62.81c | −212.53c | −52.12c |
(18.48) | (22.60) | (23.66) | (73.70) | (19.13) | |
1–6 months after closure (Transfer) | −19.26 | 17.02 | 15.62 | −62.24 | −26.47 |
(41.24) | (47.33) | (29.55) | (52.18) | (20.39) |
. | Main matching strategies . | Robustness . | |||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
I . | II . | III . | IV . | V . | |
Matching variables | Benchmark | Loose matching | |||
Quarter | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Inside bank | Yes | Yes | – | – | |
Outside bank | – | – | Yes | – | Yes |
Foreign bank | – | Yes | – | – | – |
Firm | – | – | – | Yes | – |
Credit rating | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | – |
Region | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | – |
Industry | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | – |
Legal structure | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | – |
Collateral | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | – |
Loan maturity | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Loan amount | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Floating loan rate | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | |
Number of switching or transfer loans | 621 | 439 | 612 | 191 | 1,768 |
Number of non-switching loans | 4,232 | 2,469 | 2,497 | 312 | 362,387 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 6,249 | 3,735 | 3,261 | 657 | 515,327 |
Rate difference | |||||
Before branch closure (Switching) | −90.21c | −90.51c | −62.81c | −212.53c | −52.12c |
(18.48) | (22.60) | (23.66) | (73.70) | (19.13) | |
1–6 months after closure (Transfer) | −19.26 | 17.02 | 15.62 | −62.24 | −26.47 |
(41.24) | (47.33) | (29.55) | (52.18) | (20.39) |
Spreads between interest rates on switching or transfer loans and matched non-switching loans when the closest branch of the inside bank closes
We assess the spread between the interest rate on switching or transfer loans and the interest rate on new non-switching loans obtained from the switchers’ inside bank (Columns I, II, and IV) and outside bank (Column III) when the closest branch of the inside bank closes. In Columns I–III, we consider other non-switching loans given to other firms. In Column IV we consider non-switching loans given to the same firm. All variables are defined in Table III. We regress the spreads on a constant and report the coefficient on the constant. We weigh each observation by one over the total number of comparable non-switching loans per switching or transfer loan. We cluster at the switching-firm level and report robust standard errors between parentheses. We report standard errors in the parentheses. a, b, and c indicate significance at the 10, 5, and 1% levels, two-tailed.
. | Main matching strategies . | Robustness . | |||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
I . | II . | III . | IV . | V . | |
Matching variables | Benchmark | Loose matching | |||
Quarter | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Inside bank | Yes | Yes | – | – | |
Outside bank | – | – | Yes | – | Yes |
Foreign bank | – | Yes | – | – | – |
Firm | – | – | – | Yes | – |
Credit rating | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | – |
Region | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | – |
Industry | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | – |
Legal structure | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | – |
Collateral | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | – |
Loan maturity | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Loan amount | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Floating loan rate | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | |
Number of switching or transfer loans | 621 | 439 | 612 | 191 | 1,768 |
Number of non-switching loans | 4,232 | 2,469 | 2,497 | 312 | 362,387 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 6,249 | 3,735 | 3,261 | 657 | 515,327 |
Rate difference | |||||
Before branch closure (Switching) | −90.21c | −90.51c | −62.81c | −212.53c | −52.12c |
(18.48) | (22.60) | (23.66) | (73.70) | (19.13) | |
1–6 months after closure (Transfer) | −19.26 | 17.02 | 15.62 | −62.24 | −26.47 |
(41.24) | (47.33) | (29.55) | (52.18) | (20.39) |
. | Main matching strategies . | Robustness . | |||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
I . | II . | III . | IV . | V . | |
Matching variables | Benchmark | Loose matching | |||
Quarter | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Inside bank | Yes | Yes | – | – | |
Outside bank | – | – | Yes | – | Yes |
Foreign bank | – | Yes | – | – | – |
Firm | – | – | – | Yes | – |
Credit rating | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | – |
Region | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | – |
Industry | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | – |
Legal structure | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | – |
Collateral | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | – |
Loan maturity | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Loan amount | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Floating loan rate | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | |
Number of switching or transfer loans | 621 | 439 | 612 | 191 | 1,768 |
Number of non-switching loans | 4,232 | 2,469 | 2,497 | 312 | 362,387 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 6,249 | 3,735 | 3,261 | 657 | 515,327 |
Rate difference | |||||
Before branch closure (Switching) | −90.21c | −90.51c | −62.81c | −212.53c | −52.12c |
(18.48) | (22.60) | (23.66) | (73.70) | (19.13) | |
1–6 months after closure (Transfer) | −19.26 | 17.02 | 15.62 | −62.24 | −26.47 |
(41.24) | (47.33) | (29.55) | (52.18) | (20.39) |
We pursue four matching strategies. In Column I, we compare the interest rate of switching and transfer loans with the interest rate of non-switching loans made by firms’ inside banks, conditional on the specified matching variables.
For Regression 1, we retain 621 switching or transfer loans, which are paired with 4,232 non-switching loans. The total number of matched pairs is 6,249, which means that on average each non-switching loan is paired with 1.5 switching or transfer loans. Switching loans before branch closure have interest rates that are on average lower by ninety bps, which is estimated to be significant at the 1% level and most similar in magnitude to the ones reported in the literature.23 Transfer loans, which are the core of our analysis, do not receive any discount. This is the main finding in our paper, showing that new relationships established in the months following a branch closure do not benefit from the well-documented switching discounts. This evidence suggests that after the branch closure the informational link between the inside bank and its firms is broken. As a consequence, the outside bank that grants the first (transfer) loan to the firm will simply pool-price and lend to the firm at a market interest rate reflecting pooled risks.
One obvious concern is the heterogeneity in interest rate costs faced by banks between 2012 and 2015. In this period, financing rates varied among Portuguese banks because of the rising sovereign debt interest rates. Crosignani, Faria-e-Castro, and Fonseca (2015), for example, find that the lending patterns of foreign, large, and small local banks were heterogeneous in the period between 2005 and 2014. In Column II we therefore also match on the bank affiliation to an international banking group (i.e., we match local to local and foreign to foreign banks). Adding this matching variable does not alter the estimates.24
In Column III, we report the interest rate differential when comparing with interest rates on loans granted by outside banks (recall Figure 5). Now the comparison is within the same bank during the same quarter. Therefore, the loan rate differences between switching or transfer loans and non-switching loans cannot be attributed simply to differences in the marginal cost of funding between inside and outside banks (or more generally to any other form of unobserved heterogeneity with respect to the two banks). This is an important advantage over the matching exercise in Column II (or any alternative exercise whereby even more bank characteristics are added to the set of matching variables). So for the rest of the article, we focus the analysis on comparing switching loan interest rates with rates from non-switching loans of the outside bank to avoid the impact of heterogeneous interest rate policies among different types of banks.
Column III is therefore our benchmark model (which we detail further in Table V and subsequent tables). We continue to observe a switching discount (now of sixty-three bps). More importantly, our main result holds: for transfer loans in the first 6 months after closure there is again no discount.
Spreads between interest rates on switching or transfer loans and matched non-switching loans when the closest branch of the inside bank closes, after >6 months
We assess the spread between the interest rate on switching or first or later transfer loans and the interest rate on new non-switching loans obtained from the switchers’ outside bank (by other firms) when the closest branch of the inside bank closes. We match on the variables indicated in Column III of Table IV. All variables are defined in Table III. We regress the spreads on a constant and report the coefficient on the constant. We weigh each observation by one over the total number of comparable non-switching loans per switching or first transfer loan. We cluster at the switching-firm level and report robust standard errors between parentheses. a, b, and c indicate significance at the 10, 5, and 1% levels, two-tailed.
. | Switching . | Transfer . | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
Period since the branch closure . | Before . | 1–6 months after . | 7–12 months after . | >12 months after . |
Number of switching/transfer loans | 230 | 68 | 78 | 236 |
Number of non-switching loans | 878 | 295 | 338 | 986 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 1,050 | 305 | 535 | 1,371 |
Interest rate difference with matching | −62.81c | 15.62 | −57.30a | −94.21c |
(23.66) | (29.55) | (33.85) | (16.84) | |
Interest rate difference without matching | −79.73c | −180.55c | −209.16c | −263.39c |
(21.07) | (29.88) | (28.61) | (21.78) |
. | Switching . | Transfer . | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
Period since the branch closure . | Before . | 1–6 months after . | 7–12 months after . | >12 months after . |
Number of switching/transfer loans | 230 | 68 | 78 | 236 |
Number of non-switching loans | 878 | 295 | 338 | 986 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 1,050 | 305 | 535 | 1,371 |
Interest rate difference with matching | −62.81c | 15.62 | −57.30a | −94.21c |
(23.66) | (29.55) | (33.85) | (16.84) | |
Interest rate difference without matching | −79.73c | −180.55c | −209.16c | −263.39c |
(21.07) | (29.88) | (28.61) | (21.78) |
Spreads between interest rates on switching or transfer loans and matched non-switching loans when the closest branch of the inside bank closes, after >6 months
We assess the spread between the interest rate on switching or first or later transfer loans and the interest rate on new non-switching loans obtained from the switchers’ outside bank (by other firms) when the closest branch of the inside bank closes. We match on the variables indicated in Column III of Table IV. All variables are defined in Table III. We regress the spreads on a constant and report the coefficient on the constant. We weigh each observation by one over the total number of comparable non-switching loans per switching or first transfer loan. We cluster at the switching-firm level and report robust standard errors between parentheses. a, b, and c indicate significance at the 10, 5, and 1% levels, two-tailed.
. | Switching . | Transfer . | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
Period since the branch closure . | Before . | 1–6 months after . | 7–12 months after . | >12 months after . |
Number of switching/transfer loans | 230 | 68 | 78 | 236 |
Number of non-switching loans | 878 | 295 | 338 | 986 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 1,050 | 305 | 535 | 1,371 |
Interest rate difference with matching | −62.81c | 15.62 | −57.30a | −94.21c |
(23.66) | (29.55) | (33.85) | (16.84) | |
Interest rate difference without matching | −79.73c | −180.55c | −209.16c | −263.39c |
(21.07) | (29.88) | (28.61) | (21.78) |
. | Switching . | Transfer . | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
Period since the branch closure . | Before . | 1–6 months after . | 7–12 months after . | >12 months after . |
Number of switching/transfer loans | 230 | 68 | 78 | 236 |
Number of non-switching loans | 878 | 295 | 338 | 986 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 1,050 | 305 | 535 | 1,371 |
Interest rate difference with matching | −62.81c | 15.62 | −57.30a | −94.21c |
(23.66) | (29.55) | (33.85) | (16.84) | |
Interest rate difference without matching | −79.73c | −180.55c | −209.16c | −263.39c |
(21.07) | (29.88) | (28.61) | (21.78) |
In Column IV, we match on one extra variable, that is, firm identity. This allows us to compare switching or transfer with non-switching loans granted to the same firm in a given quarter. This allows us to fully control for demand at the firm level. In this case, we are not matching a given firm with others that share the same characteristics, but we are looking at several loans offered simultaneously to the same firm by different banks. Of course, this requires that we base our estimates on a much smaller sample of firms, with a bias toward larger firms that are more likely to obtain several loans at the same time. Even so, matching on firm identity does not change our main findings, that is, the interest rate discount is still present and significant before closure, while 1–6 months after closure there is no discount.
Of course, this strict matching strategy has an important trade-off in terms of the number of observations, as not many firms obtain several loans in the same period. Even the benchmark matching strategy hinges on a limited set of observations, what is necessary to require that the loans are truly comparable. Nevertheless, to be sure that our results are not biased by being too strict on the matching criteria, in Column V, we report one additional matching exercise, now using a much looser strategy. When we match only on the date, loan amount, and loan maturity, we see that the results for loans granted by the same outside bank remain entirely consistent, being now based on a 100-fold larger number of observations.
In Table V, we zoom in on the results obtained for transfers using the benchmark matching strategy (Column III from Table IV), now including a longer period after branch closures. Column II contains transfer loans 1–6 months after the closest branch of the inside bank is closed. As we had reported in Table IV, the estimated coefficient equals 15.62, but it is not significant at the 10% level. Ignoring matching would lead to a substantially large “hidden bias” in the estimated spreads for transfers than for switchers, as in this case, we would find a switching discount of 181 bps after the branch closures. This finding suggests that borrower heterogeneity is high for transfer loans, while before closure outside banks attracted a more similar set of customers.
In the period from 7 to 12 months after the branch closure, the coefficient is negative and close to the initial level (−57 bps), implying that as time passes the effect of the branch closure disappears. From the thirteenth month onward the effect of the branch closure disappears completely. The transfer discount is ninety-four bps, statistically significant at the 1% level. The reason for this reappearance of the discount in later periods should be that firms start re-engaging banks and hence we are no longer dealing with first transfer loans. These later transfers thus resemble regular switches.
The pattern is similar for the other matching strategies. Even when we use the tighter matching strategies comparing loans granted to the same firm by outside and inside banks after a branch closure (Column IV in Table IV) we obtain consistent results. There are no switching discounts immediately after branch closure. One year afterward, this effect has vanished.
In the first column of Table V, we include all switching loans by firms that switch in areas affected by branch closures. One could argue that firms that switch after closure are different from firms that switch before closure. As robustness, we use only firms that switch at least once in the period after closure. We do not report these results separately because they are the same as in Table V except for the period before closure. Before closure, we obtain thirty-seven observations and an average interest rate difference with a matching of −228.62 bps. The coefficient is statistically significant at the 10% level. Hence, results do not seem to be driven by different firms switching after closure.
4.2 First versus Later Transfers
According to the informational holdup theory, only the first transfer loan after branch closure should not have the interest rate discount observed in switching loans. After the first transfer loan, the firm establishes a relationship with a new bank. As a consequence, in future transfer loans, the outside bank of the first transfer in effect becomes a new inside bank, therefore able to hold up the firm. Hence, the outside bank in subsequent transfer loans has to offer the switching rate that we observed before, otherwise the firm will continue to borrow from the inside bank.
To test this conjecture, we separate first transfers from later transfers. Transfers are classified as “first transfers” if the firm is switching for the first time after the branch of its inside bank has closed and as “later transfers” otherwise. Table VI, Panel A shows interest rate differentials for first transfer loans only. The structure is similar to the one used in Table V. Switching loans are matched with non-switching loans from the outside bank. Matching variables are the ones used in Column III of Table IV. Before the branch closure, we use the same switching loans of Table V for easy reference, yielding the same switching discount of sixty-three bps.
Spreads between interest rates on switching or first and later transfer loans and matched non-switching loans given by the outside bank when the closest branch of the inside bank closes
We assess the spread between the interest rate on switching or first or later transfer loans and the interest rate on new non-switching loans obtained from the switchers’ outside bank (by other firms) when the closest branch of the inside bank closes. We match on the variables indicated in Column III of Table IV. All variables are defined in Table III. We regress the spreads on a constant and report the coefficient on the constant. We weigh each observation by one over the total number of comparable non-switching loans per switching or first transfer loan. We cluster at the switching-firm level and report robust standard errors between parentheses. We also report the difference between the mean interest rate on the switching or first transfer loans and the mean interest rate on the non-switching loans in each column. We report standard errors between parentheses. a, b, and c indicate significance at the 10, 5, and 1% levels, two-tailed.
. | Switching . | First transfer . | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
Period since the branch closure . | Before . | 1–6 months after . | 7–12 months after . | >12 months after . |
Panel A: First transfer loans | ||||
Number of switching/first transfer loans | 230 | 62 | 39 | 155 |
Number of non-switching loans | 878 | 283 | 185 | 659 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 1,050 | 289 | 235 | 783 |
Interest rate difference with matching | −62.81c | 25.06 | 0.77 | −96.89c |
(23.66) | (31.13) | (25.38) | (22.18) | |
Interest rate difference without matching | −79.73c | −163.60c | −239.23c | −229.91c |
(21.07) | (30.83) | (31.35) | (26.63) | |
Panel B: Later transfer loans | ||||
Number of switching loans | 230 | 6 | 39 | 81 |
Number of non-switching loans | 878 | 16 | 189 | 336 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 1,050 | 16 | 300 | 588 |
Interest rate difference with matching | −62.81c | −81.96 | −115.38b | −89.09c |
(23.66) | (74.82) | (51.13) | (24.20) | |
Interest rate difference without matching | −79.73c | −355.67b | −179.09c | −327.45c |
(21.07) | (90.54) | (45.13) | (26.11) |
. | Switching . | First transfer . | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
Period since the branch closure . | Before . | 1–6 months after . | 7–12 months after . | >12 months after . |
Panel A: First transfer loans | ||||
Number of switching/first transfer loans | 230 | 62 | 39 | 155 |
Number of non-switching loans | 878 | 283 | 185 | 659 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 1,050 | 289 | 235 | 783 |
Interest rate difference with matching | −62.81c | 25.06 | 0.77 | −96.89c |
(23.66) | (31.13) | (25.38) | (22.18) | |
Interest rate difference without matching | −79.73c | −163.60c | −239.23c | −229.91c |
(21.07) | (30.83) | (31.35) | (26.63) | |
Panel B: Later transfer loans | ||||
Number of switching loans | 230 | 6 | 39 | 81 |
Number of non-switching loans | 878 | 16 | 189 | 336 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 1,050 | 16 | 300 | 588 |
Interest rate difference with matching | −62.81c | −81.96 | −115.38b | −89.09c |
(23.66) | (74.82) | (51.13) | (24.20) | |
Interest rate difference without matching | −79.73c | −355.67b | −179.09c | −327.45c |
(21.07) | (90.54) | (45.13) | (26.11) |
Spreads between interest rates on switching or first and later transfer loans and matched non-switching loans given by the outside bank when the closest branch of the inside bank closes
We assess the spread between the interest rate on switching or first or later transfer loans and the interest rate on new non-switching loans obtained from the switchers’ outside bank (by other firms) when the closest branch of the inside bank closes. We match on the variables indicated in Column III of Table IV. All variables are defined in Table III. We regress the spreads on a constant and report the coefficient on the constant. We weigh each observation by one over the total number of comparable non-switching loans per switching or first transfer loan. We cluster at the switching-firm level and report robust standard errors between parentheses. We also report the difference between the mean interest rate on the switching or first transfer loans and the mean interest rate on the non-switching loans in each column. We report standard errors between parentheses. a, b, and c indicate significance at the 10, 5, and 1% levels, two-tailed.
. | Switching . | First transfer . | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
Period since the branch closure . | Before . | 1–6 months after . | 7–12 months after . | >12 months after . |
Panel A: First transfer loans | ||||
Number of switching/first transfer loans | 230 | 62 | 39 | 155 |
Number of non-switching loans | 878 | 283 | 185 | 659 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 1,050 | 289 | 235 | 783 |
Interest rate difference with matching | −62.81c | 25.06 | 0.77 | −96.89c |
(23.66) | (31.13) | (25.38) | (22.18) | |
Interest rate difference without matching | −79.73c | −163.60c | −239.23c | −229.91c |
(21.07) | (30.83) | (31.35) | (26.63) | |
Panel B: Later transfer loans | ||||
Number of switching loans | 230 | 6 | 39 | 81 |
Number of non-switching loans | 878 | 16 | 189 | 336 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 1,050 | 16 | 300 | 588 |
Interest rate difference with matching | −62.81c | −81.96 | −115.38b | −89.09c |
(23.66) | (74.82) | (51.13) | (24.20) | |
Interest rate difference without matching | −79.73c | −355.67b | −179.09c | −327.45c |
(21.07) | (90.54) | (45.13) | (26.11) |
. | Switching . | First transfer . | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
Period since the branch closure . | Before . | 1–6 months after . | 7–12 months after . | >12 months after . |
Panel A: First transfer loans | ||||
Number of switching/first transfer loans | 230 | 62 | 39 | 155 |
Number of non-switching loans | 878 | 283 | 185 | 659 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 1,050 | 289 | 235 | 783 |
Interest rate difference with matching | −62.81c | 25.06 | 0.77 | −96.89c |
(23.66) | (31.13) | (25.38) | (22.18) | |
Interest rate difference without matching | −79.73c | −163.60c | −239.23c | −229.91c |
(21.07) | (30.83) | (31.35) | (26.63) | |
Panel B: Later transfer loans | ||||
Number of switching loans | 230 | 6 | 39 | 81 |
Number of non-switching loans | 878 | 16 | 189 | 336 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 1,050 | 16 | 300 | 588 |
Interest rate difference with matching | −62.81c | −81.96 | −115.38b | −89.09c |
(23.66) | (74.82) | (51.13) | (24.20) | |
Interest rate difference without matching | −79.73c | −355.67b | −179.09c | −327.45c |
(21.07) | (90.54) | (45.13) | (26.11) |
When we only keep first transfers that occur 1–6 months after the closure, the coefficient is positive and results are not significant at the 10% significance level, meaning that there is no evidence of a switching discount up to 6 months after the closure of the branch.
Considering only first transfers 7–12 months after the closure, the coefficient is now positive, very close to 0, and still non-significant at the 10% significance level. In Table V, the coefficient was negative and significant, which implies that later transfers were driving this result. As a consequence, the evidence is consistent with the fact that the effect of the branch closure goes >6 months.
More than 12 months after the closure, the coefficient is −97 bps, close to the −94 bps reported in Table V. Results are now significant at the 1% level. These results imply that in the long-term the effect of the branch closure fades even for first transfer loans. The evidence is consistent with the gradual fading of pool-pricing of the group of firms transferring in immediate need of financing, to a reestablishment of a discount granted to individual “switching” firms to be recovered later through informational holdup.
Table VI, Panel B contains interest rate differentials for later loan transfers. This table again follows the same structure as in Table V. In the 1–6 months after the branch closure, the interest differential is −82 bps, but not statistically significant, suggesting that these loans may not enjoy any switching discount.
In the 7 and 12 months after the branch closure, the interest rate differential for these later transfers is −115 bps and is significant at the 5% level. Beyond 12 months after the branch closure, the switching discount is 89 bps, significant at the 1% level.
These results contrast with the findings from Table VI, Panel A. While for first transfers, there is no switching discount in the first year after branch closure, for later transfers we observe a sizeable discount. This result is consistent with the hypothesis that the outside bank receiving the transferring firm informationally captures it such that later transfers involving new outside banks will again result in the switching discount we have seen so far.
4.3 Transferring Within the Inside Bank
In Table VII, we investigate (regular) switching versus transferring within the inside bank, which is the bank that closes the branch. Hence we assess the spread between the interest rate on switching or first transfer loans now granted by other branches from the same inside bank that closes a branch and the interest rate on new non-switching loans obtained from the switchers’ outside bank (by other firms), all of this before and after the closest branch of the inside bank closes.25
Spreads between interest rates on switching or first transfer loans, given by other branches of the inside bank that close a branch, and matched non-switching loans given by the outside bank when the closest branch of the inside bank closes
We assess the spread between the interest rate on switching or first transfer loans granted by other branches from the inside bank that closes a branch and the interest rate on new non-switching loans obtained from the switchers’ outside bank (by other firms) when the closest branch of the inside bank closes. We match on the variables from Column V of Table IV, on credit rating and on a variable that is equal to 1 if the credit relationship is >5-years old. All variables are defined in Table III. We include only firms with risk category ≤3. We regress the spreads on a constant and report the coefficient on the constant. We weigh each observation by one over the total number of comparable non-switching loans per switching or first transfer loan. We cluster at the switching-firm level and report robust standard errors between parentheses. We also report the difference between the mean interest rate on the switching or first transfer loans and the mean interest rate on the non-switching loans in each column. We report standard errors between parentheses. a, b, and c indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, two-tailed.
. | Loans before . | First transfer within the inside bank . | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
Period since the branch closure . | Before . | 1–6 months after . | 7–12 months after . | >12 months after . |
Number of switching/first transfer loans | 241 | 24 | 34 | 54 |
Number of non-switching loans | 8,091 | 893 | 1,707 | 1,396 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 10,301 | 893 | 1,772 | 1,413 |
Interest rate difference with matching | −52.50c | −92.97b | −73.42b | −33.58a |
(19.86) | (41.23) | (31.65) | (19.90) | |
Interest rate difference without matching | −4.33 | −246.03c | −195.81c | −293.56c |
(29.15) | (30.24) | (43.95) | (28.94) |
. | Loans before . | First transfer within the inside bank . | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
Period since the branch closure . | Before . | 1–6 months after . | 7–12 months after . | >12 months after . |
Number of switching/first transfer loans | 241 | 24 | 34 | 54 |
Number of non-switching loans | 8,091 | 893 | 1,707 | 1,396 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 10,301 | 893 | 1,772 | 1,413 |
Interest rate difference with matching | −52.50c | −92.97b | −73.42b | −33.58a |
(19.86) | (41.23) | (31.65) | (19.90) | |
Interest rate difference without matching | −4.33 | −246.03c | −195.81c | −293.56c |
(29.15) | (30.24) | (43.95) | (28.94) |
Spreads between interest rates on switching or first transfer loans, given by other branches of the inside bank that close a branch, and matched non-switching loans given by the outside bank when the closest branch of the inside bank closes
We assess the spread between the interest rate on switching or first transfer loans granted by other branches from the inside bank that closes a branch and the interest rate on new non-switching loans obtained from the switchers’ outside bank (by other firms) when the closest branch of the inside bank closes. We match on the variables from Column V of Table IV, on credit rating and on a variable that is equal to 1 if the credit relationship is >5-years old. All variables are defined in Table III. We include only firms with risk category ≤3. We regress the spreads on a constant and report the coefficient on the constant. We weigh each observation by one over the total number of comparable non-switching loans per switching or first transfer loan. We cluster at the switching-firm level and report robust standard errors between parentheses. We also report the difference between the mean interest rate on the switching or first transfer loans and the mean interest rate on the non-switching loans in each column. We report standard errors between parentheses. a, b, and c indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, two-tailed.
. | Loans before . | First transfer within the inside bank . | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
Period since the branch closure . | Before . | 1–6 months after . | 7–12 months after . | >12 months after . |
Number of switching/first transfer loans | 241 | 24 | 34 | 54 |
Number of non-switching loans | 8,091 | 893 | 1,707 | 1,396 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 10,301 | 893 | 1,772 | 1,413 |
Interest rate difference with matching | −52.50c | −92.97b | −73.42b | −33.58a |
(19.86) | (41.23) | (31.65) | (19.90) | |
Interest rate difference without matching | −4.33 | −246.03c | −195.81c | −293.56c |
(29.15) | (30.24) | (43.95) | (28.94) |
. | Loans before . | First transfer within the inside bank . | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
Period since the branch closure . | Before . | 1–6 months after . | 7–12 months after . | >12 months after . |
Number of switching/first transfer loans | 241 | 24 | 34 | 54 |
Number of non-switching loans | 8,091 | 893 | 1,707 | 1,396 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 10,301 | 893 | 1,772 | 1,413 |
Interest rate difference with matching | −52.50c | −92.97b | −73.42b | −33.58a |
(19.86) | (41.23) | (31.65) | (19.90) | |
Interest rate difference without matching | −4.33 | −246.03c | −195.81c | −293.56c |
(29.15) | (30.24) | (43.95) | (28.94) |
If other branches of the inside bank are inconveniently located in other areas (which is often the case) and if geographical distance dilutes the quality of the information signal these branches are able to obtain (e.g., Hauswald and Marquez, 2006; Agarwal and Hauswald, 2010), then we would expect the pricing of these within-inside bank transfers to be priced more like later transfer (or switching) loans whereby firms once more receive the discount. That is exactly what we find.26
4.4 Default after Transferring
In Table VIII, we distinguish between switching and transfer loans 1 or 2 years after switching or transferring with respect to their default probability and the loan loss rate given default. In Panel A of the table, the dependent variable equals one if the firm defaults at the firm–bank level. In Panel B, the dependent variable equals the share of the outstanding amount in default for all firm–bank pairs. We include more control variables as we move from Columns I to III (that study a 1-year horizon), and similarly from Columns IV to VI (for a 2-year horizon).
Default rate for firms that switch and transfer
The table distinguishes between switching and transfer loans with respect to their default probability and loan loss rate. In Panel A, the dependent variable equals one if the firm defaults at the firm–bank level 1 or 2 years after the switching or transfer event. In Panel B, the dependent variable equals the share of the outstanding amount in default for all firm–bank pairs 1 and 2 years after the switching or transfer event. All models include a constant. We report robust standard errors between parentheses. a, b, and c indicate significance at the 10, 5, and 1% levels, two-tailed.
. | I . | II . | III . | IV . | V . | VI . |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Panel A: The firm defaults on the loan 1 or 2 years after switch or transfer | ||||||
After 1 year | After 2 years | |||||
Transfer loan | −0.50 | −0.36 | −0.26 | −1.00a | −0.64 | −0.45 |
(0.45) | (0.46) | (0.46) | (0.61) | (0.62) | (0.62) | |
Credit rating, province, quarter, economic activity, and legal structure | No | Yes | Yes | No | Yes | Yes |
Interest rate | No | No | Yes | No | No | Yes |
Observations | 24,292 | 24,288 | 24,288 | 24,292 | 24,288 | 24,288 |
R-squared | 0.00 | 0.03 | 0.03 | 0.00 | 0.03 | 0.04 |
Panel B: The loss rate on the loan 1 or 2 years after switch or transfer | ||||||
After 1 year | After 2 years | |||||
Transfer loan | −0.09 | −0.04 | −0.01 | −1.19c | −1.07c | −0.98c |
(0.28) | (0.28) | (0.28) | (0.33) | (0.34) | (0.34) | |
Credit rating, province, quarter, economic activity, and legal structure | No | Yes | Yes | No | Yes | Yes |
Interest rate | No | No | Yes | No | No | Yes |
Observations | 24,292 | 24,288 | 24,288 | 24,292 | 24,288 | 24,288 |
R2 | 0.00 | 0.02 | 0.02 | 0.00 | 0.02 | 0.03 |
. | I . | II . | III . | IV . | V . | VI . |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Panel A: The firm defaults on the loan 1 or 2 years after switch or transfer | ||||||
After 1 year | After 2 years | |||||
Transfer loan | −0.50 | −0.36 | −0.26 | −1.00a | −0.64 | −0.45 |
(0.45) | (0.46) | (0.46) | (0.61) | (0.62) | (0.62) | |
Credit rating, province, quarter, economic activity, and legal structure | No | Yes | Yes | No | Yes | Yes |
Interest rate | No | No | Yes | No | No | Yes |
Observations | 24,292 | 24,288 | 24,288 | 24,292 | 24,288 | 24,288 |
R-squared | 0.00 | 0.03 | 0.03 | 0.00 | 0.03 | 0.04 |
Panel B: The loss rate on the loan 1 or 2 years after switch or transfer | ||||||
After 1 year | After 2 years | |||||
Transfer loan | −0.09 | −0.04 | −0.01 | −1.19c | −1.07c | −0.98c |
(0.28) | (0.28) | (0.28) | (0.33) | (0.34) | (0.34) | |
Credit rating, province, quarter, economic activity, and legal structure | No | Yes | Yes | No | Yes | Yes |
Interest rate | No | No | Yes | No | No | Yes |
Observations | 24,292 | 24,288 | 24,288 | 24,292 | 24,288 | 24,288 |
R2 | 0.00 | 0.02 | 0.02 | 0.00 | 0.02 | 0.03 |
Default rate for firms that switch and transfer
The table distinguishes between switching and transfer loans with respect to their default probability and loan loss rate. In Panel A, the dependent variable equals one if the firm defaults at the firm–bank level 1 or 2 years after the switching or transfer event. In Panel B, the dependent variable equals the share of the outstanding amount in default for all firm–bank pairs 1 and 2 years after the switching or transfer event. All models include a constant. We report robust standard errors between parentheses. a, b, and c indicate significance at the 10, 5, and 1% levels, two-tailed.
. | I . | II . | III . | IV . | V . | VI . |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Panel A: The firm defaults on the loan 1 or 2 years after switch or transfer | ||||||
After 1 year | After 2 years | |||||
Transfer loan | −0.50 | −0.36 | −0.26 | −1.00a | −0.64 | −0.45 |
(0.45) | (0.46) | (0.46) | (0.61) | (0.62) | (0.62) | |
Credit rating, province, quarter, economic activity, and legal structure | No | Yes | Yes | No | Yes | Yes |
Interest rate | No | No | Yes | No | No | Yes |
Observations | 24,292 | 24,288 | 24,288 | 24,292 | 24,288 | 24,288 |
R-squared | 0.00 | 0.03 | 0.03 | 0.00 | 0.03 | 0.04 |
Panel B: The loss rate on the loan 1 or 2 years after switch or transfer | ||||||
After 1 year | After 2 years | |||||
Transfer loan | −0.09 | −0.04 | −0.01 | −1.19c | −1.07c | −0.98c |
(0.28) | (0.28) | (0.28) | (0.33) | (0.34) | (0.34) | |
Credit rating, province, quarter, economic activity, and legal structure | No | Yes | Yes | No | Yes | Yes |
Interest rate | No | No | Yes | No | No | Yes |
Observations | 24,292 | 24,288 | 24,288 | 24,292 | 24,288 | 24,288 |
R2 | 0.00 | 0.02 | 0.02 | 0.00 | 0.02 | 0.03 |
. | I . | II . | III . | IV . | V . | VI . |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Panel A: The firm defaults on the loan 1 or 2 years after switch or transfer | ||||||
After 1 year | After 2 years | |||||
Transfer loan | −0.50 | −0.36 | −0.26 | −1.00a | −0.64 | −0.45 |
(0.45) | (0.46) | (0.46) | (0.61) | (0.62) | (0.62) | |
Credit rating, province, quarter, economic activity, and legal structure | No | Yes | Yes | No | Yes | Yes |
Interest rate | No | No | Yes | No | No | Yes |
Observations | 24,292 | 24,288 | 24,288 | 24,292 | 24,288 | 24,288 |
R-squared | 0.00 | 0.03 | 0.03 | 0.00 | 0.03 | 0.04 |
Panel B: The loss rate on the loan 1 or 2 years after switch or transfer | ||||||
After 1 year | After 2 years | |||||
Transfer loan | −0.09 | −0.04 | −0.01 | −1.19c | −1.07c | −0.98c |
(0.28) | (0.28) | (0.28) | (0.33) | (0.34) | (0.34) | |
Credit rating, province, quarter, economic activity, and legal structure | No | Yes | Yes | No | Yes | Yes |
Interest rate | No | No | Yes | No | No | Yes |
Observations | 24,292 | 24,288 | 24,288 | 24,292 | 24,288 | 24,288 |
R2 | 0.00 | 0.02 | 0.02 | 0.00 | 0.02 | 0.03 |
We find that in all instances, but in particular for a 2-year horizon, the estimated coefficient on transfer loans is negative suggesting that transfer borrowers are less likely to default than switchers. These results are consistent with informational holdup theory, which predicts that switchers are on average worse than non-switchers, but also that both good and bad firms switch.
5. Robustness
5.1 Local Banking Sector Competition and Unexpected Branch Closures
We note that Portugal is one of the EU countries with the highest bank branch density.27 The closure of a few branches is unlikely to affect local bank competition and thus our results should be driven by asymmetric information rather than by changes in competition.28 To exclude the latter possibility entirely, in an Appendix B: Robustness of Empirical Findings, we discuss an extensive array of analyses of areas where given the many branches present the hypothetical closure of a branch should have an even more negligible impact on competition. Our findings are unaffected by focusing on such areas.
To be sure that the absence of discounts after loan transfers is not due to the fact that branch closures could have been anticipated, we run our estimates for a subsample of branches that were more unlikely to close. To do that, we first estimate a simple model to compute the likelihood of individual branch closure (as in Morales Acevedo and Ongena, 2020).
In Table IX, we report the results of a regression model that estimates the probability of individual branch closures. We run both linear probability model and probit specifications.29 In Figure 6, we show the predictive quality of the model using a ROC curve. When controlling for the county, bank, and time fixed effects, we find that smaller branches are more likely to close. Furthermore, a higher local branch density is also associated with a higher probability of branch closure.

ROC curve for the branch closure prediction model. The figure above shows the ROC curve for the branch closure prediction probit model ( Supplementary Appendix 2). The AUC is 0.8070 and is significantly different from 0 at the 5% significance level. We performed 1,000 replications and clustered at the branch level.
Probability of branch closure
We assess the probability that branches close in a given month. We regress a dummy variable that marks whether each branch closes in a given month on the variables defined below. Branch density refers to the number of branches per 1,000 adults. We use separate linear probability and probit specifications. We cluster at the bank level and report robust standard errors between parentheses. a, b, and c indicate significance at the 10, 5, and 1% levels, two-tailed.
Specification . | LPM . | Probit . |
---|---|---|
Amount outstanding (EUR Million) | −0.0005a | −0.0006a |
(0.0002) | (0.0001) | |
Percentage of defaulted loans (≥1 month) | 0.0021 | 0.0015 |
(0.0016) | (0.0026) | |
Branch density | 0.0100c | 0.0255c |
(0.0035) | (0.0035) | |
Observations | 369,131 | 304,641 |
County dummies | Yes | Yes |
Bank-time dummies | Yes | No |
Time dummies | No | Yes |
Bank dummies | No | Yes |
Specification . | LPM . | Probit . |
---|---|---|
Amount outstanding (EUR Million) | −0.0005a | −0.0006a |
(0.0002) | (0.0001) | |
Percentage of defaulted loans (≥1 month) | 0.0021 | 0.0015 |
(0.0016) | (0.0026) | |
Branch density | 0.0100c | 0.0255c |
(0.0035) | (0.0035) | |
Observations | 369,131 | 304,641 |
County dummies | Yes | Yes |
Bank-time dummies | Yes | No |
Time dummies | No | Yes |
Bank dummies | No | Yes |
Probability of branch closure
We assess the probability that branches close in a given month. We regress a dummy variable that marks whether each branch closes in a given month on the variables defined below. Branch density refers to the number of branches per 1,000 adults. We use separate linear probability and probit specifications. We cluster at the bank level and report robust standard errors between parentheses. a, b, and c indicate significance at the 10, 5, and 1% levels, two-tailed.
Specification . | LPM . | Probit . |
---|---|---|
Amount outstanding (EUR Million) | −0.0005a | −0.0006a |
(0.0002) | (0.0001) | |
Percentage of defaulted loans (≥1 month) | 0.0021 | 0.0015 |
(0.0016) | (0.0026) | |
Branch density | 0.0100c | 0.0255c |
(0.0035) | (0.0035) | |
Observations | 369,131 | 304,641 |
County dummies | Yes | Yes |
Bank-time dummies | Yes | No |
Time dummies | No | Yes |
Bank dummies | No | Yes |
Specification . | LPM . | Probit . |
---|---|---|
Amount outstanding (EUR Million) | −0.0005a | −0.0006a |
(0.0002) | (0.0001) | |
Percentage of defaulted loans (≥1 month) | 0.0021 | 0.0015 |
(0.0016) | (0.0026) | |
Branch density | 0.0100c | 0.0255c |
(0.0035) | (0.0035) | |
Observations | 369,131 | 304,641 |
County dummies | Yes | Yes |
Bank-time dummies | Yes | No |
Time dummies | No | Yes |
Bank dummies | No | Yes |
Our next step is to estimate our main empirical specification on transfers for a subsample of branches that were unlikely to close (Table X). To do that, we use the estimated likelihood of individual branch closure using a probit model. If we split the sample into three quantiles according to this likelihood and use only the group of branches that were least likely to close, we confirm that our results remain unchanged.
Spreads between interest rates on switching or transfer loans and matched non-switching loans given by the outside bank when the closest branch of the inside bank closes—unlikely branch closures
We assess the spread between the interest rate on switching or transfer loans and the interest rate on new non-switching loans obtained from the switchers’ outside bank (by other firms) when the closest branch of the inside bank closes. We use the estimates of the probability of branch closures to divide transfers in three quantiles and use only transfers from branches that are the least likely to close. We match on the variables indicated in Column III of Table IV. All variables are defined in Table III. We regress the spreads on a constant and report the coefficient on the constant. We weigh each observation by one over the total number of comparable non-switching loans per switching or transfer loan. We cluster at the switching-firm level and report robust standard errors between parentheses. We also report the difference between the mean interest rate on the switching or transfer loans and the mean interest rate on the non-switching loans in each column. We report standard errors between parentheses. a, b, and c indicate significance at the 10, 5, and 1% levels, two-tailed.
. | Switching . | Transfer . | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
Period since the branch closure . | Before . | 1–6 months after . | 7–12 months after . | >12 months after . |
Number of switching/transfer loans | 31 | 15 | 12 | 123 |
Number of non-switching loans | 211 | 100 | 67 | 613 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 255 | 106 | 84 | 796 |
Interest rate difference with matching | −64.74b | 10.54 | −137.31b | −65.43c |
(27.71) | (54.96) | (41.96) | (22.81) | |
Interest rate difference without matching | −166.54c | −165.17b | 45.73 | −118.97 |
(42.18) | (69.93) | (138.45) | (126.84) |
. | Switching . | Transfer . | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
Period since the branch closure . | Before . | 1–6 months after . | 7–12 months after . | >12 months after . |
Number of switching/transfer loans | 31 | 15 | 12 | 123 |
Number of non-switching loans | 211 | 100 | 67 | 613 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 255 | 106 | 84 | 796 |
Interest rate difference with matching | −64.74b | 10.54 | −137.31b | −65.43c |
(27.71) | (54.96) | (41.96) | (22.81) | |
Interest rate difference without matching | −166.54c | −165.17b | 45.73 | −118.97 |
(42.18) | (69.93) | (138.45) | (126.84) |
Spreads between interest rates on switching or transfer loans and matched non-switching loans given by the outside bank when the closest branch of the inside bank closes—unlikely branch closures
We assess the spread between the interest rate on switching or transfer loans and the interest rate on new non-switching loans obtained from the switchers’ outside bank (by other firms) when the closest branch of the inside bank closes. We use the estimates of the probability of branch closures to divide transfers in three quantiles and use only transfers from branches that are the least likely to close. We match on the variables indicated in Column III of Table IV. All variables are defined in Table III. We regress the spreads on a constant and report the coefficient on the constant. We weigh each observation by one over the total number of comparable non-switching loans per switching or transfer loan. We cluster at the switching-firm level and report robust standard errors between parentheses. We also report the difference between the mean interest rate on the switching or transfer loans and the mean interest rate on the non-switching loans in each column. We report standard errors between parentheses. a, b, and c indicate significance at the 10, 5, and 1% levels, two-tailed.
. | Switching . | Transfer . | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
Period since the branch closure . | Before . | 1–6 months after . | 7–12 months after . | >12 months after . |
Number of switching/transfer loans | 31 | 15 | 12 | 123 |
Number of non-switching loans | 211 | 100 | 67 | 613 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 255 | 106 | 84 | 796 |
Interest rate difference with matching | −64.74b | 10.54 | −137.31b | −65.43c |
(27.71) | (54.96) | (41.96) | (22.81) | |
Interest rate difference without matching | −166.54c | −165.17b | 45.73 | −118.97 |
(42.18) | (69.93) | (138.45) | (126.84) |
. | Switching . | Transfer . | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
Period since the branch closure . | Before . | 1–6 months after . | 7–12 months after . | >12 months after . |
Number of switching/transfer loans | 31 | 15 | 12 | 123 |
Number of non-switching loans | 211 | 100 | 67 | 613 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 255 | 106 | 84 | 796 |
Interest rate difference with matching | −64.74b | 10.54 | −137.31b | −65.43c |
(27.71) | (54.96) | (41.96) | (22.81) | |
Interest rate difference without matching | −166.54c | −165.17b | 45.73 | −118.97 |
(42.18) | (69.93) | (138.45) | (126.84) |
5.2 Comparison and Matching Methodology
So far comparisons between transfer and switching loans are based on singular estimates for each group. In Table XI, we now directly compare the difference between interest rate discounts of transfer and switching loans. We match switching loans with non-switching loans that share the characteristics of Column III of Table IV and calculate the interest rate difference between each switching loan and their matching non-switching loans. We regress interest rate differentials on a constant and on a categorical variable that classifies loan transfers according to the number of months since the closure of the branch of the inside bank.
Spreads between interest rates on switching or transfer loans
We assess the spread between the interest rate on switching or transfer loans and the interest rate on new non-switching loans obtained from the switchers’ outside bank (by other firms) when the closest branch of the inside bank closes. We match on the variables indicated in Column III of Table IV. All variables are defined in Table III. We create a categorical variable to classify loan transfers. Categories are: switching loans that occur before the branch closure; loan transfers 1–6 months after the closure; loan transfers 7–12 months after the closure; loan transfers >12 months after the closure. We regress the spreads on a constant and on the categorical variable, and report the coefficient on the constant. We weigh each observation by one over the total number of comparable non-switching loans per switching or transfer loan. We cluster at the switching-firm level and report robust standard errors between parentheses. We also report the difference between the mean interest rate on the switching or transfer loans and the mean interest rate on the non-switching loans in each column. We report standard errors between parentheses. a, b, and c indicate significance at the 10, 5, and 1% levels, two-tailed.
Type of transfer . | All transfers . | First transfers . | Later transfers . |
---|---|---|---|
Number of switching/transfer loans | 612 | 486 | 356 |
Number of non-switching loans | 2,497 | 2,005 | 1,419 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 3,261 | 2,357 | 1,954 |
Switching discount | −62.81c | −62.81c | −62.81c |
(23.62) | (23.63) | (23.66) | |
Transfer 1–6 months after | 78.43b | 87.87b | −19.15 |
(37.68) | (38.91) | (72.48) | |
Transfer 7–12 months after | 5.51 | 63.58a | −52.57 |
(40.92) | (34.19) | (54.79) | |
Transfer >12 months after | −31.40 | −34.08 | −26.28 |
(28.99) | (32.37) | (33.65) |
Type of transfer . | All transfers . | First transfers . | Later transfers . |
---|---|---|---|
Number of switching/transfer loans | 612 | 486 | 356 |
Number of non-switching loans | 2,497 | 2,005 | 1,419 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 3,261 | 2,357 | 1,954 |
Switching discount | −62.81c | −62.81c | −62.81c |
(23.62) | (23.63) | (23.66) | |
Transfer 1–6 months after | 78.43b | 87.87b | −19.15 |
(37.68) | (38.91) | (72.48) | |
Transfer 7–12 months after | 5.51 | 63.58a | −52.57 |
(40.92) | (34.19) | (54.79) | |
Transfer >12 months after | −31.40 | −34.08 | −26.28 |
(28.99) | (32.37) | (33.65) |
Spreads between interest rates on switching or transfer loans
We assess the spread between the interest rate on switching or transfer loans and the interest rate on new non-switching loans obtained from the switchers’ outside bank (by other firms) when the closest branch of the inside bank closes. We match on the variables indicated in Column III of Table IV. All variables are defined in Table III. We create a categorical variable to classify loan transfers. Categories are: switching loans that occur before the branch closure; loan transfers 1–6 months after the closure; loan transfers 7–12 months after the closure; loan transfers >12 months after the closure. We regress the spreads on a constant and on the categorical variable, and report the coefficient on the constant. We weigh each observation by one over the total number of comparable non-switching loans per switching or transfer loan. We cluster at the switching-firm level and report robust standard errors between parentheses. We also report the difference between the mean interest rate on the switching or transfer loans and the mean interest rate on the non-switching loans in each column. We report standard errors between parentheses. a, b, and c indicate significance at the 10, 5, and 1% levels, two-tailed.
Type of transfer . | All transfers . | First transfers . | Later transfers . |
---|---|---|---|
Number of switching/transfer loans | 612 | 486 | 356 |
Number of non-switching loans | 2,497 | 2,005 | 1,419 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 3,261 | 2,357 | 1,954 |
Switching discount | −62.81c | −62.81c | −62.81c |
(23.62) | (23.63) | (23.66) | |
Transfer 1–6 months after | 78.43b | 87.87b | −19.15 |
(37.68) | (38.91) | (72.48) | |
Transfer 7–12 months after | 5.51 | 63.58a | −52.57 |
(40.92) | (34.19) | (54.79) | |
Transfer >12 months after | −31.40 | −34.08 | −26.28 |
(28.99) | (32.37) | (33.65) |
Type of transfer . | All transfers . | First transfers . | Later transfers . |
---|---|---|---|
Number of switching/transfer loans | 612 | 486 | 356 |
Number of non-switching loans | 2,497 | 2,005 | 1,419 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 3,261 | 2,357 | 1,954 |
Switching discount | −62.81c | −62.81c | −62.81c |
(23.62) | (23.63) | (23.66) | |
Transfer 1–6 months after | 78.43b | 87.87b | −19.15 |
(37.68) | (38.91) | (72.48) | |
Transfer 7–12 months after | 5.51 | 63.58a | −52.57 |
(40.92) | (34.19) | (54.79) | |
Transfer >12 months after | −31.40 | −34.08 | −26.28 |
(28.99) | (32.37) | (33.65) |
Spreads between interest rates on switching or first transfer loans and matched non-switching loans given to the same firm when the closest branch of the inside bank closes
We assess the spread between the interest rate on switching or first transfer loans and the interest rate on new non-switching loans obtained by the same firm when the closest branch of the inside bank closes. We match on the variables indicated in Column IV of Table IV and exclude non-switching loans from the outside bank. All variables are defined in Table III. We regress the spreads on a constant and report the coefficient on the constant. We weigh each observation by one over the total number of comparable non-switching loans per switching or first transfer loan. We cluster at the switching-firm level and report robust standard errors between parentheses. We also report the difference between the mean interest rate on the switching or first transfer loans and the mean interest rate on the non-switching loans in each column. We report standard errors between parentheses. a, b, and c indicate significance at the 10, 5, and 1% levels, two-tailed.
. | Switching . | First transfer . | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
Period since the branch closure . | Before . | 1–6 months after . | 7–12 months after . | >12 months after . |
Number of switching/first transfer loans | 68 | 14 | 10 | 36 |
Number of non-switching loans | 121 | 28 | 21 | 56 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 220 | 34 | 67 | 75 |
Interest rate difference with matching | −212.53c | −62.24 | −161.24b | −146.62c |
(73.70) | (52.18) | (30.89) | (40.32) | |
Interest rate difference without matching | −263.61c | −131.02b | −243.62c | −275.54c |
(20.28) | (54.97) | (25.57) | (26.51) |
. | Switching . | First transfer . | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
Period since the branch closure . | Before . | 1–6 months after . | 7–12 months after . | >12 months after . |
Number of switching/first transfer loans | 68 | 14 | 10 | 36 |
Number of non-switching loans | 121 | 28 | 21 | 56 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 220 | 34 | 67 | 75 |
Interest rate difference with matching | −212.53c | −62.24 | −161.24b | −146.62c |
(73.70) | (52.18) | (30.89) | (40.32) | |
Interest rate difference without matching | −263.61c | −131.02b | −243.62c | −275.54c |
(20.28) | (54.97) | (25.57) | (26.51) |
Spreads between interest rates on switching or first transfer loans and matched non-switching loans given to the same firm when the closest branch of the inside bank closes
We assess the spread between the interest rate on switching or first transfer loans and the interest rate on new non-switching loans obtained by the same firm when the closest branch of the inside bank closes. We match on the variables indicated in Column IV of Table IV and exclude non-switching loans from the outside bank. All variables are defined in Table III. We regress the spreads on a constant and report the coefficient on the constant. We weigh each observation by one over the total number of comparable non-switching loans per switching or first transfer loan. We cluster at the switching-firm level and report robust standard errors between parentheses. We also report the difference between the mean interest rate on the switching or first transfer loans and the mean interest rate on the non-switching loans in each column. We report standard errors between parentheses. a, b, and c indicate significance at the 10, 5, and 1% levels, two-tailed.
. | Switching . | First transfer . | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
Period since the branch closure . | Before . | 1–6 months after . | 7–12 months after . | >12 months after . |
Number of switching/first transfer loans | 68 | 14 | 10 | 36 |
Number of non-switching loans | 121 | 28 | 21 | 56 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 220 | 34 | 67 | 75 |
Interest rate difference with matching | −212.53c | −62.24 | −161.24b | −146.62c |
(73.70) | (52.18) | (30.89) | (40.32) | |
Interest rate difference without matching | −263.61c | −131.02b | −243.62c | −275.54c |
(20.28) | (54.97) | (25.57) | (26.51) |
. | Switching . | First transfer . | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
Period since the branch closure . | Before . | 1–6 months after . | 7–12 months after . | >12 months after . |
Number of switching/first transfer loans | 68 | 14 | 10 | 36 |
Number of non-switching loans | 121 | 28 | 21 | 56 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 220 | 34 | 67 | 75 |
Interest rate difference with matching | −212.53c | −62.24 | −161.24b | −146.62c |
(73.70) | (52.18) | (30.89) | (40.32) | |
Interest rate difference without matching | −263.61c | −131.02b | −243.62c | −275.54c |
(20.28) | (54.97) | (25.57) | (26.51) |
Spreads between interest rates on switching or later transfer loans and matched non-switching loans given to the same firm when the closest branch of the inside bank closes
We assess the spread between the interest rate on switching or later transfer loans and the interest rate on new non-switching loans obtained by the same firm when the closest branch of the inside bank closes. We match on the variables indicated in Column IV of Table IV and exclude non-switching loans from the outside bank. All variables are defined in Table III. We regress the spreads on a constant and report the coefficient on the constant. We weigh each observation by one over the total number of comparable non-switching loans per switching or later transfer loan. We cluster at the switching-firm level and report robust standard errors between parentheses. We also report the difference between the mean interest rate on the switching or later transfer loans and the mean interest rate on the non-switching loans in each column. We report standard errors between parentheses. a, b, and c indicate significance at the 10, 5, and 1% levels, two-tailed.
. | Switching . | Later transfer . | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
Period since the branch closure . | Before . | 1–6 months after . | 7–12 months after . | >12 months after . |
Number of switching loans | 68 | 0 | 21 | 42 |
Number of non-switching loans | 121 | 0 | 37 | 66 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 220 | 0 | 70 | 191 |
Constant | −212.53c | NA | −76.67b | −119.40b |
(73.70) | NA | (25.46) | (50.29) | |
Interest rate difference without matching | −226.78c | NA | −247.51c | −293.98c |
(26.80) | NA | (37.20) | (69.66) |
. | Switching . | Later transfer . | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
Period since the branch closure . | Before . | 1–6 months after . | 7–12 months after . | >12 months after . |
Number of switching loans | 68 | 0 | 21 | 42 |
Number of non-switching loans | 121 | 0 | 37 | 66 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 220 | 0 | 70 | 191 |
Constant | −212.53c | NA | −76.67b | −119.40b |
(73.70) | NA | (25.46) | (50.29) | |
Interest rate difference without matching | −226.78c | NA | −247.51c | −293.98c |
(26.80) | NA | (37.20) | (69.66) |
Spreads between interest rates on switching or later transfer loans and matched non-switching loans given to the same firm when the closest branch of the inside bank closes
We assess the spread between the interest rate on switching or later transfer loans and the interest rate on new non-switching loans obtained by the same firm when the closest branch of the inside bank closes. We match on the variables indicated in Column IV of Table IV and exclude non-switching loans from the outside bank. All variables are defined in Table III. We regress the spreads on a constant and report the coefficient on the constant. We weigh each observation by one over the total number of comparable non-switching loans per switching or later transfer loan. We cluster at the switching-firm level and report robust standard errors between parentheses. We also report the difference between the mean interest rate on the switching or later transfer loans and the mean interest rate on the non-switching loans in each column. We report standard errors between parentheses. a, b, and c indicate significance at the 10, 5, and 1% levels, two-tailed.
. | Switching . | Later transfer . | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
Period since the branch closure . | Before . | 1–6 months after . | 7–12 months after . | >12 months after . |
Number of switching loans | 68 | 0 | 21 | 42 |
Number of non-switching loans | 121 | 0 | 37 | 66 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 220 | 0 | 70 | 191 |
Constant | −212.53c | NA | −76.67b | −119.40b |
(73.70) | NA | (25.46) | (50.29) | |
Interest rate difference without matching | −226.78c | NA | −247.51c | −293.98c |
(26.80) | NA | (37.20) | (69.66) |
. | Switching . | Later transfer . | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
Period since the branch closure . | Before . | 1–6 months after . | 7–12 months after . | >12 months after . |
Number of switching loans | 68 | 0 | 21 | 42 |
Number of non-switching loans | 121 | 0 | 37 | 66 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 220 | 0 | 70 | 191 |
Constant | −212.53c | NA | −76.67b | −119.40b |
(73.70) | NA | (25.46) | (50.29) | |
Interest rate difference without matching | −226.78c | NA | −247.51c | −293.98c |
(26.80) | NA | (37.20) | (69.66) |
Switching loans that are not loan transfers have an average discount of sixty-three bps, significantly different from zero at the most common significance levels. In comparison to other switching loans, loan transfers up to 6 months after the branch closure have average interest rates greater than the switching interest rate by seventy-eight bps. This result is statistically significant at the 1% level, which confirms that loan transfers immediately after branch closures have interest rates that are significantly higher than the rates of normal switching loans. For later transfers, we do not observe this effect, as coefficients are not significant at the 10% significance level.
To ensure that our results are further robust to different matching strategies, we extensively revisit our matching methodology choices in Appendix B: Robustness of Empirical Findings. We further investigate and discuss various other sample composition and issues with variable definitions in Appendix B. At this stage, we also note that our main results hinge on ensuring that firms matched in treatment and control groups are as similar as possible. This of course depends on the choice of matching variables.
5.3 Matching and Differentiating Variables
5.3.a. Within-firm and firm credit rating.
In Tables XII and XIII, we return to the limited set of first and later transfer loans for which we also observe concurrent non-switching loans being granted to the same firm, that is, the matching scheme in Column IV in Table IV. Matching at the firm-level addresses two concerns. First, we verify if results are not driven by unobserved characteristics of firms that switch after branch closure. Second, we verify if results are driven by shoe-leather costs à la Klemperer (1987). If this is the case, then we should see discounts after branch closure, since entrants would still have to compete with other incumbent banks, which provide the loans we are matching with.
While also matching on firm identity provides a high degree of confidence in having controlled for all relevant heterogeneity, fewer observations remain. For example, we observe only fourteen first transfer loans in the period 1–6 months after the branch closure that can be matched with twenty-eight non-switching loans. But despite this substantial drop in the number of observations, results remain qualitatively most similar.
Recall that in our baseline results, one of the matching variables used is firms’ credit rating. This allows us to be sure that potential pricing differences are not attributable to differences in perceived risk. Nevertheless, it is interesting to dig deeper into this issue and examine if transfer and switching outcomes are similar for good and bad quality firms. Appendix B: Robustness of Empirical Findings discusses a set of exercises showing that the main results are not driven by differences in credit ratings.
5.3.b. Bank–firm relationship characteristics.
Another dimension on which it might be important to further extend our analysis is to consider issues on the relationship between borrowers and lenders. The number, uniqueness, and length of the relationships between borrowers and lenders influence the way interest rates are set (e.g., Petersen and Rajan, 1994; Berger and Udell, 1995).30 For instance, firms with a single bank relationship may face more difficulties in finding a new bank and may therefore face different pricing conditions.
To address this concern, in Table XIV, Panel A, we use a dummy that tags firms with multiple bank relationships in the month before the new loan as an extra matching variable. We once more observe similar results. Hence, interest rate discounts for switches and the impact of branch closures on switching discounts seems not to be driven by matching single relationship and multiple relationship loans.
Spreads between interest rates on switching or transfer loans and matched non-switching loans given by the outside bank when the closest branch of the inside bank closes: bank–firm relationships
We assess the spread between the interest rate on switching or transfer loans and the interest rate on new non-switching loans obtained from the switchers’ outside bank (by other firms) when the closest branch of the inside bank closes. We match on the variables indicated in Column III of Table IV. All variables are defined in Table III. We regress the spreads on a constant and report the coefficient on the constant. We weigh each observation by one over the total number of comparable non-switching loans per switching or transfer loan. We cluster at the switching-firm level and report robust standard errors between parentheses. We also report the difference between the mean interest rate on the switching or transfer loans and the mean interest rate on the non-switching loans in each column. We report standard errors between parentheses. a, b, and c indicate significance at the 10, 5, and 1% levels, two-tailed.
. | Switching . | Transfer . | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
Period since the branch closure . | Before . | 1–6 months after . | 7–12 months after . | >12 months after . |
Panel A: Matching also on a multiple bank relationship dummy | ||||
Number of switching/transfer loans | 191 | 56 | 73 | 202 |
Number of non-switching loans | 708 | 186 | 311 | 858 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 860 | 194 | 506 | 1,222 |
Interest rate difference with matching | −47.85a | 1.07 | −60.39a | −90.61c |
(26.24) | (34.25) | (35.66) | (17.69) | |
Interest rate difference without matching | −101.84c | −121.10c | −211.60c | −208.56b |
(24.80) | (39.06) | (51.98) | (81.25) | |
Panel B: Main lender closes | ||||
Number of switching/transfer loans | 47 | 14 | 23 | 61 |
Number of non-switching loans | 281 | 71 | 68 | 306 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 311 | 76 | 97 | 426 |
Interest rate difference with matching | −97.70b | −7.32 | −110.00 | −31.82 |
(47.28) | (84.06) | (81.57) | (34.07) | |
Interest rate difference without matching | −94.27a | −200.93c | −241.54b | 46.74 |
(48.40) | (55.39) | (103.76) | (212.77) | |
Panel C: Separation by length of relationship with the inside bank | ||||
Number of switching/transfer loans | 230 | 68 | 78 | 236 |
Number of non-switching loans | 878 | 295 | 338 | 986 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 1,050 | 305 | 535 | 1,371 |
Interest rate difference with matching | ||||
Constant | 12.74 | 18.33 | −46.21 | −89.34c |
(36.53) | (48.19) | (48.24) | (19.09) | |
1 = Relationship length >3 years | −117.40b | −4.98 | −15.73 | −9.51 |
(46.83) | (60.43) | (64.81) | (33.66) | |
Interest rate difference without matching | ||||
Constant | −30.72 | −163.52c | −239.99c | −259.92c |
(44.40) | (41.13) | (37.23) | (24.99) | |
1 = Relationship length >3 years | −76.17 | −31.30 | 43.72 | −6.77 |
(49.29) | (59.41) | (51.93) | (43.32) | |
Panel D: Only firms that transfer to a bank with no previous relationship ever | ||||
Number of switching/transfer loans | 160 | 48 | 59 | 115 |
Number of non-switching loans | 593 | 216 | 199 | 526 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 696 | 223 | 339 | 672 |
Interest rate difference with matching | −40.48a | 31.90 | −77.55a | −82.05c |
(24.13) | (36.90) | (39.42) | (24.59) | |
Interest rate difference without matching | −49.19a | −164.13c | −181.28c | −225.86c |
(26.81) | (34.22) | (31.37) | (33.91) |
. | Switching . | Transfer . | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
Period since the branch closure . | Before . | 1–6 months after . | 7–12 months after . | >12 months after . |
Panel A: Matching also on a multiple bank relationship dummy | ||||
Number of switching/transfer loans | 191 | 56 | 73 | 202 |
Number of non-switching loans | 708 | 186 | 311 | 858 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 860 | 194 | 506 | 1,222 |
Interest rate difference with matching | −47.85a | 1.07 | −60.39a | −90.61c |
(26.24) | (34.25) | (35.66) | (17.69) | |
Interest rate difference without matching | −101.84c | −121.10c | −211.60c | −208.56b |
(24.80) | (39.06) | (51.98) | (81.25) | |
Panel B: Main lender closes | ||||
Number of switching/transfer loans | 47 | 14 | 23 | 61 |
Number of non-switching loans | 281 | 71 | 68 | 306 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 311 | 76 | 97 | 426 |
Interest rate difference with matching | −97.70b | −7.32 | −110.00 | −31.82 |
(47.28) | (84.06) | (81.57) | (34.07) | |
Interest rate difference without matching | −94.27a | −200.93c | −241.54b | 46.74 |
(48.40) | (55.39) | (103.76) | (212.77) | |
Panel C: Separation by length of relationship with the inside bank | ||||
Number of switching/transfer loans | 230 | 68 | 78 | 236 |
Number of non-switching loans | 878 | 295 | 338 | 986 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 1,050 | 305 | 535 | 1,371 |
Interest rate difference with matching | ||||
Constant | 12.74 | 18.33 | −46.21 | −89.34c |
(36.53) | (48.19) | (48.24) | (19.09) | |
1 = Relationship length >3 years | −117.40b | −4.98 | −15.73 | −9.51 |
(46.83) | (60.43) | (64.81) | (33.66) | |
Interest rate difference without matching | ||||
Constant | −30.72 | −163.52c | −239.99c | −259.92c |
(44.40) | (41.13) | (37.23) | (24.99) | |
1 = Relationship length >3 years | −76.17 | −31.30 | 43.72 | −6.77 |
(49.29) | (59.41) | (51.93) | (43.32) | |
Panel D: Only firms that transfer to a bank with no previous relationship ever | ||||
Number of switching/transfer loans | 160 | 48 | 59 | 115 |
Number of non-switching loans | 593 | 216 | 199 | 526 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 696 | 223 | 339 | 672 |
Interest rate difference with matching | −40.48a | 31.90 | −77.55a | −82.05c |
(24.13) | (36.90) | (39.42) | (24.59) | |
Interest rate difference without matching | −49.19a | −164.13c | −181.28c | −225.86c |
(26.81) | (34.22) | (31.37) | (33.91) |
Spreads between interest rates on switching or transfer loans and matched non-switching loans given by the outside bank when the closest branch of the inside bank closes: bank–firm relationships
We assess the spread between the interest rate on switching or transfer loans and the interest rate on new non-switching loans obtained from the switchers’ outside bank (by other firms) when the closest branch of the inside bank closes. We match on the variables indicated in Column III of Table IV. All variables are defined in Table III. We regress the spreads on a constant and report the coefficient on the constant. We weigh each observation by one over the total number of comparable non-switching loans per switching or transfer loan. We cluster at the switching-firm level and report robust standard errors between parentheses. We also report the difference between the mean interest rate on the switching or transfer loans and the mean interest rate on the non-switching loans in each column. We report standard errors between parentheses. a, b, and c indicate significance at the 10, 5, and 1% levels, two-tailed.
. | Switching . | Transfer . | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
Period since the branch closure . | Before . | 1–6 months after . | 7–12 months after . | >12 months after . |
Panel A: Matching also on a multiple bank relationship dummy | ||||
Number of switching/transfer loans | 191 | 56 | 73 | 202 |
Number of non-switching loans | 708 | 186 | 311 | 858 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 860 | 194 | 506 | 1,222 |
Interest rate difference with matching | −47.85a | 1.07 | −60.39a | −90.61c |
(26.24) | (34.25) | (35.66) | (17.69) | |
Interest rate difference without matching | −101.84c | −121.10c | −211.60c | −208.56b |
(24.80) | (39.06) | (51.98) | (81.25) | |
Panel B: Main lender closes | ||||
Number of switching/transfer loans | 47 | 14 | 23 | 61 |
Number of non-switching loans | 281 | 71 | 68 | 306 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 311 | 76 | 97 | 426 |
Interest rate difference with matching | −97.70b | −7.32 | −110.00 | −31.82 |
(47.28) | (84.06) | (81.57) | (34.07) | |
Interest rate difference without matching | −94.27a | −200.93c | −241.54b | 46.74 |
(48.40) | (55.39) | (103.76) | (212.77) | |
Panel C: Separation by length of relationship with the inside bank | ||||
Number of switching/transfer loans | 230 | 68 | 78 | 236 |
Number of non-switching loans | 878 | 295 | 338 | 986 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 1,050 | 305 | 535 | 1,371 |
Interest rate difference with matching | ||||
Constant | 12.74 | 18.33 | −46.21 | −89.34c |
(36.53) | (48.19) | (48.24) | (19.09) | |
1 = Relationship length >3 years | −117.40b | −4.98 | −15.73 | −9.51 |
(46.83) | (60.43) | (64.81) | (33.66) | |
Interest rate difference without matching | ||||
Constant | −30.72 | −163.52c | −239.99c | −259.92c |
(44.40) | (41.13) | (37.23) | (24.99) | |
1 = Relationship length >3 years | −76.17 | −31.30 | 43.72 | −6.77 |
(49.29) | (59.41) | (51.93) | (43.32) | |
Panel D: Only firms that transfer to a bank with no previous relationship ever | ||||
Number of switching/transfer loans | 160 | 48 | 59 | 115 |
Number of non-switching loans | 593 | 216 | 199 | 526 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 696 | 223 | 339 | 672 |
Interest rate difference with matching | −40.48a | 31.90 | −77.55a | −82.05c |
(24.13) | (36.90) | (39.42) | (24.59) | |
Interest rate difference without matching | −49.19a | −164.13c | −181.28c | −225.86c |
(26.81) | (34.22) | (31.37) | (33.91) |
. | Switching . | Transfer . | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
Period since the branch closure . | Before . | 1–6 months after . | 7–12 months after . | >12 months after . |
Panel A: Matching also on a multiple bank relationship dummy | ||||
Number of switching/transfer loans | 191 | 56 | 73 | 202 |
Number of non-switching loans | 708 | 186 | 311 | 858 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 860 | 194 | 506 | 1,222 |
Interest rate difference with matching | −47.85a | 1.07 | −60.39a | −90.61c |
(26.24) | (34.25) | (35.66) | (17.69) | |
Interest rate difference without matching | −101.84c | −121.10c | −211.60c | −208.56b |
(24.80) | (39.06) | (51.98) | (81.25) | |
Panel B: Main lender closes | ||||
Number of switching/transfer loans | 47 | 14 | 23 | 61 |
Number of non-switching loans | 281 | 71 | 68 | 306 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 311 | 76 | 97 | 426 |
Interest rate difference with matching | −97.70b | −7.32 | −110.00 | −31.82 |
(47.28) | (84.06) | (81.57) | (34.07) | |
Interest rate difference without matching | −94.27a | −200.93c | −241.54b | 46.74 |
(48.40) | (55.39) | (103.76) | (212.77) | |
Panel C: Separation by length of relationship with the inside bank | ||||
Number of switching/transfer loans | 230 | 68 | 78 | 236 |
Number of non-switching loans | 878 | 295 | 338 | 986 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 1,050 | 305 | 535 | 1,371 |
Interest rate difference with matching | ||||
Constant | 12.74 | 18.33 | −46.21 | −89.34c |
(36.53) | (48.19) | (48.24) | (19.09) | |
1 = Relationship length >3 years | −117.40b | −4.98 | −15.73 | −9.51 |
(46.83) | (60.43) | (64.81) | (33.66) | |
Interest rate difference without matching | ||||
Constant | −30.72 | −163.52c | −239.99c | −259.92c |
(44.40) | (41.13) | (37.23) | (24.99) | |
1 = Relationship length >3 years | −76.17 | −31.30 | 43.72 | −6.77 |
(49.29) | (59.41) | (51.93) | (43.32) | |
Panel D: Only firms that transfer to a bank with no previous relationship ever | ||||
Number of switching/transfer loans | 160 | 48 | 59 | 115 |
Number of non-switching loans | 593 | 216 | 199 | 526 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 696 | 223 | 339 | 672 |
Interest rate difference with matching | −40.48a | 31.90 | −77.55a | −82.05c |
(24.13) | (36.90) | (39.42) | (24.59) | |
Interest rate difference without matching | −49.19a | −164.13c | −181.28c | −225.86c |
(26.81) | (34.22) | (31.37) | (33.91) |
In Panel B, we only consider transfers if they are caused by closure of the branch of the firm’s main lender. It is possible that the impact of branch closure is larger when this is the main bank of the firm. Still, the results are similar to the ones obtained in Table IV. The interest rate spread between the switching loan and similar loans is close to zero and not statistically significant for transfers 1–6 months after the branch closure. There are no interest rate discounts when the main lender closes its branch. It remains statistically not different from zero even in the window that goes beyond 12 months. Assuming that the main lender is the most important one for the firm, these results corroborate the conclusion that the change in soft information explains the existence of interest rate discounts for switching firms.
In Panel C, we further explore the dynamics of the lock-in effects. We examine the (additional) switching and transfer discounts for firms that have long relationships. We find that the switching discounts are more significant for firms with longer relationships (>3 years), thus supporting the existence of lock-in effects. However, in the year after branch closure, the discount vanishes both for shorter and longer relationships, giving further support to the hypothesis that switching discounts are indeed driven by asymmetric information issues.
Finally, we consider a subset of firms that transfer to a bank with whom they never had any previous relationship (Panel D). In our baseline specification, we consider that there is a transfer (or a switch) when a new relationship is established with a bank that did not lend to that firm in the previous 12 months. This implies that we consider that private information about the firm might get stale after 1 year. To be more stringent, we consider only truly new relationships. Once more, the main results are unchanged.
5.4 Other Loan Conditions
Table XV compares loan conditions of transfer or switching loans with loan conditions of comparable non-switching loans using the same matching technology as in Column III of Table IV. Recall that with this matching exercise, we aim to simulate the offered loan conditions as if the firm had not switched to any new outside bank and compare them with the transfer or switching conditions offered by this bank.
Differences in loan conditions on transfer loans and matched non-switching loans given by the outside bank
In Panel A, we assess the difference in each loan condition on transfer loans (i.e., switching loan after the closest branch of the inside bank closes) and the loan condition on new non-switching loans obtained (by other firms) from the switchers’ outside bank. In Panel B, we repeat the analysis of Panel A only for the first transfers after the branch closure. In Panel C, we do the analysis for the remaining later transfers. We match on the indicated variables (similar to the benchmark model in Column III of Table IV). The variables are defined in Table III. Loans for the Panels A–C span between the first and the twelfth month after closure. We regress the difference in each loan condition on a constant and report the coefficient on the constant. We cluster at the switching-firm level and report robust standard errors between parentheses. a, b, and c indicate significance at the 10, 5, and 1% levels, two-tailed.
. | I . | II . | III . | IV . |
---|---|---|---|---|
Rate . | Collateralized loans . | Maturity . | Loan amount . | |
Quarter, bank, credit rating, region, industry, legal structure, and floating loan rate | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Loan rate | Yes | Yes | Yes | |
Collateral | Yes | Yes | Yes | |
Loan maturity | Yes | Yes | Yes | |
Loan amount | Yes | Yes | Yes | |
Panel A: Transfer loans | ||||
Number of transfer loans | 146 | 125 | 158 | 207 |
Number of non-switching loans | 633 | 549 | 856 | 1,736 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 840 | 786 | 1,306 | 2,903 |
Difference in loan conditions (at time of the transfer loan) | −23.34 | −0.08a | −0.46 | −12,365.28 |
(24.40) | (0.05) | (1.52) | (8,804.40) | |
Panel B: First transfers | ||||
Number of first transfer loans | 101 | 87 | 113 | 143 |
Number of non-switching loans | 468 | 403 | 652 | 1,325 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 524 | 495 | 837 | 1,618 |
Difference in loan conditions (at time of the first transfer loan) | 15.68 | −0.09 | −0.96 | −7,630.12 |
(21.44) | (0.06) | (2.10) | (12,179.94) | |
Panel C: Later transfers | ||||
Number of later transfer loans | 45 | 38 | 45 | 64 |
Number of non-switching loans | 205 | 206 | 295 | 560 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 316 | 291 | 469 | 1,285 |
Difference in loan conditions (at time of the later transfer loan) | −110.92b | −0.06 | 0.79 | −22,945.40c |
(45.39) | (0.05) | (1.06) | (7,820.51) |
. | I . | II . | III . | IV . |
---|---|---|---|---|
Rate . | Collateralized loans . | Maturity . | Loan amount . | |
Quarter, bank, credit rating, region, industry, legal structure, and floating loan rate | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Loan rate | Yes | Yes | Yes | |
Collateral | Yes | Yes | Yes | |
Loan maturity | Yes | Yes | Yes | |
Loan amount | Yes | Yes | Yes | |
Panel A: Transfer loans | ||||
Number of transfer loans | 146 | 125 | 158 | 207 |
Number of non-switching loans | 633 | 549 | 856 | 1,736 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 840 | 786 | 1,306 | 2,903 |
Difference in loan conditions (at time of the transfer loan) | −23.34 | −0.08a | −0.46 | −12,365.28 |
(24.40) | (0.05) | (1.52) | (8,804.40) | |
Panel B: First transfers | ||||
Number of first transfer loans | 101 | 87 | 113 | 143 |
Number of non-switching loans | 468 | 403 | 652 | 1,325 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 524 | 495 | 837 | 1,618 |
Difference in loan conditions (at time of the first transfer loan) | 15.68 | −0.09 | −0.96 | −7,630.12 |
(21.44) | (0.06) | (2.10) | (12,179.94) | |
Panel C: Later transfers | ||||
Number of later transfer loans | 45 | 38 | 45 | 64 |
Number of non-switching loans | 205 | 206 | 295 | 560 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 316 | 291 | 469 | 1,285 |
Difference in loan conditions (at time of the later transfer loan) | −110.92b | −0.06 | 0.79 | −22,945.40c |
(45.39) | (0.05) | (1.06) | (7,820.51) |
Differences in loan conditions on transfer loans and matched non-switching loans given by the outside bank
In Panel A, we assess the difference in each loan condition on transfer loans (i.e., switching loan after the closest branch of the inside bank closes) and the loan condition on new non-switching loans obtained (by other firms) from the switchers’ outside bank. In Panel B, we repeat the analysis of Panel A only for the first transfers after the branch closure. In Panel C, we do the analysis for the remaining later transfers. We match on the indicated variables (similar to the benchmark model in Column III of Table IV). The variables are defined in Table III. Loans for the Panels A–C span between the first and the twelfth month after closure. We regress the difference in each loan condition on a constant and report the coefficient on the constant. We cluster at the switching-firm level and report robust standard errors between parentheses. a, b, and c indicate significance at the 10, 5, and 1% levels, two-tailed.
. | I . | II . | III . | IV . |
---|---|---|---|---|
Rate . | Collateralized loans . | Maturity . | Loan amount . | |
Quarter, bank, credit rating, region, industry, legal structure, and floating loan rate | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Loan rate | Yes | Yes | Yes | |
Collateral | Yes | Yes | Yes | |
Loan maturity | Yes | Yes | Yes | |
Loan amount | Yes | Yes | Yes | |
Panel A: Transfer loans | ||||
Number of transfer loans | 146 | 125 | 158 | 207 |
Number of non-switching loans | 633 | 549 | 856 | 1,736 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 840 | 786 | 1,306 | 2,903 |
Difference in loan conditions (at time of the transfer loan) | −23.34 | −0.08a | −0.46 | −12,365.28 |
(24.40) | (0.05) | (1.52) | (8,804.40) | |
Panel B: First transfers | ||||
Number of first transfer loans | 101 | 87 | 113 | 143 |
Number of non-switching loans | 468 | 403 | 652 | 1,325 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 524 | 495 | 837 | 1,618 |
Difference in loan conditions (at time of the first transfer loan) | 15.68 | −0.09 | −0.96 | −7,630.12 |
(21.44) | (0.06) | (2.10) | (12,179.94) | |
Panel C: Later transfers | ||||
Number of later transfer loans | 45 | 38 | 45 | 64 |
Number of non-switching loans | 205 | 206 | 295 | 560 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 316 | 291 | 469 | 1,285 |
Difference in loan conditions (at time of the later transfer loan) | −110.92b | −0.06 | 0.79 | −22,945.40c |
(45.39) | (0.05) | (1.06) | (7,820.51) |
. | I . | II . | III . | IV . |
---|---|---|---|---|
Rate . | Collateralized loans . | Maturity . | Loan amount . | |
Quarter, bank, credit rating, region, industry, legal structure, and floating loan rate | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Loan rate | Yes | Yes | Yes | |
Collateral | Yes | Yes | Yes | |
Loan maturity | Yes | Yes | Yes | |
Loan amount | Yes | Yes | Yes | |
Panel A: Transfer loans | ||||
Number of transfer loans | 146 | 125 | 158 | 207 |
Number of non-switching loans | 633 | 549 | 856 | 1,736 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 840 | 786 | 1,306 | 2,903 |
Difference in loan conditions (at time of the transfer loan) | −23.34 | −0.08a | −0.46 | −12,365.28 |
(24.40) | (0.05) | (1.52) | (8,804.40) | |
Panel B: First transfers | ||||
Number of first transfer loans | 101 | 87 | 113 | 143 |
Number of non-switching loans | 468 | 403 | 652 | 1,325 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 524 | 495 | 837 | 1,618 |
Difference in loan conditions (at time of the first transfer loan) | 15.68 | −0.09 | −0.96 | −7,630.12 |
(21.44) | (0.06) | (2.10) | (12,179.94) | |
Panel C: Later transfers | ||||
Number of later transfer loans | 45 | 38 | 45 | 64 |
Number of non-switching loans | 205 | 206 | 295 | 560 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 316 | 291 | 469 | 1,285 |
Difference in loan conditions (at time of the later transfer loan) | −110.92b | −0.06 | 0.79 | −22,945.40c |
(45.39) | (0.05) | (1.06) | (7,820.51) |
Panel A contains all transfer loans, while Panel B contains first transfers, and Panel C later transfers. Column I reports the results for interest rates, column II for the existence of collateral attached to a loan, Column III for loan maturity, and Column IV for loan amount.
In Panel A, none of the loan conditions are statistically different at the 5% level. Transfers are less likely to be collateralized by eight percentage points, but this result is only statistically significant at the 10% level.
Results are more evident in Panel B because we are only including first transfers. None of the loan conditions are statistically different at the 10% level, indicating that loan transfers and non-switching loans share on average the same loan conditions.
In Panel C, the interest rate of later transfers is lower on average by 111 bps in comparison with non-switching loans. Loan amounts of later loan transfers are on average lower by €22,945. According to Degryse, Kim, and Ongena (2009), relationship borrowers tend to have better access to finance and therefore obtain larger loans than other borrowers that are initiating their relationship with another bank.31 However, we only find this effect for later transfers.
There are no statistically significant differences in loan maturity for transfer loans, even though we find that switching loans have a longer maturity on average (0.63 months). These results are consistent with hold up theories, showing that firms that establish new relationships after a branch closure are not able to reap the benefits usually obtained when switching.
6. The Effects of Branch Closures
We have shown that firms obtain higher interest rates if they establish a new relationship with a bank after a branch of their inside bank closes than they would if this relationship was established in normal conditions. This result allows us to identify the mechanism underlying the well-documented switching discounts in banking, showing that they are anchored to information asymmetries leading to a holdup problem.
The richness of our data and the widespread presence of branch closures allows us to analyze what happens after branches close along several other dimensions that go beyond loan pricing, thus complementing results obtained by De Juan (2003), Cerutti, Dell’Ariccia and Martínez Pería (2007), Coccorese (2012), and recently Allen, Damar, and Martinez-Miera (2016), Brown, Guin, and Kirschenmann (2016), Martin-Oliver (2016), Xu et al. (2018), and Qi et al. (2020).
In Table XVI, we show what happens to firms affected by branch closures in the 12 months after the event occurred. After 1 year, 17% of these firms had obtained loans from a new bank. In the first month after closure, 8% of affected firms established relationships with new banks, compared with 3% for the whole financial system. Some firms continue to borrow from the same bank, despite the closure (7%). However, the vast majority (70%) do not obtain any new bank loan in the 12 months after branch closure. One month after closure, 4% of all affected firms get loans from their incumbent bank, compared with 6% for the whole financial system.
Outcomes for firms that are affected by branch closure
In this table, we look at firms that are affected by the closure of a bank branch. In the first column, we calculate the percentage of firms that get a new loan from a bank other than the bank that closes its branch. In the second column, we show the percentage of firms that get a loan from the bank that closed its branch. In the third column, we show the percentage of firms that get a loan from the bank that closes its branch, as well as from other banks. In the fourth column, we show the percentage of firms that do not get a new loan. Rows represent the number of months passed since the branch closure. Values are cumulative.
Number of months since closure . | % loans other banks . | % loans same bank . | % loans same bank and other banks . | % no new loans . |
---|---|---|---|---|
1 | 7.75 | 2.75 | 1.27 | 88.23 |
2 | 10.33 | 3.53 | 2.17 | 83.97 |
3 | 11.56 | 4.35 | 2.84 | 81.26 |
4 | 13.08 | 4.50 | 3.29 | 79.13 |
5 | 14.20 | 5.06 | 3.62 | 77.13 |
6 | 14.93 | 5.70 | 4.09 | 75.27 |
7 | 15.45 | 5.90 | 4.63 | 74.03 |
8 | 16.05 | 6.09 | 5.06 | 72.80 |
9 | 16.33 | 6.22 | 5.42 | 72.02 |
10 | 16.72 | 6.41 | 5.77 | 71.10 |
11 | 17.06 | 6.46 | 6.22 | 70.26 |
12 | 17.17 | 6.52 | 6.50 | 69.81 |
Financial system (firm-month pairs) | 3.23 | 5.67 | 0.04 | 91.06 |
Number of months since closure . | % loans other banks . | % loans same bank . | % loans same bank and other banks . | % no new loans . |
---|---|---|---|---|
1 | 7.75 | 2.75 | 1.27 | 88.23 |
2 | 10.33 | 3.53 | 2.17 | 83.97 |
3 | 11.56 | 4.35 | 2.84 | 81.26 |
4 | 13.08 | 4.50 | 3.29 | 79.13 |
5 | 14.20 | 5.06 | 3.62 | 77.13 |
6 | 14.93 | 5.70 | 4.09 | 75.27 |
7 | 15.45 | 5.90 | 4.63 | 74.03 |
8 | 16.05 | 6.09 | 5.06 | 72.80 |
9 | 16.33 | 6.22 | 5.42 | 72.02 |
10 | 16.72 | 6.41 | 5.77 | 71.10 |
11 | 17.06 | 6.46 | 6.22 | 70.26 |
12 | 17.17 | 6.52 | 6.50 | 69.81 |
Financial system (firm-month pairs) | 3.23 | 5.67 | 0.04 | 91.06 |
Outcomes for firms that are affected by branch closure
In this table, we look at firms that are affected by the closure of a bank branch. In the first column, we calculate the percentage of firms that get a new loan from a bank other than the bank that closes its branch. In the second column, we show the percentage of firms that get a loan from the bank that closed its branch. In the third column, we show the percentage of firms that get a loan from the bank that closes its branch, as well as from other banks. In the fourth column, we show the percentage of firms that do not get a new loan. Rows represent the number of months passed since the branch closure. Values are cumulative.
Number of months since closure . | % loans other banks . | % loans same bank . | % loans same bank and other banks . | % no new loans . |
---|---|---|---|---|
1 | 7.75 | 2.75 | 1.27 | 88.23 |
2 | 10.33 | 3.53 | 2.17 | 83.97 |
3 | 11.56 | 4.35 | 2.84 | 81.26 |
4 | 13.08 | 4.50 | 3.29 | 79.13 |
5 | 14.20 | 5.06 | 3.62 | 77.13 |
6 | 14.93 | 5.70 | 4.09 | 75.27 |
7 | 15.45 | 5.90 | 4.63 | 74.03 |
8 | 16.05 | 6.09 | 5.06 | 72.80 |
9 | 16.33 | 6.22 | 5.42 | 72.02 |
10 | 16.72 | 6.41 | 5.77 | 71.10 |
11 | 17.06 | 6.46 | 6.22 | 70.26 |
12 | 17.17 | 6.52 | 6.50 | 69.81 |
Financial system (firm-month pairs) | 3.23 | 5.67 | 0.04 | 91.06 |
Number of months since closure . | % loans other banks . | % loans same bank . | % loans same bank and other banks . | % no new loans . |
---|---|---|---|---|
1 | 7.75 | 2.75 | 1.27 | 88.23 |
2 | 10.33 | 3.53 | 2.17 | 83.97 |
3 | 11.56 | 4.35 | 2.84 | 81.26 |
4 | 13.08 | 4.50 | 3.29 | 79.13 |
5 | 14.20 | 5.06 | 3.62 | 77.13 |
6 | 14.93 | 5.70 | 4.09 | 75.27 |
7 | 15.45 | 5.90 | 4.63 | 74.03 |
8 | 16.05 | 6.09 | 5.06 | 72.80 |
9 | 16.33 | 6.22 | 5.42 | 72.02 |
10 | 16.72 | 6.41 | 5.77 | 71.10 |
11 | 17.06 | 6.46 | 6.22 | 70.26 |
12 | 17.17 | 6.52 | 6.50 | 69.81 |
Financial system (firm-month pairs) | 3.23 | 5.67 | 0.04 | 91.06 |
In Table XVII, we look into another dimension of loan pricing. We compare the interest rate of new loans given by inside banks in areas where they close branches against similar loans they give in other areas. Matched loans do not have significantly different interest rates, which goes against the idea that inside banks abandon areas where they close branches. However, when we do not match, interest rates go down considerably 1 year after the branch closure. These results are consistent with banks’ lending to less opaque customers after branch closures.
Spreads between interest rates on loans to firms affected by branch closures and firms not affected by branch closures
We assess the spread between the interest rate on new loans obtained from the transferers’ inside bank when the closest branch of the inside bank closes and other loans that the inside bank gives to firms not affected by branch closures. We match on the variables indicated in Column III of Table IV. All variables are defined in Table III. We regress the spreads on a constant and report the coefficient on the constant. We weigh each observation by one over the total number of comparable loans per loan to an affected firm. We cluster at the switching-firm level and report robust standard errors between parentheses. We also report the difference between the mean interest rate on the loans to affected firms and the mean interest rate on loans to other firms in each column. We report standard errors between parentheses. a, b, and c indicate significance at the 10, 5, and 1% levels, two-tailed.
Period since the branch closure . | Before . | 1–6 months after . | 7–12 months after . | >12 months after . |
---|---|---|---|---|
Number of switching/transfer loans | 10,484 | 5,347 | 1,919 | 4,544 |
Number of non-switching loans | 32,351 | 10,367 | 4,831 | 9,339 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 180,303 | 195,094 | 18,062 | 20,304 |
Interest rate difference with matching | 7.00 | 5.81 | −1.41 | 1.28 |
(0.11) | (0.26) | (0.80) | (0.69) | |
Interest rate difference without matching | 105.15c | −5.38 | 10.94 | −83.62c |
(12.64) | (14.83) | (17.20) | (11.56) |
Period since the branch closure . | Before . | 1–6 months after . | 7–12 months after . | >12 months after . |
---|---|---|---|---|
Number of switching/transfer loans | 10,484 | 5,347 | 1,919 | 4,544 |
Number of non-switching loans | 32,351 | 10,367 | 4,831 | 9,339 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 180,303 | 195,094 | 18,062 | 20,304 |
Interest rate difference with matching | 7.00 | 5.81 | −1.41 | 1.28 |
(0.11) | (0.26) | (0.80) | (0.69) | |
Interest rate difference without matching | 105.15c | −5.38 | 10.94 | −83.62c |
(12.64) | (14.83) | (17.20) | (11.56) |
Spreads between interest rates on loans to firms affected by branch closures and firms not affected by branch closures
We assess the spread between the interest rate on new loans obtained from the transferers’ inside bank when the closest branch of the inside bank closes and other loans that the inside bank gives to firms not affected by branch closures. We match on the variables indicated in Column III of Table IV. All variables are defined in Table III. We regress the spreads on a constant and report the coefficient on the constant. We weigh each observation by one over the total number of comparable loans per loan to an affected firm. We cluster at the switching-firm level and report robust standard errors between parentheses. We also report the difference between the mean interest rate on the loans to affected firms and the mean interest rate on loans to other firms in each column. We report standard errors between parentheses. a, b, and c indicate significance at the 10, 5, and 1% levels, two-tailed.
Period since the branch closure . | Before . | 1–6 months after . | 7–12 months after . | >12 months after . |
---|---|---|---|---|
Number of switching/transfer loans | 10,484 | 5,347 | 1,919 | 4,544 |
Number of non-switching loans | 32,351 | 10,367 | 4,831 | 9,339 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 180,303 | 195,094 | 18,062 | 20,304 |
Interest rate difference with matching | 7.00 | 5.81 | −1.41 | 1.28 |
(0.11) | (0.26) | (0.80) | (0.69) | |
Interest rate difference without matching | 105.15c | −5.38 | 10.94 | −83.62c |
(12.64) | (14.83) | (17.20) | (11.56) |
Period since the branch closure . | Before . | 1–6 months after . | 7–12 months after . | >12 months after . |
---|---|---|---|---|
Number of switching/transfer loans | 10,484 | 5,347 | 1,919 | 4,544 |
Number of non-switching loans | 32,351 | 10,367 | 4,831 | 9,339 |
Number of observations (matched pairs) | 180,303 | 195,094 | 18,062 | 20,304 |
Interest rate difference with matching | 7.00 | 5.81 | −1.41 | 1.28 |
(0.11) | (0.26) | (0.80) | (0.69) | |
Interest rate difference without matching | 105.15c | −5.38 | 10.94 | −83.62c |
(12.64) | (14.83) | (17.20) | (11.56) |
To further explore what happens to firms in terms of access to credit in the aftermath of a branch closure, we also look into credit profile consultations in the Credit Register. When a bank is approached by a new potential customer, the bank can, with the customer’s consent, consult his situation in the Credit Register. In Column I of Table XVIII, we measure the probability that bank i downloads at least one credit profile of firms located in zip code j. The download probability decreases by 1.84 percentage points for banks that close branches1–6 months after branch closure. There is no significant change in the probability of credit profile downloads for other banks.
New loans and credit profile downloads at the bank-zipcode level in transfer areas
Columns I and II are LPMs. In the first column, the dependent variable is equal to 1 if bank i does at least one credit profile download of a firm located in zipcode j. In the second column, the dependent variable is the total amount of new loans given by bank i to firms located in zipcode j. The independent variable “Closing bank” is equal to 1 if zipcode j is at most 5 km away from a closing branch of bank i. We create a categorical variable to classify loan transfers. Categories are: period before the branch closure; 1–6 months after the closure; 7–12 months after the closure; >12 months after the closure. In Column II, we exclude bank–period pairs before December 2014 when smaller banks do not have to report new loans. Only zipcodes with branch closures within 5 km are included. We cluster at the zipcode level and report robust standard errors in parentheses. a, b, and c indicate significance at the 10, 5, and 1% levels, two-tailed.
. | Probability of credit profile downloads . | New loans (EUR thousand) . |
---|---|---|
. | I . | II . |
Closing bank | −0.20 | 3.90 |
(0.47) | (2.45) | |
1–6 months after transfer | 0.15 | 0.11 |
(0.13) | (4.56) | |
7–12 months after transfer | 0.22 | 2.02 |
(0.15) | (6.30) | |
>12 months after transfer | 0.25 | 9.09 |
(0.17) | (9.65) | |
Closing bank a1–6 months after transfer | −1.84b | −5.02 |
(0.76) | (6.59) | |
Closing bank a7–12 months after transfer | −1.76 | 2.17 |
(0.98) | (17.04) | |
Closing bank a>12 months after transfer | −0.66 | −2.82 |
(0.87) | (8.46) | |
Observations | 397,770 | 165,216 |
R2 | 0.1515 | 0.0450 |
Time FE | Yes | Yes |
Location FE | Yes | Yes |
Bank FE | Yes | Yes |
. | Probability of credit profile downloads . | New loans (EUR thousand) . |
---|---|---|
. | I . | II . |
Closing bank | −0.20 | 3.90 |
(0.47) | (2.45) | |
1–6 months after transfer | 0.15 | 0.11 |
(0.13) | (4.56) | |
7–12 months after transfer | 0.22 | 2.02 |
(0.15) | (6.30) | |
>12 months after transfer | 0.25 | 9.09 |
(0.17) | (9.65) | |
Closing bank a1–6 months after transfer | −1.84b | −5.02 |
(0.76) | (6.59) | |
Closing bank a7–12 months after transfer | −1.76 | 2.17 |
(0.98) | (17.04) | |
Closing bank a>12 months after transfer | −0.66 | −2.82 |
(0.87) | (8.46) | |
Observations | 397,770 | 165,216 |
R2 | 0.1515 | 0.0450 |
Time FE | Yes | Yes |
Location FE | Yes | Yes |
Bank FE | Yes | Yes |
New loans and credit profile downloads at the bank-zipcode level in transfer areas
Columns I and II are LPMs. In the first column, the dependent variable is equal to 1 if bank i does at least one credit profile download of a firm located in zipcode j. In the second column, the dependent variable is the total amount of new loans given by bank i to firms located in zipcode j. The independent variable “Closing bank” is equal to 1 if zipcode j is at most 5 km away from a closing branch of bank i. We create a categorical variable to classify loan transfers. Categories are: period before the branch closure; 1–6 months after the closure; 7–12 months after the closure; >12 months after the closure. In Column II, we exclude bank–period pairs before December 2014 when smaller banks do not have to report new loans. Only zipcodes with branch closures within 5 km are included. We cluster at the zipcode level and report robust standard errors in parentheses. a, b, and c indicate significance at the 10, 5, and 1% levels, two-tailed.
. | Probability of credit profile downloads . | New loans (EUR thousand) . |
---|---|---|
. | I . | II . |
Closing bank | −0.20 | 3.90 |
(0.47) | (2.45) | |
1–6 months after transfer | 0.15 | 0.11 |
(0.13) | (4.56) | |
7–12 months after transfer | 0.22 | 2.02 |
(0.15) | (6.30) | |
>12 months after transfer | 0.25 | 9.09 |
(0.17) | (9.65) | |
Closing bank a1–6 months after transfer | −1.84b | −5.02 |
(0.76) | (6.59) | |
Closing bank a7–12 months after transfer | −1.76 | 2.17 |
(0.98) | (17.04) | |
Closing bank a>12 months after transfer | −0.66 | −2.82 |
(0.87) | (8.46) | |
Observations | 397,770 | 165,216 |
R2 | 0.1515 | 0.0450 |
Time FE | Yes | Yes |
Location FE | Yes | Yes |
Bank FE | Yes | Yes |
. | Probability of credit profile downloads . | New loans (EUR thousand) . |
---|---|---|
. | I . | II . |
Closing bank | −0.20 | 3.90 |
(0.47) | (2.45) | |
1–6 months after transfer | 0.15 | 0.11 |
(0.13) | (4.56) | |
7–12 months after transfer | 0.22 | 2.02 |
(0.15) | (6.30) | |
>12 months after transfer | 0.25 | 9.09 |
(0.17) | (9.65) | |
Closing bank a1–6 months after transfer | −1.84b | −5.02 |
(0.76) | (6.59) | |
Closing bank a7–12 months after transfer | −1.76 | 2.17 |
(0.98) | (17.04) | |
Closing bank a>12 months after transfer | −0.66 | −2.82 |
(0.87) | (8.46) | |
Observations | 397,770 | 165,216 |
R2 | 0.1515 | 0.0450 |
Time FE | Yes | Yes |
Location FE | Yes | Yes |
Bank FE | Yes | Yes |
In Column II of Table XVIII, we look at new loan volume given by bank i in zip code j. There is no significant change in loan volume either for banks that close branches or for other banks, thus suggesting that there are no major additional contractions in credit supply coming from the banks that are closing down branches.
In Table XIX, Column I shows the evolution of the number of firms with credit profile downloads and Column II the change in the volume of new loans. Here we aggregate credit profile downloads and new loans at the zip code level, and not at the zip code-bank level, in order to understand what happens locally. These two variables do not seem to change much after branch closures. In Table XX, we report the probability that firms affected by a branch closure to get a new loan after that event, compared to the probability they recorded before closure. The results confirm that nothing changed in a significant way.
New loans and credit profile downloads at the zipcode level in transfer areas
Columns I and II are LPMs. In the first column, the dependent variable is the number of firms with credit profile downloads in month i and zipcode j. In the second column, the dependent variable is the total amount of new loans given to firms located in zipcode j in month i. We create a categorical variable to classify loan transfers. Categories are: period before the branch closure; 1–6 months after the closure; 7–12 months after the closure; >12 months after the closure. In Column II, we exclude banks that do not have to report new loans before December 2014. Only zipcodes with branch closures within 5 km are included. We cluster at the zipcode level and report robust standard errors in parentheses. a, b, and c indicate significance at the 10, 5, and 1% levels, two-tailed.
. | Number of firms with credit profile downloads . | New loans (EUR thousand) . |
---|---|---|
. | I . | II . |
1–6 months after transfer | 0.92 | −25.41 |
(1.54) | (48.31) | |
7–12 months after transfer | 0.60 | −6.68 |
(2.05) | (95.42) | |
>12 months after transfer | 3.23 | −79.61 |
(2.50) | (115.00) | |
Observations | 12,544 | 12,544 |
R2 | 0.8930 | 0.4008 |
Time FE | Yes | Yes |
Location FE | Yes | Yes |
. | Number of firms with credit profile downloads . | New loans (EUR thousand) . |
---|---|---|
. | I . | II . |
1–6 months after transfer | 0.92 | −25.41 |
(1.54) | (48.31) | |
7–12 months after transfer | 0.60 | −6.68 |
(2.05) | (95.42) | |
>12 months after transfer | 3.23 | −79.61 |
(2.50) | (115.00) | |
Observations | 12,544 | 12,544 |
R2 | 0.8930 | 0.4008 |
Time FE | Yes | Yes |
Location FE | Yes | Yes |
New loans and credit profile downloads at the zipcode level in transfer areas
Columns I and II are LPMs. In the first column, the dependent variable is the number of firms with credit profile downloads in month i and zipcode j. In the second column, the dependent variable is the total amount of new loans given to firms located in zipcode j in month i. We create a categorical variable to classify loan transfers. Categories are: period before the branch closure; 1–6 months after the closure; 7–12 months after the closure; >12 months after the closure. In Column II, we exclude banks that do not have to report new loans before December 2014. Only zipcodes with branch closures within 5 km are included. We cluster at the zipcode level and report robust standard errors in parentheses. a, b, and c indicate significance at the 10, 5, and 1% levels, two-tailed.
. | Number of firms with credit profile downloads . | New loans (EUR thousand) . |
---|---|---|
. | I . | II . |
1–6 months after transfer | 0.92 | −25.41 |
(1.54) | (48.31) | |
7–12 months after transfer | 0.60 | −6.68 |
(2.05) | (95.42) | |
>12 months after transfer | 3.23 | −79.61 |
(2.50) | (115.00) | |
Observations | 12,544 | 12,544 |
R2 | 0.8930 | 0.4008 |
Time FE | Yes | Yes |
Location FE | Yes | Yes |
. | Number of firms with credit profile downloads . | New loans (EUR thousand) . |
---|---|---|
. | I . | II . |
1–6 months after transfer | 0.92 | −25.41 |
(1.54) | (48.31) | |
7–12 months after transfer | 0.60 | −6.68 |
(2.05) | (95.42) | |
>12 months after transfer | 3.23 | −79.61 |
(2.50) | (115.00) | |
Observations | 12,544 | 12,544 |
R2 | 0.8930 | 0.4008 |
Time FE | Yes | Yes |
Location FE | Yes | Yes |
Probability of getting a new loan
This table measures the probability of getting a new loan for firms affected by branch closures. We create a categorical variable to classify loan transfers. Categories are: period before the branch closure; 1–6 months after the closure; 7–12 months after the closure; >12 months after the closure. We cluster at the firm level and report robust standard errors in parentheses. a, b, and c indicate significance at the 10, 5, and 1% levels, two-tailed.
. | (1) . |
---|---|
Firm affected by closure, 1–6 months after closure | 0.28 |
(0.18) | |
Firm affected by closure, 7–12 months after closure | 0.25 |
(0.22) | |
Firm affected by closure, >12 months after closure | −0.01 |
(0.27) | |
Observations | 8,335,618 |
R2 | 41.24% |
Time FE | Yes |
Firm FE | Yes |
. | (1) . |
---|---|
Firm affected by closure, 1–6 months after closure | 0.28 |
(0.18) | |
Firm affected by closure, 7–12 months after closure | 0.25 |
(0.22) | |
Firm affected by closure, >12 months after closure | −0.01 |
(0.27) | |
Observations | 8,335,618 |
R2 | 41.24% |
Time FE | Yes |
Firm FE | Yes |
Probability of getting a new loan
This table measures the probability of getting a new loan for firms affected by branch closures. We create a categorical variable to classify loan transfers. Categories are: period before the branch closure; 1–6 months after the closure; 7–12 months after the closure; >12 months after the closure. We cluster at the firm level and report robust standard errors in parentheses. a, b, and c indicate significance at the 10, 5, and 1% levels, two-tailed.
. | (1) . |
---|---|
Firm affected by closure, 1–6 months after closure | 0.28 |
(0.18) | |
Firm affected by closure, 7–12 months after closure | 0.25 |
(0.22) | |
Firm affected by closure, >12 months after closure | −0.01 |
(0.27) | |
Observations | 8,335,618 |
R2 | 41.24% |
Time FE | Yes |
Firm FE | Yes |
. | (1) . |
---|---|
Firm affected by closure, 1–6 months after closure | 0.28 |
(0.18) | |
Firm affected by closure, 7–12 months after closure | 0.25 |
(0.22) | |
Firm affected by closure, >12 months after closure | −0.01 |
(0.27) | |
Observations | 8,335,618 |
R2 | 41.24% |
Time FE | Yes |
Firm FE | Yes |
Taken together, these results suggest that branch closures in Portugal in the analyzed period did not lead to local credit crunches. Our main results also show that these firms borrow from inside banks at rates that are not statistically different from the average interest rate granted by those banks. These outcomes possibly reflect the fact that despite a large number of closures, branch density in Portugal continues to rank among the highest in the world. This makes us even more confident that the results on loan pricing are driven by asymmetric information issues rather than by changes in local competition.
7. Conclusion
Using comprehensive data from Portuguese bank branch closures and new loans granted between 2012 and 2015, we study how inside information affects loan conditions. The interest rate on loans that firms obtain following the closure of the branch of their “inside” bank—so, when transferring to a branch of another bank in the same vicinity—is not different from the interest rate on non-switching loans. At the same time, and consistent with previous findings in the literature, we find that switching loans carry interest rates that are on average sixty-three bps lower than those of non-switching loans. These findings suggest that firms incur a loss by foregoing a discount when their bank branch closes.
Later transfers (so, not the first following the branch closure) again enjoy statistically significant interest rate discounts, as do within-bank transfers to other (potentially far-flung) branches. We also observe that transfers are associated with lower loan defaults if we compare them with regular switches.
The main contribution of our article is to show that the interest rate discounts that a firm typically obtains when establishing a relationship with a new bank vanish if these new matches are forged in the aftermath of the closure of a branch that was providing the firm’s financing. This is consistent with theories of holdup in banking, suggesting that branch closure (at least partially) destroys the information captured by the inside banks. These results still hold even when considering a large variety of factors that may cause such behavior.
We also analyze the local impact of branch closures. Firms borrow more from other banks following a closure, and banks that close branches tend to lend to more informationally transparent firms. However, on aggregate, there are no significant differences in terms of interest rates, levels of monitoring, or loan volumes. Despite the large number of branch closures and the immediate consequences for loan pricing for firms that establish new relationships, there are no scarring effects in terms of access to credit. That said, the branch closures in question did not significantly change the local banking landscape, as the figure for branches per capita remained among the highest in the world. This implies that over-branching can be successfully dealt with without compromising small businesses’ access to credit.
Footnotes
Seminal work by Jayaratne and Strahan (1996), Jayaratne and Strahan (1998), and Kroszner and Strahan (1999) led to a very large literature investigating the impact of bank branch deregulation and resultant bank branch dynamics on local finance and economic growth.
Event studies of the impact of bank distress and/or merger announcements on borrowing firms’ stock prices also contain evidence of the value of bank relationships and hence the existence of informational switching costs (e.g., Slovin, Sushka, and Polonchek, 1993; Ongena, Smith, and Michalsen, 2003; Karceski, Ongena, and Smith, 2005; Miyajima and Yafeh, 2007). Complementary to event studies are methods that investigate the long-term performance of firms whose banks are affected by distress or default (e.g., Kang and Stulz, 2000; Gan, 2007; Nakashima and Takahashi, 2018); for a review, see Degryse, Kim, and Ongena (2009). All these studies are at the bank, not bank branch, level, and none analyze the impact on loan conditions.
As in the transfer loan analysis this is contemporaneously compared to similar non-switchers. It is by now well documented that firms receive a lower interest rate when they switch from one bank to another. Ioannidou and Ongena (2010), for example, document an average discount of 89 bps when firms switch banks in Bolivia, Barone, Felici, and Pagnini (2011) find an average discount of 44 bps in Italy, while Stein (2015) finds an average discount for main bank borrowers of 33 bps in Germany. However, this existing work has not yet fully settled empirically which factors cause such discounts. Other papers explore the impact of relationship duration on loan rates and other loan contract terms. Overall the evidence in this literature is rather mixed; see Kysucky and Norden (2016) for a recent meta-analysis of some of these findings. In contrast to this literature, we study firms and bank branches over a relevant period of time, identify transfers and switches, and study the loan conditions associated with transferring and switching by comparing the loan conditions on transfer and switching loans to the conditions on similar non-switching loans.
As indicated later we re-run all main specifications reported below using only the period until December 2014 but results are virtually unaffected.
Given all this information and the zero minimum loan size, the combined database is consequently even more comprehensive than many credit registers that have been studied and that have nonzero reporting thresholds, such as the registers from Bolivia (e.g., Ioannidou and Ongena, 2010; Berger, Frame, and Ioannidou, 2011; Ioannidou, Ongena, and Peydró, 2015), Italy (e.g., Ippolito et al., 2016), or Spain (e.g., Jiménez, Salas, and Saurina, 2006; Jiménez et al., 2012; Jiménez et al., 2014).
Limiting “the amount of data made available for distribution to the financial institutions to the current month” is common in many countries including Portugal (see Miller (2003), Table 1A.7, Column 3). Administrative costs and regulatory objectives may explain the short information-sharing window. A 2-month window seems too short to achieve optimal memory loss à la Vercammen (1995).
For further details, please see for example the Press Release on July 24 2013, by the European Commission on “State aid: Commission finalizes discussions on restructuring plans for Portuguese banks CGD, Banco BPI, BCP.”
As explained in Appendix A: Informational Holdup Theory, across many models in this literature inside banks are banks that have acquired information about the firm, while outside banks concurrently lack this information.
As in other countries (e.g., Petersen and Rajan, 2002; Degryse and Ongena, 2005; Agarwal and Hauswald, 2010) most firms in Portugal engage banks in the vicinity. About 78% of the firms employ at least one bank that has branches in the same postal zone as the firm while 63% firms engage only banks that have a branch there. The median distance between a firm and a bank is 1.9 km. For radii of 10 km estimates are qualitatively similar but based on seemingly more noisy information.
Throughout our analysis we consider only single closures. If there are multiple closures affecting a firm at the same time, we drop them from the sample. This only affects 5% of our initial observations. Most multiple closures occur in the largest cities, where our definition of transfers rarely applies, as there are often other branches of the same bank nearby.
Empirical findings suggest that a substantial portion of the bank’s inside information is collected during the first year (Cole, 1998). As we show later, our estimates for the switching spread are similar to theirs, so we consider 12 months as appropriate.
We observe that differentiating between “adders” and “movers” based on whether they have or do not have other outstanding loans at the time of the switch does not necessarily provide a meaningful distinction. Adders could be classified as movers if, at the time of the switch, their inside loans expired and were not renewed until after they got a loan from an outside bank. Similarly, movers could be classified as adders if their inside loans happened to expire a few months after the switch. It is therefore hard to develop a meaningful classification without relying on future (but possibly endogenous) information. That is, firms may decide to reverse their initial decisions, depending on future offers they receive from both the inside and outside banks. We also believe that investigating the conditions under which a firm obtains a loan from another bank (and not from an existing lender that remains operational or closes its branch) is the most pertinent question. It is correct that adding versus moving a relationship may be a meaningful distinction for de novo firms (Farinha and Santos, 2002) or for firms that switch following bank mergers (Degryse, Masschelein, and Mitchell, 2011). As we analyze only firms that had an inside bank, de novo firms are unlikely to play an important role in our sample. While bank mergers do not affect results in the sample period, our analysis is indeed focused on differentiating between switching and transferring following local branch closures.
From the 94,281 firms that obtained at least one new loan, 16,568 switched at least once, representing 17.6% of our sample, or 5.9%/year. Results are similar to the previous literature about bank switching, which is summarized by Degryse, Kim, and Ongena (2009). Farinha and Santos (2002) for example also find that 64% of 1,577 Portuguese de novo firms in their sample switch between 1980 and 1996, that is, ∼3.7% of their sample switches in a year. Nevertheless, this calculation underestimates the annual percentage of switches in their sample because not all relationships last from 1980 to 1996.
But also in this application we can view the performed matching as “a tool for making the regression more effective” (Angrist and Pischke, 2008), by balancing the two groups so that we are obtaining an average treatment effect.
While banks differ in some of their characteristics, their business model is quite homogenous. They are all universal banks, with a predominance of retail activities targeted at customers all over the country. Moreover, we are controlling for time invariant bank characteristics by matching with outside bank loans.
The credit rating is attributed by the Banco de Portugal using an internal credit scoring model. For details see Antunes, Gonçalves, and Prego (2016).
Most studies assume that the collateral and maturity decisions are taken either independently or sequentially after the loan-granting decision but before the determination of the loan rate. Ignoring the joint character of the loan decision may bias the findings (e.g., Berger et al., 2005; Brick and Palia, 2007; Ortiz-Molina and Penas, 2008). By matching on collateral and loan maturity, we do not need to assume anything about the decision process. Most studies also ignore loan fees (exceptions are Hao, 2003 and Berg, Saunders, and Steffen, 2016) and the pricing implications of cross-selling (Liberti, 2004). By matching on time, bank, type of loan, and loan characteristics, we control for loan fees and cross-selling (assuming banks at the same point in time apply the same fees and cross-selling practices to similar loans and borrowers with similar relationship characteristics). Matching is nonparametric and does not incorporate information from outside the overlap region between the treatment and control groups. At this stage it is also worth recalling that these matching strategies make loans similar in all these dimensions at the same time, equivalent to controlling with a dense set of fully “multiplicative” fixed effects (without the linear functional form constraint).
The descriptive statistics reported in Table I show that observably bad borrowers are less likely to switch.
If we also cluster at the industry-region level, the main results remain unchanged.
To make our setup directly comparable to extant work, we estimate the spreads for all switching loans, that is, no longer conditioning on a branch closure. We find an estimated coefficient of −122, significant at the 1% level. We report this and other estimates in Table IV in Internet Appendix 0.
By using this additional matching variable, the number of observations used in the estimation decreases from 6,249 to 3,735. Different matching choices will condition the number of observations in each estimation. This is not dissimilar to the change in the number of observations underpinning identification in a panel setting with varying high-dimensional fixed effects.
In this estimation, we also match on the length of relationship. This might be important if we consider that a long lasting bank–firm relationship allows the inside bank to collect more private information on the firm. Nevertheless, the results are not sensitive to this choice.
We cannot find evidence that there are significant differences in pricing behavior toward good and bad quality firms, which could suggest that distance does not deteriorate the informational signal.
According to the International Monetary Fund Financial Access Survey Portugal had fifty four commercial bank branches per 100,000 adults in 2014, while France, Germany and Italy had 38, 15, and 60, respectively.
In the Internet Appendix: Data we provide summary statistics on banks and branches at the municipality level.
One may be concerned about the incidental parameters problem in the probit specification. Note however that the number of months covered in the sample is relatively high (forty three) and that we do not include firm fixed-effects. The dummies we include in the model (e.g., bank dummies) are equal to one for many observations.
Various dimensions of bank–firm relationships are found to be associated with salient features of firm financing and performance (e.g., Brunner and Krahnen, 2008; Degryse, Kim, and Ongena, 2009).
In most informational holdup models (and to facilitate theoretical interpretation) all granted loans are of unit size, making these findings that are indeed seemingly inconsistent with such models not entirely straightforward to interpret.
We thank an anonymous editor and referee and Frederic Boissay, Chiara Canta, Paula Cruz-García, Roberta de Filippis, Michał Kowalik, Walter Novaes, Tommaso Oliviero, and John Wilson as discussants. For many helpful comments, we thank Manuel Adelino, Rui Albuquerque, Allen Berger, Marcello Bofondi, Geraldo Cerqueiro, Iftekhar Hasan, Olivier de Jonghe, Artashes Karapetyan, Michael Koetter, David Martinez-Miera, Lars Norden, Andrea Presbitero, Diane Pierret, Amiyatosh Purnanandam (the editor), Kasper Roszbach, Farzad Saidi, Anthony Saunders, Amit Seru, Johannes Stroebel, Victoria Vanasco, Ernst-Ludwig von Thadden, conference participants at the Annual Congress of the European Economic Association Meetings (Geneva), the Annual Conference of the European Association for Research in Industrial Economics (Lisbon), the Financial Intermediation Research Society Conference (Barcelona), Danmarks Nationalbank Conference on the Use of Credit Register Data for Financial Stability Purposes and Credit Risk Analysis (Copenhagen), the sixth CInSt Banking Workshop “Banking in Emerging Markets” (Moscow), the fifth EBA Research Workshop (London), the fourth Paris Financial Management Conference (Paris), the tenth Swiss Winter Conference on Financial Intermediation (Lenzerheide), the sixth MoFiR Workshop on Banking (London), the third Annual Chicago Financial Institutions Conference (Chicago), the tenth Luso-Brazilian Finance Meeting (Ponta Delgada), the 21st Annual FMA European Conference (Lisbon), the NHH Workshop on Competition and Stability in the Banking Market (Bergen), the Fordham Financial Markets Workshop (New York), the 25th International Rome Conference on Money Banking and Finance (Rome), the sixth International Conference of the Financial Engineering and Banking Society (Malaga), the International Finance and Banking Society 2018 Conference (Porto), the MMF-EFiC 2018 Conference in Banking, Finance and Financial Econometrics (Essex), and seminar participants at the Bank of Finland, Barcelona Graduate School of Economics, BI Norwegian Business School, Hong Kong University of Science and Technology, KU Leuven, Maastricht University, Nanyang Technological University, Singapore Management University, Sveriges Riksbank, and the Universities of Nottingham and Padova. The paper previously circulated under the title “`Sorry, We're Closed` Loan Conditions When Bank Branches Close and Firms Transfer to Another Bank.” These are our views and do not necessarily reflect those of the BdP or the Eurosystem. We thank João Guerreiro for excellent research assistance and Dave Brooks (at elcs.ch) for excellent editorial support. Bonfim acknowledges financial support from grants UID/GES/00407/2013 and PTDC/EGE-OGE/30314/2017 of the Portuguese Foundation for Science and Technology-FCT, and Ongena acknowledges financial support from grant ERC ADG 2016 - GA 740272 lending from the European Research Council.
To keep the set of financial institutions homogeneous in terms of financial structure and regulation, we focus on loans from commercial banks and exclude loans from other formal nonbank institutions (such as private financial funds, credit unions, mutual societies, etc.). Most commercial banks are privately owned. Banks are also prohibited from owning nonfinancial firms (Barth, Caprio, and Levine, 2006). The sample period is characterized by an economic recession. The average growth rate of real Gross Domestic Product is −0.8%, somewhat lower than the average −0.03% growth rate of the previous 5 years.
Hence the incidence of collateral is fairly low and even (fully) collateralized loans may still carry a positive loss in the event of default—a prerequisite for informational holdup models to be applicable.
As indicated later, removing these two regions from our sample will not affect our main findings.
Our discussion adjusts Ioannidou and Ongena (2010) to our setting. Boot (2000), Ongena and Smith (2000), Berger and Udell (2002), Elyasiani and Goldberg (2004), Degryse and Ongena (2008), Degryse, Kim, and Ongena (2009), Degryse, Ioannidou, and Ongena (2015), Duqi, Tomaselli, and Torluccio (2018), and Degryse, Morales-Acevedo, and Ongena (2019), among others, review this literature.
Holdup costs are also present in Rajan (1992), since in his model the bank has the power to withdraw financing when it perceives the firm to be inadequately managed. This degree of control can be costly because it reduces the incentives of the firm manager to exert effort. In Hauswald and Marquez (2003), the informational advantage is differentiated across banks. See also Egli, Ongena, and Smith (2006), Black (2011), and Karapetyan and Stacescu (2014).
Recall that the pooling rate in the first period is lower than the fair rate if competing banks expect to extract informational rents in the second period. Simulations of von Thadden (2004) in Ioannidou and Ongena (2010), Internet Appendix II, show that the difference between the average loan rate on all loans granted (in the second period) and the average pooling rate (in the first period) will be one quarter of the difference between accepted and offered loan rates for switchers and one third of the difference between switchers and stayers when matching on firm quality. Put differently, in von Thadden (2004) the discount on transfer loans (in the first period) will be less than one third of the size of the discount on switching loans (in the second period). We confirm and robustify these findings with further simulations for this paper.
While the pool-pricing of transfer loans should in principle be unaffected by the organizational characteristics of the closing branch, the pricing of switching loans can be affected by the organization of the inside bank. Loan officers at decentralized banks for example may be more incentivized to collect and use soft information (Stein, 2002) that may be more private in nature than the hard information employed to price loans in centralized banks. The discount received when switching from a decentralized bank will then be steeper. See also Degryse, Laeven, and Ongena (2009). For this and other Internet Appendices we also re-calculate all estimates for switching loans unconditional on branch closure, that is, the equivalent of Internet Appendix 0, Table A0 IV. Findings are consistent and available upon request (or can be found in earlier versions of the paper on the internet).
The mean HHI is 1,423 and the median is 1,250. According to the guidelines of the US Department of Justice, a market in which the HHI is between 1,500 and 2,500 is considered to be moderately concentrated, and markets in which the HHI is in excess of 2,500 points are considered highly concentrated.
In a further robustness exercise, we consider only transfers in which the HHI of the inside bank does not decrease by >25 points. The results remain valid.
In one specific date, one bank reports a large number of loans to the same firm. We believe that this might have been a reporting error. Because it is impossible for us to reject this conjecture, we repeat the analysis without these loans. The results are qualitatively the same. We opted to maintain these loans in the dataset to maintain its integrity.
Appendix A: Informational Holdup Theory
What happens when firms have to change banks and establish new relationships? We start from a literature in which it is conjectured that a bank’s ability to privately and recurrently observe proprietary information about its customer during a relationship can be beneficial to the customer, but it can also impose certain costs.32 A credit relationship can foster flexibility in writing loan contracts (Boot and Thakor, 1994; von Thadden, 1995) and can increase access to capital at a lower cost and/or with less collateral. In addition, banks may smooth interest rates and reschedule capital payments to help their customers overcome financial difficulties (Chemmanur and Fulghieri, 1994). A relationship with a reputable institution may also facilitate current and future funding from both shareholders and alternative outside sources (Diamond, 1991). Finally, the confidentiality of a relationship may facilitate screening and monitoring (Campbell, 1979) and prevent the leakage of proprietary information to product market competitors (Bhattacharya and Chiesa, 1995; Yosha, 1995).
Access to private information about a borrower could also lead to holdup problems, however, and to the extraction of informational rents. In Sharpe (1990), the incumbent bank has the ability to extract rents from its best customers by “holding up” customers from receiving competitive financing elsewhere.33 The incumbent “inside” bank gains this monopoly power through its informational advantage over the other “outside” banks. If a high quality or “good” borrower tries to switch to a new, uninformed bank, it gets pooled with low quality or “bad” firms and is offered a higher loan rate. And, in the model proposed by von Thadden (2004) following Sharpe (1990) and Rajan (1992), outside banks will optimally randomize loan rates to attract firms that have the same observed characteristics but in the end at best break even in terms of profits. From his model, three hypotheses are empirically verifiable:
(H1) Firms will switch banks, from one period to the next.
(H2) Loans to new applicants will obtain similar interest rates compared to non-switching loans if the inside bank (or any other bank) is known not to have private information about the specific firm, which is the case with “pooling” in the first period of the model.
(H3) Switching loans have lower interest rates than non-switching loans if the inside bank is known to have collected private information about the firm, which is the case with “poaching” in the second period of the model.
The second hypothesis describes the pricing that occurs in its first period of the model and this scenario may arise if a branch of the inside bank closes and all its firms have to transfer; outside banks will then pool-price the arriving firms. In essence, the third hypothesis summarizes the differential pricing of switchers and non-switchers in the second period in von Thadden (2004).34 It is in the careful comparison of the differential pricing in these two situations that resides the contribution of our article.
von Thadden (2004) also contains predictions with respect to the quality of switchers. Higher quality firms are less likely to switch because incumbent banks seek to retain them; still von Thadden (2004) expects that a mixture of good and bad firms will switch. The fourth testable hypothesis is therefore:
(H4) Both low- and high-quality firms switch banks, but low-quality firms switch more proportionally than high-quality firms.
In sum, inside banks charge good borrowers loan rates that are higher than warranted by their true quality (were it publicly known). The more severe the informational asymmetries (e.g., the stronger the bank–firm relationship), the higher the informational rents. Banking models that incorporate holdup are founded on two key assumptions:
(A1) Relationships mitigate informational asymmetries between firms and banks.
(A2) Relationships create informational asymmetries between inside and outside banks that are alleviated by observable firm information.
Information asymmetry is not a necessary condition for switching discounts. Klemperer (1987) discusses that in oligopolistic markets with switching costs banks have incentives to provide introductory offers to capture rents when there are repeated interactions with firms, even when both incumbent and entrant banks have the same information about the firm.
The suboptimal closure of bank branches within a short time frame provides the quasi-ideal setting to understand how these theories and hypotheses shape the commonly observed switching discounts.
Appendix B: Robustness of Empirical Findings
In this Appendix, we report on many alterations of the exercises presented in the article. We report the estimates in the Supplementary Appendix that comes with a table of contents that indicate the Supplementary Appendix Number, the issue addressed, the analysis done, and its operationalization. Overall, the many estimates show robustness and consistency of interpretation in the article.
Appendix B.1 Changes in Local Competition
To ensure that our estimates are not driven by changes in competition we analyze areas where the hypothetical closure of a branch should have a negligible impact on competition.35 For that purpose, we calculate the impact of each branch closure in our data set on the local HHI (for a radius of 5 km around the closure and an HHI calculated based on branch presence). In Supplementary Appendix 1, we re-do Tables V–VII for firms served by branches that witness a minor change in HHI which is less than twenty-five (which is a few points below the median change on a scale of 0–10,000; see Supplementary Appendix 1 and Figure 1).36 These are the areas in which closing a branch should have the smallest impact on competition (Supplementary Appendix 1). Figure 2 shows the variation in branch density per municipality.
We obtain the same conclusions as before. There is an interest rate discount for loan switches, which varies between 59 and 122 bps, and this discount does not exist for transfers and first transfers 1–6 months after the branch closure. These estimates imply that our findings so far are robust across different levels in the intensity of competition.37
In the Supplementary Appendix 2, we use only small banks within highly competitive areas. If discounts still exist in high competition areas for small banks that have arguably no market power, then it is unlikely that discounts are being generated by an increase in competition after branch closure. Our results are broadly consistent with what we had before, thus providing further evidence that changes in competition do not play a role in our story.
To be sure that the effect on interest rates is not being driven by changes in local competition, we explicitly control for changes in the HHI (Supplementary Appendix 3). We compute the change in HHI between month t−1 and t using the number of branches within a 5 km radius. We include a quadratic effect as well, to consider potential non-linearities. The change in HHI has a positive concave effect on the spread between transfer and switching loans only in the 7–12 months window. A decrease in competition increases loan interest rates 7–12 months after the branch closure. However, our main results for transfer firms remain unchanged.
Appendix B.2 Firm Quality
In our baseline results, one of the matching variables used is firms’ credit rating. As indicated before, this allows us to be sure that potential pricing differences are not attributable to differences in perceived risk. Nevertheless, it is interesting to dig deeper into this issue and examine if switching and transfer outcomes are similar for good and bad quality firms. This is even more relevant if we recall that one of our aims is to test the informational holdup models, which predict that because of adverse selection, a higher proportion of switching firms is worse-off in terms of unobservable risk characteristics than if the firms had been randomly drawn from the population (which resembles more the branch closure situation that generated the transfer loans).
In Supplementary Appendices 4 and 5, we do a sample split of firms according to their credit rating. In Appendix 4, we use firms that have a probability of default below the median and in Appendix 5, we use firms with a probability of default above the median. We replicate Table V in both appendices and find the same results for the two groups. Apparently, it is not the differences in credit ratings that drive our main results. Interestingly, we observe that better quality firms have larger switching discounts.
Appendix B.3 Matching Strategies
To be sure that our results are as robust as possible to different matching strategies, in Supplementary Appendices 6–12, we re-run Table V with different matching variables.
In Supplementary Appendix 6, we match switching loans on county instead of the province and obtain similar interest rate discounts for switching loans. We also do not find statistically significant interest rate discounts for loan transfers 1–6 months after the branch closure.
In Supplementary Appendix 7, we match on branch density (number of branches in the county per 1,000 adults) and find similar results for switching discounts and loan transfer discounts 1–6 months after the branch closure. Results from Supplementary Appendices 6 and 7 address remaining concerns that our baseline results are driven by differences between the regions of the switching loans and the regions of the matching loans.
In Supplementary Appendix 8, we create a categorical variable that classifies firms as being micro-sized, small, medium-sized, or large. We create this classification using the guidelines defined in the EU recommendation 2003/361. We use this variable as an additional matching variable, replicate Table V, and arrive at qualitatively similar conclusions.
To further push our matching strategy in Supplementary Appendix 9, we report the results of a much stricter approach. Instead of matching transfer firms with non-switching loans, we match transfer firms with switching firms arriving at the same bank. This means that we are comparing two firms that establish a new relationship with the same bank at the same time, sharing a number of similar characteristics. The only observable difference is that one firm is switching likely because the closest branch of its former bank closed, while the other is switching due to an endogenous choice. The results suggest that there are no discernable differences in the interest rates offered by a bank to these two types of firms, which are switching for different reasons, neither before nor immediately after the branch closure. Transfer loans are indeed somewhat more expensive, as we would expect, 7–12 months after the branch closure. However, we should emphasize that these results are based on a very small number of observations (twelve matched pairs in the 6 months after closure and nine matched pairs between 7 and 12 months).
In order to increase the number of observations, we loosen the matching strategy along a few dimensions, namely collateral, legal structure of the firms and fixed versus floating interest rates (Supplementary Appendix 10). We still have a very reduced number of observations (nineteen pairs in the 6 months after closure). The results are slightly stronger than in Supplementary Appendix 9, but they are overall similar.
To be fully transparent on the impacts of our matching strategy, in Supplementary Appendix 11, we show our results for transfer loans when we exclude one matching variable at a time. The results are remarkably consistent, with only two exceptions: when we do not match by province or by loan amount, we also observe statistically significant discounts on transfer loans in the 6 months following a branch closure. However, there may exist important differences between provinces or firms asking for significantly different loan amounts that make these controls especially relevant.
One final test on the matching strategy is to use a propensity score matching algorithm instead of the coarsened exact matching strategy (Supplementary Appendix 12). The propensity score matching is a different matching strategy (e.g., Rosenbaum and Rubin, 1983) because it relies on matching similar firms instead of firms that share exactly the same characteristics. The trade-off is that we are able to increase the number of matches (e.g., Stuart, 2010). Despite the methodological and sample differences, the results on transfer loans are entirely consistent.
Appendix B.4 Other Robustness
In Supplementary Appendices 13–22, we go on to further test the robustness of our findings for other dimensions. First, we analyze sub-samples of our dataset and revisit two earlier mentioned issues, pertaining to the sample period and geographical area covered by our study.
In Supplementary Appendix 13, we replicate Tables IV and V excluding the period starting in December 2014 after which all banks had to report loan rates.
In Supplementary Appendix 14, we exclude Lisbon and Porto, large cities where many closures occurred yet distances may play a different role than elsewhere due to branch density. In both cases, our findings are most similar.
In Supplementary Appendix 15, we include the month of the branch closure and the month before the branch closure in the post-transfer period, that is, we assume that in the month before the branch closure firms already act as if the branch of the incumbent bank has been closed. With this assumption, we obtain similar results for transfers.
To be sure that the results are not driven by a few special loans, we consider a subsample where we take only branch closures that lead to more than ten transfers (Supplementary Appendix 16). We still obtain an average positive but non-significant interest rate differential 1–6 months after closure.
Another potentially relevant issue is that firms are not forced to search for a new relationship immediately after their branch closes. Even though that will likely be the case in most situations, as firms often interact with banks to have access to a variety of services that go beyond bank loans, in some cases a firm may wait until its loan expires before searching for a new bank. This is actually what might explain why switching discounts re-emerge after the branch closure, as these are firms that could afford more time to look for a better deal (and the bank has time to make a more solid assessment). To exclude these situations, in Supplementary Appendix 17, we show the results for the subset of firms that had to refinance a loan within 90 days after branch closure. Our results still hold.
One of the reasons why the pool-pricing argument is relevant comes from the fact that, as mentioned above, banks might have trouble in processing information on a pool of new borrowers that suddenly arrive at the bank. To check whether the degree of information asymmetry between borrowers and lenders truly matters in this setting, in Supplementary Appendix 18, we run our estimates only for the most opaque firms (defined as those with fewer than ten employees, and turnover or assets ˂€2 million, located in areas with branch density below the median). In this case, the results are quite stronger. These firms never get a discount when they switch, regardless of the time horizon. Banks seem to always pool price loans on firms on which they might have more difficulties in assessing their true quality.
In Supplementary Appendices 19 and 20, we look at what happens to switchers and transferers over time. Ioannidou and Ongena (2010) show that switching discounts tend to vanish over time, as the firm gets locked-in the new relationship. That is consistent with the results we obtain in Supplementary Appendix 19. For transfer loans, in Supplementary Appendix 20, which start without a discount, the interest rates are never statistically different from those of the control group.
In Supplementary Appendix 21, we show the results of what we can call a placebo test. We still compare interest rates on transfers and switches. However, while in our baseline definition we consider that there is a transfer only when a new relationship is established after a branch closure when there is no other branch of that bank close by (in a 5 km radius), here we look at cases in which there is a closure but there is still at least another branch of that bank at most 1 km away from the firm. In this case, the switching discount reappears for the month immediately after the closure, that is, these transfers are actually switched. This shows that our definition of transfer loans is strict enough to provide meaningful tests.
Finally, in Supplementary Appendix 22, we consider a different control group. Instead of comparing the transfer loans with all other similar loans being granted by the outside bank, we do this comparison for the branches of the outside bank that are not close to the areas where branches closed. This allows us to avoid concerns that the branches of the outside banks faced with more incoming borrowers pass on potential congestion costs to all their customers. The lack of discount after branch closure becomes even clearer.
In further unreported regressions we re-run all exercises only for closures of branches by banks that were recapitalized with bailout funds (as these closures could even be more externally imposed and therefore even less encumbered than other closures). Results are most similar.38
Supplementary Material
Supplementary data are available at Review of Finance online.